Automobile Insurance Pricing:Automobile Insurance Pricing:
Operating Cost versusOperating Cost versus
Ownership Cost;Ownership Cost;
the Implications for Womenthe Implications for Women
Patrick Butler
National Organization for Women
39
Automobile Insurance Pricing
P. Butler
737
AUTOMOBILE INSURANCE PRICING:
OPERATING COST VERSUS OWNERSHIP COST;
THE IMPLICATIONS FOR WOMEN
ABSTRACT
This paper assesses the ability of automobile insurance prices to distinguish the 2:1 ratio of men's to
women's annual mileage, which is linked to a similar ratio of accident involvement per year. Review
of current price classes by driver sex and age, by future mileage, and by past driver record reveals
severe limitations to their capacity to assess women's lower mileage exposure to risk of accidents.
Accidents are modeled as a process of random sampling of vehicle miles traveled (VMT) by cars in
an insurance class. This analogy underscores 1) the impossibility of pricing by individual accident
record and 2) the paramount importance of odometer-measured vehicle miles of on-the-road exposure
for assessing individual accident risk in money terms.
The need for risk classification as the essential complement to exposure measurement is shown by
considering how a single insurance surcharge on gasoline ("pay at the pump" insurance) as an
exposure measure would perversely affect incentives for risk control. Current risk classification is
profoundly compromised because individual exposure is not measured. An efficient per-mile
premium system combining exposure measurement and risk classification is described. Current flat
premiums are compared to premiums that would increase in direct proportion to miles of driving
exposure. This comparison shows how individuals, and also women and men as groups, would be
affected by changing insurance from a fixed cost of car ownership to a per-mile operating cost of car
use.
INTRODUCTION
As a fixed cost of car ownership, automobile insurance currently competes for financial resources
with car payments, registration fees, and property taxes. If we were to make insurance a per-mile
cost of driving, however, operating costs, which now are dominated by gasoline, would
approximately double. Why make such a change? Two reasons are obvious: to enhance affordability
and to reduce externalization of accident costs. A third and less obvious reason is suggested by the
fact that this change would reduce annual ownership cost by several hundred to several thousand
dollars for all drivers and cause operating cost to increase by a similar range in amount. We will see,
however, that the insurance increase in operating cost for most drivers would either be greater or less
but not the same as the insurance decrease in their ownership cost. An important political question is
which groups would spend more for insurance and which would spend less than they do now.
A more fundamental question, however, is which system—fixed cost or operating cost—can more
accurately measure and charge for the risk of driving an automobile. Economists generally agree that
insurance cost pressure should provide individuals with incentives to control accident risk
(Williamson et al., 1967, Vickrey, 1968, Calabresi, 1970). We will consider how well the current
system provides this risk control function and whether a change to per-mile charges would do a better
job.
Women’s Travel Issues
Proceedings from the Second National Conference
738
Insurance would be changed to an operating cost if mandated by a one-sentence amendment to
insurance rate regulation law, introduced but not enacted several years ago in Pennsylvania (Butler,
1993a, National Organization for Women, 1998) and proposed in other states. The amendment
would require companies to convert their price unit—and thus their cost unit—from dollars per
vehicle year to cents per vehicle mile. But what would this change mean for women?
This question is especially relevant since the system now in use has been defended for several
decades as a benefit to women and used to justify resistance to any civil rights measure to prohibit
pricing by driver sex (recently by Brown, 1995, but see also Butler, 1995). As a lower mileage
group, women might on average spend less for auto insurance, but insurers argue that price classes
are already tied to the annual mileage of cars and also to women's lower accident involvement and
better driving records. Therefore, we will start with an examination of the current class system and
its capabilities.
INSURANCE CLASSES
The car, not the driver, is the unit of insurance. To analyze costs and set prices, insurers categorize
cars according to six kinds of classes: territory, type of car, declared future use of car (such as
driving to work), type of driver, declared future mileage (Butler et al., 1988), and past driver record
(Butler and Butler, 1989). In practice, they assign a base price by coverage (liability, collision, etc.)
to each territory class according to past costs. The other five kinds of classes supply additions to and
subtractions from a base 1.00 multiplier of the territory price. If converted to the vehicle mile unit,
territory base prices could be adjusted by vehicle weight and other important risk attributes—
classifications not now used—to serve important risk evaluation functions. Before discussing these
functions, however, we will look more closely at the classes involving drivers and mileage that
insurers represent as beneficial to women.
