DIRECTORATE-GENERAL FOR INTERNAL POLICIES
POLICY DEPARTMENT B: STRUCTURAL AND COHESION POLICIES
AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT
COMPARISON OF FARMERS’ INCOMES
IN THE EU MEMBER STATES
STUDY
This document was requested by the European Parliament's Committee on Agriculture and
Rural Development.
AUTHORS
1
University of London: Professor Berkeley Hill, Emeritus Professor of Policy Analysis
Agra CEAS Consulting: Dr B. Dylan Bradley
RESPONSIBLE ADMINISTRATOR
Albert Massot
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
European Parliament
B-1047 Brussels
E-mail: poldep-cohesi[email protected].eu
EDITORIAL ASSISTANCE
Catherine Morvan
LINGUISTIC VERSIONS
Original: EN
ABOUT THE PUBLISHER
To contact the Policy Department or to subscribe to its monthly newsletter please write to:
poldep-cohesion@europarl.europa.eu
Manuscript completed in June, 2015.
© European Union, 2015.
This document is available on the Internet at:
http://www.europarl.europa.eu/studies
DISCLAIMER
The opinions expressed in this document are the sole responsibility of the author and do
not necessarily represent the official position of the European Parliament.
Reproduction and translation for non-commercial purposes are authorized, provided the
source is acknowledged and the publisher is given prior notice and sent a copy.
1
Acknowledgements: Most of our analysis has made use of public databases. However, the authors gratefully
acknowledge the assistance provided by the DG AGRI EU-FADN unit which provided special analysis where
access to raw data was needed and for the construction of maps. The authors also gratefully acknowledge the
input of Professor Sophia Davidova, University of Kent.
DIRECTORATE-GENERAL FOR INTERNAL POLICIES
POLICY DEPARTMENT B: STRUCTURAL AND COHESION POLICIES
AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT
COMPARISON OF FARMERS’ INCOMES
IN THE EU MEMBER STATES
STUDY
Abstract
With the main stated objectives of the CAP in mind, relevant comparisons
that involve the incomes of farmers are made. EU official data sources
are used to describe income differences between holdings of different
sizes and types and between Member States. Comparisons between the
incomes of farmer household and other groups in society have to rely on
ad hoc information. Recommendations relate to the support of small
farms, actions to mitigate instability and to fill the important gap in farm
household income information.
IP/B/AGRI/IC/2014-68 June 2015
PE 540.374 EN
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
3
CONTENTS
LIST OF ABBREVIATIONS 5
LIST OF TABLES 7
LIST OF MAPS 7
LIST OF FIGURES 7
LIST OF BOXES 9
EXECUTIVE SUMMARY 11
1. INTRODUCTION 17
1.1. The economic function of profit from farming 18
1.2. Characteristics of incomes in agriculture 18
1.3. Accounting systems and agricultural incomes 21
1.4. Policy aims and appropriate measures of income 24
2. DATA SOURCES AND METHODOLOGICAL EXPLANATION 29
2.1. Data sources on the incomes of agricultural households 30
2.2. Data sources on the rewards from agricultural production 31
3. OVERVIEW OF THE INCOME DEVELOPMENT OF EU AGRICULTURE 35
3.1. Incomes of farm households 36
3.2. Incomes from agricultural activity 40
4. THE DYNAMICS OF FARM INCOMES AND THE KEY DRIVERS 65
4.1. Farm household income 66
4.2. Income from agricultural activity 67
5. DIFFERENCES BETWEEN MEMBER STATES 83
5.1. Differences in income levels 84
5.2. Differences in direction of change 88
5.3. Comparisons between Member State incomes for each main farm type
(FADN data) 91
5.4. Comparisons between Member States of farms by economic size group 94
5.5. Agricultural wages in Member States 96
6. RECOMMENDATIONS FOR FUTURE INCOME SUPPORT UNDER THE
CAP 101
6.1. The need for reliable statistics on agricultural household incomes 101
6.2. Statistics based on people rather than production 104
6.3. Income stabilisation 105
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
4
6.4. Support for small farms 108
6.5. Balance between support and market orientation 109
REFERENCES 111
LEGAL REFERENCES 115
ANNEX : Data sources on the rewards from Agricultural production 117
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
5
LIST OF ABBREVIATIONS
ARMS
AWU
Agricultural Resource Management Survey
Agricultural work unit
CAP
Common Agricultural Policy
CMO
Common market organisation
DG AGRI
Directorate-General for Agriculture and Rural Development
EAA
Economic Accounts for Agriculture
ECA
European Court of Auditors
ECU
European Currency Unit
ERS
Economic Research Service (of the United States Department of
Agriculture)
ESA
European System of Accounts
EU
European Union
EU-15
Grouping of Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany,
Greece, Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg, Netherlands, Portugal, Spain,
Sweden and the UK.