DRIVER SEX AND AGE CLASSES
Classification of cars by type of driver uses sex and age to define three kinds of subclasses: young
men, young women, and unisex adult. According to annual police reports, men's accident
involvement per 100 licensed drivers is about twice women's in each age group. Strikingly
inconsistent with this pattern, however, is the insurance switch from sex-specific to unisex pricing
for almost all cars with drivers more than 25 or 30 years old (Butler et al., 1988, p. 251).
Table 1 shows typical prices for cars assigned by driver age to unisex and sex specific classes.
Insurance for cars driven by young men is about 1.6 times the price for cars driven by young women,
and both are higher than the unisex prices. Since these prices approximate the ratio of men's to
women's annual mileage, however, young men and women on average—but not individually—spend
about the same amount per mile for insurance. As emphasized in Table 1, for example, young
women who drove 5,000 miles in a year paid 15 cents per mile while young men who drove 10,000
miles paid 14 cents per mile. Although all cars are classified by driver age, fewer than one in four
cars are classified by driver sex.
Automobile Insurance Pricing
P. Butler
739
Table 1
Insurance Prices and Costs by Driver Sex and Age, and Car Miles per Year
If insurers kept claim costs for cars with adult drivers separately for men and women, as they do for
young drivers, non-insurance mileage and accident statistics indicate that the price for adult men
would be about 40% above the current unisex price and the price for adult women would be about
30% below it (Butler et al., 1988). This is not an argument for expanding discrimination between
men and women to include all cars instead of a small minority of them. Nevertheless, since a large
majority of cars are classified as unisex, one can reasonably ask how the real difference between
men's and women's average mileages for these cars is expressed in insurance prices? Why is the cost
difference ostentatiously responded to in youth cars and ignored in the far larger group of adult cars?
Even if all cars were classified by the sex of a driver, however, many men drive fewer miles in a year
than women’s average and some women drive more miles in a year than men's average. Therefore,
driver sex fails at all ages as a measure for the miles individual cars travel.
FUTURE MILEAGE CLASSES
Insurers profess to take individual vehicle miles traveled (VMT) into account by offering price
classes that are defined in terms of annual mileage, which they call "mileage rating." By requesting
odometer readings on application and renewal forms, they encourage the driving public to assume
mistakenly that mileage driven has a significant effect on premium amount. However, company rate
and rule manuals define a car’s annual mileage by how far it will be driven in the coming year—that
is, future mileage—as stated by the insured (or filled in by the agent). At the end of the policy year,
there is no premium adjustment regardless of how many or few miles a car actually was driven.
Predictably, the resulting price differences between low and high future mileage classes conform to
nominal discount or surcharge amounts of 15 to 20 percent. Some companies have even
discontinued low future mileage discounts entirely because of the inherent impossibility under the
pressure of price competition on agents of keeping a large majority of drivers from getting such
discounts (Butler et al., 1988, pp. 388-393). Since neither future mileage nor driver sex comes close
to pricing the differences between the average accident involvements and annual mileages of men
and women, we turn to driver record as the third and last kind of class pricing that insurers say helps
to distinguish these major differences.
DRIVER RECORD CLASSES
The familiar advertisements that offer "good rates for good drivers" promote the mistaken idea that
individual risk can be measured by a driver's accident record. Although the idea is quietly disparaged
by some company actuaries, the public only hears the marketing department’s message. Probability
Class Multiplier Vehicle-Year Vehicle-Mile Cost
by Future Price ($) for (Cents) to Owner by
Driver Class Mileage Class* High Future Miles Actually Driven in Year
Low High Mileage** 5,000 mi. 10,000 mi. 20,000 mi.
Men 17-24 2.35 2.80 1400 23.5
14.0
7.0
Women 17-24 1.50 1.70 850
15.0
8.5 4.3
Unisex 30+ 0.95 1.10 550 9.5 5.5 2.8
* State Farm California manual effective 1-15-91.
** Territory base price assumed to be $500.
Women’s Travel Issues
Proceedings from the Second National Conference
740
modeling by industry actuaries that treats traffic accidents as a random process, however, shows that
this popular idea is erroneous (Industry Advisory Committee 1979, Butler and Butler, 1989, Butler,
1993b). A simple thought-experiment explains why. Imagine a jar containing 100 black balls
representing individual cars. Draw out one ball at random to represent an accident involvement, and
then replace it in the jar and stir before the next drawing. To keep track of the accident record of
individual balls, change the color of a drawn ball before replacing it from black to white (first
accident), then from white to green if drawn a second time, then from green to red for a third draw of
the same ball. Since 100 insured cars typically produce 5 claims a year and since insurers use the
records of the past three years to determine surcharges, draw and replace 15 balls. Then count the
balls by color. Poisson probability predicts that about 86 of the balls will still be black (accident
free), 13 white (1 accident), 1 green (2 accidents), and 0.05 red. If the experiment were scaled up to
10,000 balls—approximately the number of cars actuaries require for a credible risk class—five of
them would be red, indicating 3 accidents apiece in a period of three years. Is this proof that some
balls are more likely to be drawn than others? Not at all. By design, all of the balls had an equal
chance of being picked in each draw.
In defense of classifying cars by accident record, insurance companies point to the well-established
fact that the subclass of drivers who had accidents in a three-year period subsequently averages more
accidents in the following (fourth) year than accident-free drivers in the same class. This result,
however, can be modeled by specifying that not all of the balls spend the same amount of time in the
jar and thus have different chances of being drawn (Butler and Butler, 1989, pp. 206-208, Butler,
1993b, pp. 58-60). Rather than appealing to compound Poisson models of balls with different
exposures, we can instead think of an accident-record subclass as a random sample of a class of cars
on the road.
A three-year’s sample of cars picked at random by accident involvement from a class of cars would
include cars driven many miles and also cars driven few miles. The cars driven more than the class-
average, however, would be over-represented in the accident sample because they were more
exposed to risk of accident, while the cars driven less than average would be under-represented in
this sample. In the coming (fourth) year, therefore, the subclass of cars whose drivers have had
accidents in the last three years would average a higher mileage and more accidents than the large
class of cars with accident-free drivers. An example emphasizes important consequences.
Typically a subclass of cars defined by having had accidents in the past three years, taken from a
class with 5 claims a year per 100 cars, subsequently averages about 7.5 claims a year per 100 cars,
which is a fifty percent increase. This apparently large increase in accident rate would simply mean
that there has been a similar increase in annual mileage, say from a class average of 10,000 miles to
an accident subclass average of 15,000 miles. Finally, it is important to realize that despite this large
difference in accidents per year between the main accident-free class and the recent-accident
subclass, a very large majority of the cars in each would have identical accident-free records in this
fourth year: about 93% in the recent-accident subclass compared with slightly more than 95% in the
rest of the class.
In discussing a paper of mine that made the analogy between accident record classes and random
samples biased to higher average mileages, the chief actuary of the Automobile Insurers Bureau in
Boston noted that the effect of differences in miles of exposure to risk on the road "is one that I
Automobile Insurance Pricing
P. Butler
741
expect many practicing actuaries frequently forget" (Cardoso, 1993). He then described an
equivalent problem: "If one surveys riders [on the subway] at random and asks how many days per
month they ride the subway, the average answer will be too high an estimate of the population mean
because the survey-taker more likely will encounter persons who are frequently on the subway."
As with surveying subway riders for riding frequency, if one were to randomly survey cars on the
road for annual mileage, the resulting average would be too high an estimate of the population mean
for any class of cars. Similarly, an accident sample of cars on the road will not be representative of
average mileage of a population of insured cars, but will be biased to cars which are more frequently
on the road. In fact, the population that accidents sample at random is not a class of insured cars but
rather the total VMT in a year (or other time period) by the cars in the class.
It follows that the measurable protection cost an individual car imposes on the insurance system is
not proportional to the amount of time that the insurance is in effect—as insurance is currently costed
and priced—but is proportional to the number of miles the car is exposed to risk, which is recorded
by its odometer. The car owner exerts absolute control on risk-taking: without exposure there is no
chance of accident involvement and no cost to the insurance system. Moreover, VMT of on the road
exposure to risk can only be measured individually and not by averages for classes defined by driver
sex or by unverifiable declarations of future mileage. Measuring exposure, however, is only one of
two parts to the task of evaluating individual risk.
Complementary to measuring individual exposure is the need to determine the risk rate per vehicle
mile of exposure for different classes of driving risk. For cars with young drivers the accident
sampling rate per VMT is two to four times the rate for cars with adult drivers. The model of balls
picked randomly from a jar, however, emphasizes that the sampling rate per VMT is inherently a
class property that cannot be measured for individuals.
We will compare current class prices presumed to reflect risk with the risk per VMT that could be
derived from direct measurement of exposure by the odometers of all cars in each class. To
underscore the importance of classification to measure different risk rates per mile, however, we will
first examine an alternative proposal that would proportion premiums to gallons of gasoline.
MEASURING VEHICLE RISK
MEASURING VEHICLE MILES OF EXPOSURE
Adding an insurance charge to the price of gasoline is a proposal that has received considerable
support from consumer and environmental advocates and some academics (e.g., Sugarman, 1993).