EU-27
Grouping of the EU-15, EU-N10 and EU-N2
EU-28
Grouping of the EU-15, EU-N10, EU-N2 and Croatia
EU-N2
Grouping of Bulgaria and Romania
EU-N10
Grouping of Cyprus, Czech Republic, Estonia, Hungary, Latvia,
Lithuania, Malta, Poland, Slovakia, Slovenia
EU-SILC
European Union Statistics on Income and Living Conditions
FADN
Farm Accountancy Data Network
FAO
Food and Agriculture Organisation of the United Nations
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
6
FFI
Farm Family Income
FNVA
Farm Net Value Added
FSS
Farm Structural Survey
FWU
Family Work Unit
GATT
General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade
IAHS
Income of the Agricultural Households Sector
JRC
Joint Reserarch Centre (of the European Commission)
LFA
Less Favoured Area
LKAU
Local Kind of Activity Unit
NVA
Net Value Added
OECD
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development
OGA
Other Gainful Activity
SFS
Small Farmers Scheme
SNA
System of National Accounts
SO
Standard Output
TFEU
Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union
UN
United Nations
UK
United Kingdom
US(A)
United States (of America)
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
7
LIST OF TABLES
Table 1:
Economic Accounts for Agriculture: current transactions accounts from 1999 118
Table 2:
FADN field of observation 121
LIST OF MAPS
Map 1:
FNVA in Euro per AWU by FADN region, 2010-2012 average 87
Map 2:
FFI in Euro per FWU by FADN region, 2010-2012 average 88
Map 3:
Average nominal wages paid by FADN region, 2010-12 average 98
LIST OF FIGURES
Figure 1:
The relationship between agricultural activity and the institutional units that generate it 23
Figure 2:
Evolution of index of real income of factors in agricultural activity per annual work unit
(Eurostat Indicator A) and index of real net agricultural entrepreneurial income per
unpaid work unit (Eurostat Indicator B) (2005=100) 41
Figure 3:
Comparison of FADN FNVA/AWU against Eurostat Indicator A and FFI/FWU against
Eurostat Indicator B, EU-25/EU-27 (2007=100, real terms) 42
Figure 4:
Distribution of farm size by farm type in the FADN sample, 2010-2012 average 44
Figure 5:
Indicators of farm income, EU-25 2000-06, EU-27 2007-12, 2004-2012 45
Figure 6:
Evolution of FFI/FWU by EU groupings, 2004-12 46
Figure 7:
Indicators of farm income by farm size, 2010-2012 average 47
Figure 8:
Evolution of FFI/FWU by farm size, 2004-2012 48
Figure 9:
Indicators of farm income by farm type, 2010-2012 average 49
Figure 10:
Evolution of FFI/FWU by farm type, 2004-2012 50
Figure 11:
FFI/FWU by type of farm and size class, 2004-2012 51
Figure 12:
Indicators of farm income by age, EU-27 2010-2012 53
Figure 13:
Indicators of farm income by ownership structure and EU sub-group, 2010-2012 average 54
Figure 14:
Indicators of farm income by Less Favoured Area status, EU-27 2010-2012 55
Figure 15:
Annual year-on-year change in farm income indicators 56
Figure 16:
Coefficient of variation of income indicators by farm size, 2004-2012 57
Figure 17:
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
8
Coefficient of variation by farm type, 2004-2012 57
Figure 18:
Farm level volatility, 1998-2007 58
Figure 19:
Lorenz curve of the distribution of FNVA and FFI, EU-27, 2010-2012 average 59
Figure 20:
Development of the Gini coefficient of FNVA per AWU 60
Figure 21:
Paid labour (
€/hour), 2004
-2012 61
Figure 22:
Paid labour (
€/hour) by farm type, 2010
-2012 average 62
Figure 23:
Annual year-on-year change in paid agricultural wages per hour 63
Figure 24:
Income components per farm by EU group, 2010-12 average 68
Figure 25:
Income components per farm by EU farm type, 2010-12 average 70
Figure 26:
Income components per farm by economic size, 2010-12 average 71
Figure 27:
Change in value of income components 2004-06 average compared to 2010-12 average
by EU sub-group 72
Figure 28:
Change in value of income components 2004-06 average compared to 2010-12 average
by farm type 73
Figure 29:
Evolution of the components of Total Output per farm, EU-25 2004-2006, EU-27 2007-
2012 74
Figure 30:
Evolution of crop and livestock prices, EU-27, 2005 = 100 75
Figure 31:
Evolution of yield per unit of output, EU-25 2004-06, EU-27 2007-12 76
Figure 32:
Evolution of subsidies, EU-25 2004-06, EU-27 2007-12 77
Figure 33:
Evolution of specific crop and livestock costs and total farming overheads, EU-25 2004-
16, EU27 2007-12 78
Figure 34:
Evolution of specific crop and livestock costs per farm, EU-25 2004-06, EU-27 2007-12 79
Figure 35:
Evolution of the elements of total farm overheads, EU-25 2004-06, EU-27 2007-12 80
Figure 36:
Evolution of value of outstanding loans and annual interest per farm, EU-25 2004-2006,
EU-27 2007-2012 81
Figure 37:
Evolution of labour use and wages paid per farm, EU-25 2004-2006, EU-27 2007-2012 82
Figure 38:
FNVA/AWU and FFI/FWU by Member State (2010-2012 average) 85
Figure 39:
FADN coverage of economic farm size (ES) by Member State, 2010-2012 86
Figure 40:
Change in FFI/FWU, average 2010-2012 vs average 2004-2006 89
Figure 41:
Annual change in FFI/FWU, 2010-11 and 2011-12 90
Figure 42:
Coefficient of variation of farm income indicators by Member State, 2004-12 91
Figure 43:
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
9
FFI/FWU by farm type and Member State, 2010-2012 average, EU-27 = 100 92
Figure 44:
FFI/FWU by Economic Size and Member State, 2010-2012 average, EU-27 = 100 95
Figure 45:
Paid wages per hour (2010-12 average) 97
Figure 46:
Coefficient of variation in paid wages by Member State, 2004-2012 99
Figure 47:
The calculation of Economic Indicators in the FADN 124
LIST OF BOXES
Box 1:
The economic functions of profit 18
Box 2:
The Treaty statement of the objectives of the Common Agricultural Policy 24
Box 3:
CAP aims as articulated in Agenda 2000 (European Commission, 1997) 25
Box 4:
Reasons for non-adoption of household statistics 27
Box 5:
Definition of indicators used in the Economic Accounts for Agriculture 32
Box 6:
Definition of indicators used in the Farm Accountancy Data Network 33
Box 7:
Statements by the Commission on the relative position of incomes in agriculture 37
Box 8:
Pluriactive farm operators in the EU-27 39
Box 9:
Safety net for farm households (based on Gundersen et al., 2000) 103
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
10
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
11
EXECUTIVE SUMMARY
Introduction
The purpose of this study for the European Parliament, as set out in the Terms of
Reference, is to:
Provide an overview of the income developments of EU agriculture.