Full coverage would probably require about $1 per gallon, although proponents are proposing only
minimum coverage that would require a lower surcharge. A substantial insurance addition to the
price of gasoline would increase the operating cost incentive to reduce risk by driving less. A "pay-
at-the-pump" insurance system, however, would not only eliminate price variation for different car
values and optional coverages but, even more seriously, would produce strong incentives for
increased risk. For example, an insurance increase in the cost of gasoline would give a perverse
incentive to increase risk by driving lighter vehicles that provide less occupant protection than
heavier vehicles (Evans, 1991).
Women’s Travel Issues
Proceedings from the Second National Conference
742
Another problem for a gasoline surcharge system is the need for territorial classes to assess the
difference in risk per VMT between urban and rural areas. If the insurance price per gallon could not
be sufficiently varied by locale, which is likely because purchasing patterns would frustrate any but
minimal differences, it would charge too little for the risk of driving done mainly in urban areas and
too much for predominantly rural driving. As a consequence, there would be more urban driving
than justified by accident costs, which would be subsidized by overcharging for the risk of rural
driving. These difficulties in appropriate risk classification, largely ignored by proponents, are
sufficiently serious that it is not necessary to examine important practical concerns. Therefore, we
will consider alternatively how a system of per-mile insurance charges would probably operate, and
how well it would perform the combined functions of exposure measurement and risk classification
in comparison with the current system.
If required to change from the year to the vehicle mile exposure unit, auto insurance companies
would probably follow standard commercial procedures (Butler, 1993a). This would include
adopting the policy provisions on odometer fraud long since established by insurers in providing
mechanical breakdown insurance for used cars. Premium payment in advance would be required to
keep insurance protection in force. The premium at vehicle-mile prices for driving coverages would
be prepaid in mileage amounts and at times chosen by the car owner. At a price of 5 cents per mile,
for example, an owner might decide to spend $250 to get 5,000 miles of coverage for the car,
expecting that amount of protection to last about six months. Administrative expense and premium
for non-driving coverages at vehicle year prices would be prepaid at policy-year renewal time. The
car's proof-of-insurance identification card—required by law in most states—would display the
odometer-mile and date limits at which protection would lapse pending further premium prepayment.
Policy renewal would be conditional on taking the car to a garage designated by the company for the
annual physical audit of its odometer. The odometer would be inspected and read, and tamper-
evident seals would be applied at the initial audit. Under this procedure, theft of insurance protection
would be controlled because tampering with the odometer—a federal crime—would automatically
void the policy. Driving with the odometer cable unhooked would not steal insurance protection,
because it usually would be detected after an accident and the tampering would have voided the
protection. Self-interest and competition on service should assure development of company systems
that are efficient, convenient, and credible for consumers, and that effectively control premium fraud.
Although insurers have asserted in defense of current flat premiums that the costs of measuring
mileage would be enormous, examination of their statements shows that the "mileage" to which they
are referring is an expansion of declared-future "mileage rating" classes under the current vehicle
year system. They are not referring to a system that would use an audited vehicle-mile exposure unit
resulting in proportional premiums. Under cross examination at a rate discrimination trial, actuaries
testifying as expert witnesses for defendant auto insurance companies admitted that, in their opinion,
the cost of odometer auditing would be less than $25. This amount, which is large in comparison
with what private garages charge for safety and emissions inspections, is adopted for the sake of
discussion in this paper. A study considering how a per-mile system probably would be operated
found the potential for reducing the number of insurer transactions with customers from the current
number ranging up to twelve per year for installment and suspension of coverage arrangements, and
to reducing enforcement costs to states with mandatory coverage (Butler, 1993a). Since an odometer
method capable of measuring exposure appears to be feasible, we can now consider the
Automobile Insurance Pricing
P. Butler
743
characteristics of current risk classes and how they could be converted to equivalent classes in a
vehicle-mile system.
CLASSIFICATION FOR MEASURING RISK PER VMT
Of the five kinds of price classes cited, territory makes the greatest difference in what insurance now
costs. A car's territory class is determined by the owner's residence and presumably assesses the risk
where a preponderance of driving is likely to be done. This function can be evaluated by comparing
two California territories where there is a large difference in prices, Table 2.
Table 2
Insurance Costs by Territory Class for Vehicle Miles Driven
State Farm's price for urban Los Angeles is 4.4 times the price it charges in thirteen rural Northern
California counties for identical coverage, $1172 versus $265. Both prices reflect the declared future
mileage class adjustments. For comparison to these annual prices, the costs to owners in cents-per-
mile terms are calculated at four mileages from three to 20 thousand miles, each of which represents
the amount many cars are driven in a year. (In 1990, about 15% of household vehicles were driven
less than 3,000 miles, and 18% were driven more than 20,000 miles (Murakami, 1993).)
The justification for territorial classes is geographic variation in congestion and other hazards that
affect per-mile accident rates. Using the analogy of accident involvement to random sampling, there
is a higher accident-sampling rate per million VMT of urban class cars than of rural class cars. This
rationale should be called into question, however, by what it now costs individuals per-mile for
insurance protection.
The cost per mile under the existing system decreases as the number of miles driven during the policy
year increases. In Table 2 the cost per mile is least for the cars driven 20,000 miles in one year. If
the same 20,000 miles were driven in two years instead of one, however, the per-mile cost of
insurance protection would double, from 1.3 cents to 2.6 cents in rural California, Table 2. Or if the
20,000 miles were driven in a year but two cars were used instead of one, the cost per mile, with the
effect of a fifteen percent multi-car discount included, would nearly double to 2.3 cents. This large
variation in insurance cost per mile within territory classes contradicts the rationale that territory
classification assesses geographic differences in driving risk.
The driving risk rationale for territory classes is also challenged by comparing cents-per-mile insurance
cost between Los Angeles and rural Northern California, where difference in driving risk presumably
is very large. Paradoxically, however, insurance costs more per mile for rural California cars driven
Vehicle-Year Price
($) by Future Vehicle-Mile Cost (Cents) by
Territory Class Mileage Class* Miles Car Was Driven in Year
Low mi. High mi. 3,000 mi. 8,000 mi. 12,000 mi. 20,000 mi.
Rural N. Calif. 229 265 7.6 3.3 2.2 1.3
Urban Los Angeles 1,012 1,172 33.7 14.7 9.8 5.9
* State Farm California manual effective 1-15-91. "Low" is future mileage stated as
less than 7500 miles and "High" is 7500 miles and more.
Women’s Travel Issues
Proceedings from the Second National Conference
744
low mileages than it does for Los Angeles cars driven high mileages, 7.6 cents per mile for rural cars
driven 3,000 miles in a year versus 5.9 cents per mile for urban cars driven 20,000 miles, Table 2.
These kinds of anomalies in per-mile cost completely discredit the rationale of appropriate insurance
pressure on the driving risk in different territories. Conversion of these two territorial classes to per-
mile prices, however, shows how territorial classification could effectively assess difference in risk
rates.
Conversion of auto insurance prices from the vehicle year to the vehicle mile unit requires determining
the average mileage of each class. Cost per vehicle-year divided by miles per vehicle-year equals
cost per vehicle-mile. Insurance companies now routinely determine cost per vehicle-year for each
territory. They could closely estimate class-average mileages initially for conversion by sampling, but
would subsequently get the average from the sum of the individual mileages of each class population.
It is very unlikely, however, that the average annual mileage per vehicle in Los Angeles classes is the
same as the average mileage in the comparable rural Northern California classes.
Because parking, taxes, and especially insurance make the unit cost of car ownership higher in cities,
individual cars tend to be used by more drivers and the average annual miles per insured car should be
more than in non-urban areas. Consequently, it is assumed that the urban Los Angeles class averages
12,000 miles per car year, which translates to a 9.8 cents per mile class-average cost, Table 2. While
rural drivers themselves probably average more miles than urban drivers, their driving is commonly
spread over several vehicles. It is therefore assumed that the rural California class average is 8,000
miles per vehicle, which results in a 3.3 cents per mile class cost. By means of these per-mile
averages, the effect on annual insurance expenditure through conversion from per-year prices can be
considered.
Figure 1
Flat and proportional premiums by vehicle miles traveled per year for urban and rural territories
Figure 1 shows the effect on premium charges of the miles a vehicle travels during a policy year.
Stepped horizontal lines represent the premium cost at the current dollars per year prices for the two
0
500
1,000
1,500
2,000
0 5 10 15 20
Car Miles Traveled (000)
P
r
e
m
i
u
m
$
Rural
FLAT
rural avg.
PROPORTIONAL
urban avg.
Urban
FLAT
PROPORTIONAL
Automobile Insurance Pricing
P. Butler
745
territories. Steps at 7,500 miles show the effect of the two future mileage classes, as if they
represented the miles subsequently driven during the policy year. The two "proportional" lines
extending from the origin represent the premium versus vehicle miles traveled at per-mile prices.
The slopes are defined by the current premium divided by the average mileages assumed for each
class (Table 2). These mileages are marked by vertical lines, which connect to the equal premium
intersections of the Flat and Proportional lines. Owing to the different average mileages assumed for
the classes, the slope of the Urban line is only about three times as steep as the Rural line, which
probably represents a more realistic difference in risk per mile than the 4.4 to one ratio of the flat
premiums. Comparing flat and proportional premium lines also allows us to consider some
implications of a change to the vehicle mile exposure unit.