Examine the different dynamics of farming incomes (changes, amplitudes of
movements, stability) and their main drivers.
Analyse the disparities across Member States and aggregates.
Provide recommendations in order to adjust the CAP income support and national
policies to counteract current trends.
This purpose has to be achieved within the context of what the Terms of Reference describe
as the central aim of the Common Agricultural Policy to ensure a fair standard of living for
the agricultural community, in particular by increasing the individual earnings of persons
engaged in agriculture.
The Terms of Reference also make it clear that data sources and methodologies for making
the comparative analysis are the responsibility of the authors of the briefing note. With that
in mind, the chosen staring point is a review of the incomes of agricultural households and
in particular the incomes they receive from independent activity in agriculture (their self-
employment income from farming).
The profit from running a business (which may be called entrepreneurial income) has a
number of economic functions which make it a very important concept in the context of
farmers and agriculture. In particular, it represents both funds generated within the farm
that can be used for consumption, investment and saving and the rewards to the resources
owned by the farmer (including the unpaid labour on the farm).
Profits from agriculture in developed countries such as those of the EU generally suffer from
a long-term downward pressure that help explain structural change and from shorter-term
instability. Furthermore, there are geographical and circumstantial differences between
groups within agriculture.
There are two alternative approaches to measuring entrepreneurial incomes in agriculture:
aggregate accounting as used by the Economic Accounts for Agriculture (EAA) drawn
up by Eurostat and microeconomic accounting as used by the EU’s Farm Accountancy
Data Network (FADN). Both have important limitations, and there are also
methodological differences between them that have relevance for their use in the context of
this brief.
However, profit from agriculture is only part of the income picture for many farm
households and a focus on their returns from agriculture will therefore present only a
partial picture of the farm household’s income, which is a main determinant of the farmer’s
standard of living.
Data sources and methodological explanations
Literature has been drawn on to establish the main types of comparison relevant to this
study. This has been followed by an in-depth analysis of the statistical systems that
generate income data in the EU, and a detailed and independent analysis of what the data
show (presented in Chapters 3 to 5).
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
12
For statistics on the incomes of agricultural households key definitions for use in the
monitoring and guidance of agricultural policy have been worked out by Eurostat and at
international level by the FAO. The most appropriate indicator is considered to be the net
disposable income of households (covering income from farming and other gainful
activities, from property, pensions and other transfers, and after the deduction of personal
taxes and other non-optional payments). Possible data sources to furnish these statistics
are considered; these vary between Member States.
For income that arises from agricultural activity indicators based on the Economic Accounts
for Agriculture are calculated by Eurostat, but these are only available at the national level.
However, the Farm Accountancy Data Network (FADN) calculates indicators at the level of
the farm business and these can be used to illustrate detailed patterns in the agricultural
industry.
Two FADN indicators are appropriate in the present context. Farm Net Value Added
(FNVA) represents the rewards to all the fixed factors used in the farm business,
irrespective of their ownership. Farm Family Income (FFI) is after the further deduction
of the costs of hired labour, interest paid and rent paid and is the return to the farmer for
the use of his own labour, own land and own capital; it represents the amount generated
by the farm business that is available for consumption, investment and saving.
FFI expressed per business or per work unit of family (unpaid) labour (FFI/FWU) is the
preferred income concept for this analysis because it corresponds most closely to the
concept of the profit from farming that is available to support the living standards of
farmers. Because incomes are subject to much short-term instability, where possible,
averages are taken across three adjacent years; the main study period is 2010-2012.
Overview of the income development of EU agriculture
There is currently no working statistical system at EU level for agricultural household
incomes. Structural statistics for EU agriculture make it clear that many farmers (at least a
third, and more if other members of their household are included) also have other gainful
activities. National results where available show that other incomes not only raise the
household income levels of farm families, but also add to its stability.