IMPLICATIONS OF EXPOSURE UNIT CHANGE
INCENTIVE TO CONTROL RISK
The existing insurance pressure on ownership cost perversely provides incentives for increased risk.
The only way consumers have to cut insurance expense—other than by selling one car and using
another more intensively or by keeping a young household member from getting a license—is to cut
back on coverage. But reducing coverage increases the risk to family savings, and shifts costs to
employer paid health insurance and to social insurance funded by taxpayers.
It is axiomatic that, with every mile a car is driven, risk is both assumed by the car's owner and
passengers and is also imposed on other road users. With reference to the flat premium lines of
Figure 1, the effect of insurance cost on the amount of driving is limited to the extent that income to
pay the cost of gasoline is reduced by the insurance charge. Nevertheless, once the lump sum
insurance cost of admission to car registration is paid—whether $1,000 in Los Angeles or one-
quarter of that in rural California—insurance cannot put cost pressure on decisions about whether or
not to take a trip. The relatively small step up for the high future mileage class merely serves as an
incentive to avoid the step by declaring a low future mileage on the application or renewal form. Just
as price competition has dictated over the past decade for car rentals, auto insurance provides
"unlimited free mileage."
In contrast to the current lack of insurance incentive to limit exposure to accident risk, proportional
premiums would impose cost pressure on every mile driven. After paying a nominal fee for
odometer auditing, the incremental (marginal) cost that per-mile insurance would provide is like the
resistance to walking up an incline, up the proportional premium line. The steepness of proportional
premium lines in Figures 1 signals the degree of driving risk with per-mile prices. Higher risk
classes would put more cost pressure on the amount of driving. Young drivers cannot increase their
age, nor should people be expected to move to lower risk rate territories, but proportional premiums
would allow drivers to control their insurance cost, the same way they can control their accident risk,
by the amount of driving they do.
Risk is strongly affected by vehicle weight (Evans, 1991, pp. 64-77, 94-95) and, to a lesser extent, by
safety devices like air bags and anti-lock brakes. Existing premiums, however, do not vary at all by
car weight. Furthermore, the discounts insurance companies provide for safety devices on late model
cars are not only not backed by claim cost experience, but also may be associated with more collision
and injury claims per car year than identical cars without the optional devices (Peterson and Hoffer,
Women’s Travel Issues
Proceedings from the Second National Conference
746
1996). Although "offsetting behavior" and "adverse selection" (drivers with higher risk per-mile
somehow know this and preferentially buy safety equipment) are offered as explanations (Peterson
and Hoffer 1996), it is also true that demand for optional safety devices correlates directly with
income which also positively relates to demand for vehicle miles of travel, that is, exposure to risk.
More miles of travel on average by those choosing anti-lock brakes would tend to offset any
reduction in risk rate per mile.
Drivers can reduce their risk rate through choice of a heavier car at a cost of decreased fuel
efficiency and increased risk per mile imposed on other traffic. The current flat premium system,
however, provides no accurate financial risk-reducing incentive or even any information on what car
weight is most risk-efficient in terms of the combined effect of assumed and imposed risk.
INDIVIDUAL AND GROUP EFFECTS
Which individuals and groups would spend less and which would spend more on insurance with a
change from flat to proportional premiums? This issue can be framed with reference to Figure 2,
which is a simplified version of Figure 1. It shows premium paid as a function of miles traveled
during the policy year. The $500 premium line has no steps for future mileage classes, in view of
their inherent unenforceability. A class average 10,000 miles per year is assumed, which makes the
slope of the proportional premium line 5 cents per mile. An odometer audit fee--assumed generously
at $25 for the sake of discussion--raises the proportional line by that amount and puts the equal
premium intersection of the two lines at 9,500 miles (the $25 fee is equivalent to 500 miles at 5 cents
per mile).
Figure 2
Flat and proportional premiums by vehicle miles traveled per year with $25 assumed odometer fee
0
500
1,000
0 5 10 15 20
Car Miles Traveled (000)
P
r
e
m
i
u
m
$
class
avg.
FLAT
$25
PROPORTIONAL
increase
decrease
The vertical separation between the flat and proportional lines at the number of miles actually driven
represents the change in insurance expense with change in exposure unit. This helps to answer the
question I posed initially in observing that ownership cost would decrease for all drivers—by a net of
Automobile Insurance Pricing
P. Butler
747
$475 in Figure 2—but that the simultaneous insurance increase in operating cost would be greater or
less than the ownership cost reduction. The answer for individuals would depend on whether they
drive more or less after the change than what the average mileage for their class was before the
change. We can draw some conclusions about groups by considering conditions that now cause
changes in driving levels.
For Figure 1 we assumed a difference in average mileage between rural and urban territories in
California. In estimating the number of future claims, insurers take into consideration expected
economic conditions and gasoline prices. During recessions, or when the price of gasoline increases
significantly, many drivers reduce the number of trips they take with the result that overall accidents
and claims drop sharply (Butler et al., 1988, p. 272). At a hearing by the Pennsylvania House
insurance committee when the 1990-1991 recession was ending, the President of the Insurance
Federation of Pennsylvania testified that auto claims had declined not because of a recent reform law
to control medical expense, but because of decreased driving. To dramatize the relatively large drop
in auto insurance claims, he quoted State Farm's Pennsylvania vice president as speculating that "a
lot of cars are up on blocks" (Hager, 1991).
When the economy improves or gasoline gets cheaper, auto insurers apply for regulatory approval of
higher prices because "people are driving more" (see Butler et al., 1988, pp. 272-273 for statements
made to regulators). The fact that insurers find it necessary to raise prices when driving increases is
strong evidence that current automobile premiums do not respond to the individual changes that add
up to changes in average mileage.
Although insurers usually retain the windfall decreases in costs from unexpected decreases in driving
as a hedge against having to raise prices sharply when driving returns to normal, occasionally they
refund part of the surplus premium. For example, refunds by State Farm Mutual Auto Insurance that
followed the 1990-1991 recession illustrate the cost-shifting effects of the current price system. At
the end of policy periods covering that time interval, in several states the company returned 20
percent of the premium that each policy holder initially paid (News report, 1991).
Figure 3 reproduces Figure 2, but with the effect of a 20 decrease in insurer cost represented by a
premium refund. It also shows an assumed proportional decrease in average mileage from 10,000 to
8,000 miles. If 20 percent is the average decrease in driving, and if it is assumed that there are
drivers not affected by recessions or gasoline prices, then some of those who were affected must have
decreased driving more than 20 percent. Drivers who cut mileage thirty percent got a twenty percent
refund along with all other car owners. The other ten percent savings would thus pay for the refund
to owners who cut driving less than 20 percent, or may even have increased their driving.
Women’s Travel Issues
Proceedings from the Second National Conference
748
Figure 3
Effect of twenty percent decrease in average mileage on flat versus proportional premiums
0
500
1,000
0 5 10 15 20
Car Miles Traveled (000)
P
r
e
m
i
u
m
$
past
av
g
.
final FLAT
PROPORTIONAL
initial FLAT
actual
avg.
Thus with current pricing based on class-average cost, any windfall cost reduction from a decrease in
average mileage actually goes not just to people who drive less, but is spread to all policyholders
regardless of their individual mileage. Those who are responsible for cost savings share them with
others unaffected by recessions and higher gasoline prices. Since demand for vehicle miles
correlates to income (Dahl, 1986), dollars in effect are transferred from lower to higher income
motorists via auto insurance premiums. Car owners whose mileage is perennially below average are
forced to subsidize the insurance protection for owners of cars in their class driven above average
mileage. Low income individuals who buy car insurance they can scarcely afford in fact subsidize
premiums for those who generally do not need the subsidy.
WOMEN AND MEN
Economic conditions and the price of gasoline must also differentially affect the driving of women
and men as two demographic groups with a large difference in income distributions. In 1990, 41
percent of women drivers drove less than 5,000 miles, while about half as many men drivers were in
this low mileage category (Hu and Young, 1993, p. 3-20). Conversely, in the high mileage category,
nearly 30% of men drove more than 20,000 miles while only 11% of women drove that much, Figure
4. The difference between the mileage distributions of women and men leaves little doubt that a
greater proportion of women than men would gain a deserved and risk-based net saving from a
change from per year to per mile insurance. Nevertheless, it is important to keep in mind that it is
individuals, not groups, who drive cars and that individuals respond differently to changes in the cost
of driving and also to changes in economic conditions.
Automobile Insurance Pricing
P. Butler
749
Figure 4
1990 NPTS distribution of women and men drivers by annual mileage
15
23
10
11
20
12
24
15
29
41
Driver Miles Traveled (000)
% WOMEN % MEN
0
5
10
15
20 100
Current flat pricing is buttressed by strong insurer marketing mythologies. Prime examples are the
selective reality of women's greater "safety" as drivers and the statistically absurd idea that risk can
be individually assessed by use of driver-record and claim-free pricing. Moreover, recent research on
women drivers has sought to problematize the increase in women's annual accident involvement,
rather than to explain it as an inevitable consequence of an increase in women’s average miles of
exposure to accident risk. Press releases announcing research findings generate invidious newspaper
headlines like "Road hazard? Women are more accident-prone, U-M study finds" (Greenwood,
1993).