Furthermore, the evidence points to farmers NOT being a particularly low-income sector of
society in most Member States judged on the basis of their household disposable incomes.
This is of obvious importance to the CAP’s aim to ensure a fair standard of living of the
agricultural community.
In terms of incomes from agricultural activity, the focus of this report, it is clear that the
income indicators at aggregate level (Eurostat) and farm level (FADN), where they share
similar concepts, tend to move in similar fashion. The two FADN indicators (FNVA/AWU
and FFI/FWU) are also closely aligned in their directions of change over time.
Among the various groups of Member States in common usage, in absolute terms FFI/FWU
is highest in the EU-15, then the EU-N10 and lowest in the EU-N2. FFI/FWU increased over
the 2004 to 2012 period with a substantial decline between 2007 and 2009 in all groupings
with the exception of EU-N2.
For the EU-27, a strong relationship exists between the economic size of farm business and
the average levels of income generated. This applies not only to FFI per farm (as might be
expected) but, more importantly, income per unit of family labour (FFI/FWU). Care has to
be exercised in interpreting results for small farms because only some Member States are
represented because of the application of different thresholds for inclusion in FADN; only
for size classes with Standard Output of
€25
,000 and over are all countries represented.
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
13
That said, in each farming type the smallest farms have the lowest incomes, and absolute
incomes per FWU increase with farm size.
Incomes differ between the various types of farming, granivores having the highest
incomes, and mixed farms the lowest. Granivores also tend to dominate in the largest size
groups.
This relationship between farm size and income levels permeates other differences, such as
between farms of different legal status and age of farmer, with the observed patterns
largely explainable by differences in farm size.
Incomes of farms in Less Favoured Areas were lower than those in non-Less Favoured
Areas, even after including the special payments that the former receive.
It is clear that the variability of income over time in FADN results at the group level is much
greater in the smallest size class of farms, though it should be recalled that this omits data
from many Member States because of the differing size thresholds applied. Beyond that,
variation increases with farm size.
Granivore and Fieldcrop farms have the greatest volatility of income. The most stable
incomes are found in the ‘Horticulture’ and Other permanent crops’ sectors.
When income volatility is measured at the level of the individual farm 55% of large farms
and 38% of small farms experienced income volatility of ±30% from the previous three
year average.
The distribution of income at the farm level is very unequal; 20% of the labour force
generates 78% of the FFI. Furthermore, incomes averaged over three years 2010-2012
were negative for large parts of the farm labour force, suggesting that additional factors,
such as income from other gainful activities, is important in explaining the ability of such
farms to survive.
For the dependent (paid) section of the labour force, agricultural worker income (wages)
increased steadily (in nominal terms) over the 2004-12 period with only the EU-N2 group
experiencing a decline in 2008 and the EU-N10 one in 2009. The pay of agricultural
workers in the EU-N10 converged with that in the EU-15 over the period, but pay in the EU-
N2 did not. Agricultural wages per hour differ across farming type, being highest in the
wine sector and lowest in ‘Other grazing livestock’ andFieldcrops farm types.
The dynamics of farm incomes and the key drivers
For agricultural households with income from other gainful activities, earnings from
property and/or pensions and transfers, the drivers of this non-farm income are largely
those that shape the general economy. Some 12% of EU-27 farms also draw income from
on-farm diversified activities, and these increase with farm scale; this income is also driven
by general economic factors, although some will be related to the agricultural economy.
The most important component of agricultural revenue is returns from the market
which account for 86% of FADN Total Output for the EU-27.
Market returns are driven by quantity of output and price. Yields have been relatively
stable, but prices, especially for crops, have fluctuated considerably over the 2005 to 2012
period.
Subsidies make up the balance of Total Output; there is no suggestion that changes in
subsidies have played a major role in the evolution of income.
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
14
The most important cost element is total intermediate consumption which accounts for two-
thirds of total expenses for the EU-27. Depreciation accounts for 15% of total costs, wages
paid 9%, rent 5% and interest payments 3%.