Academics inexcusably ignore past criticism of the auto insurance price structure. For example, in a
1968 law and economics study, one of this year's Nobel prize winners, William Vickrey, attempted to
call attention to "the frequently overlooked fact that the manner in which premiums are computed
and paid fails miserably to bring home to the automobile user the costs he imposes in a manner that
will appropriately influence his decisions" (Vickrey, 1968). Subsequent scholarly indifference to this
strong condemnation can only be explained in terms of protecting a subsidy for higher-mileage
drivers as a politically and economically powerful group. University researchers, however, have a
responsibility to set aside class and sex politics. They need to contribute constructively to an
emerging and long overdue critique of the practice of charging for automobile insurance as a fixed
cost of car ownership rather than as a variable cost of car use, the activity that produces traffic
accidents.
Women’s Travel Issues
Proceedings from the Second National Conference
750
REFERENCES
Brown, R. L. 1995. “Recent Canadian Human Rights Decisions Having an Impact on Gender-Based
Risk Classification Systems.” Journal of Actuarial Practice 3: 171-180.
Butler, P. 1993a. “Operation of an Audited-Mile/Year Automobile Insurance System Under
Pennsylvania Law.” Casualty Actuarial Society Forum Summer 1993: 307-338.
Butler, P. 1993b. “Cost-Based Pricing of Individual Automobile Risk Transfer: Car-Mile Exposure
Unit Analysis.”
Journal of Actuarial Practice
1: 51-84.
Butler, P. 1995. “Discussion of Robert L. Brown's ‘Recent Canadian Human Rights Decisions
Having an Impact on Gender-Based Risk Classification Systems.’” Journal of Actuarial
Practice
3: 181-190.
Butler, P. and T. Butler. 1989. “Driver Record: a Political Red Herring That Reveals the Basic Flaw
in Automobile Insurance Pricing.”
Journal of Insurance Regulation
8: 200-234.
Butler, P., T. Butler, and L. L. Williams. 1988. “Sex-Divided Mileage, Accident, and Insurance Cost
Data Show That Auto Insurers Overcharge Most Women
.
Journal of Insurance Regulation
6: 243-284 (Pt. I), 373-420 (Pt. II).
Calabresi, G. 1970. The Costs of Accidents: A Legal and Economic Analysis. New Haven: Yale
University Press.
Cardoso, R. 1993. “Discussion of Patrick Butler's ‘Cost-Based Pricing of Individual Automobile
Risk Transfer: Car-Mile Exposure Unit Analysis.’” Journal of Actuarial Practice 1: 69-71.
Dahl, C. A. 1986. “Gasoline Demand Survey.”
The Energy Journal
7: 67-82.
Evans, L. 1991.
Traffic Safety and the Driver
. New York: Van Nostrand Reinhold.
Greenwood, T. 1993. “Road hazard? Women are more accident-prone.” The Detroit News, July 9,
1993, p. 1A.
Hager, H. 1991. “Insurance Federation of Pennsylvania Testimony.”
Insurance Committee,
Pennsylvania House of Representatives. Hearing Transcript, November 14, 1991: 109-125.
Hu, P. S. and J. Young. 1993.
1990 NPTS Data Book
,
Nationwide Personal Transportation Survey
.
Volume I.
Industry Advisory Committee (to the National Association of Insurance Commissioners). 1979.
“Driving Record.”
Report: Private Passenger Automobile Insurance Risk Classification.
Part G, 43-66.
Murakami, E. 1993. Table of model year by annualized vehicle miles, June 28, 1993. 1990
Nationwide Personal Transportation Survey (NPTS).
National Organization for Women. 1998. “Model Per Mile Auto Insurance Option Act.”
www.now.org/issues/economic/insurance/
Automobile Insurance Pricing
P. Butler
751
News report. 1991. “State Farm to Refund Millions in Car Premiums.” Journal of Commerce,
December 18, p. 9A.
Peterson, S. and G. E. Hoffer. 1996. “Auto Insurers and the Air Bag: Comment.” Journal of Risk
and Insurance 63: 515-523.
Sugarman, S. D. 1993.
"Pay at The Pump" Auto Insurance
. Berkeley: Institute of Governmental
Studies Press, University of California.
Vickrey, W. 1968. “Automobile Accidents, Tort Law, Externalities, and Insurance: An Economist's
Critique.”
Law and Contemporary Problems
33: 464-487.
Williamson, O. E., D. G. Olson, and A. Ralston. 1967. “Externalities, Insurance, and Disability
Analysis.” Economica 34: 235-253.