Total intermediate consumption is made up of total specific costs (crop and livestock) and
overheads (machinery and building costs, energy, contract work and direct inputs). These
elements of intermediate consumption have all increased between 2004 and 2012, but
specific crop costs have increased the least. Within specific crop costs, fertiliser cost is the
most volatile element. Within overheads, energy costs have been the most volatile and
showed the sharpest absolute increase.
Although the use of paid labour has declined, wages paid per farm increased steadily
between 2007 and 2012.
The importance of these income components differs by farm type. Subsidies account for
a quarter of the value of total output in Other grazing livestockfarms, but less than 5% in
the horticulture, granivore and wine sectors. There is less difference in the relative
importance of costs by farm type, although paid wages are more important in the
horticulture and wine sectors.
Analysis by farm size shows that the relative importance of subsidies decreases as farm
size increases.
Differences between Member States
A Common Agricultural Policy does not appear to result in a common absolute level of
income for the average farm in different Member States. Belgium, Denmark, Germany,
France, Luxembourg, the Netherlands and the UK stand out as having high farm incomes.
Amongst the EU-N10 Member States, only in the Czech Republic, Estonia and Hungary do
farm income indicators exceed or come close to the EU-27 average.
The main reason for this is the economic size of farms; the mix of farm types also plays a
role. However, when farms of the same size and type are compared, performance is often
equivalent throughout the EU-28 and sometimes higher in the EU-N10 and EU-N2 than it is
in the EU-15.
The influence of farm structure is also important at the regional level with farm incomes
varying widely within Member States. This regional variation is especially noticeable in
France and Germany.
In terms of the growth in farm incomes between figures averaged for the 2004-06 and
2010-12 periods, EU-N10 Member States have outperformed EU-15 Member States as a
result of higher market prices, access to the single market and increased public support.
The increase in farm income per unit of labour in these Member States also reflects
decreases in total labour use. Despite these increases, farm income in the EU-N10 and
especially the EU-N2 lags behind that in the EU-15.
Within this overall trend, farm incomes are highly variable from year to year, but farm
incomes in different Member States move in different directions and by different
magnitudes, partly the result of structural difference in farm type.
Some Member States have higher levels of income variation than others. Again this is
partly structural with income in the granivore and fieldcrop sectors relatively unstable while
income in horticulture and permanent crops is relatively stable. The relatively low variability
in farm income seen in Greece, Spain and Italy reflects the substantial proportion of other
permanent crop farm types in these Member States.
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
15
There is a tendency for EU-N12 Member States to have higher coefficients of variation than
EU-15 Member States, but this is partly the result of the general upward trend in farm
incomes that these Member States have experienced.
Farm income levels differ between Member States within farm type, although this is partly
the result of the structure of farms within FADN. A key factor in differences between
Member States by farm type is actually farm size within the FADN sample.
As economic size increases, it becomes more common for farms from the EU-N10 to show
higher FFI/FWU than farms in the EU-15. For the largest size group, only farms in Italy and
the UK from the EU-15 have farm income higher than the EU-27 average.
Agricultural wages differ markedly between Member States. In Denmark, the Netherlands
and Sweden wage levels average more than
€15 per hour while in Bulgaria, Greece, Latvia,
Lithuania, Poland and Romania the average is €3 or less.
Agricultural wages vary little within Member States, although there are some exceptions
with wages higher in Champagne than in the rest of France and higher in the east of
Germany where the wages of company farm managers and administrators are included in
the figures.
Recommendations for future income support under the CAP
Based on our analysis the recommendations to the European Parliament are that:
Further consideration is given to the re-establishment of EU statistics on the
incomes of agricultural households, since they are needed to assess the extent to
which the CAP is achieving this core objective of a fair standard of living.
Data sources that relate to the entire economic activities of the households (and
other institutional units) that operate farms should be encouraged.
A study be undertaken to assess the relative attributes of a safety net for the
incomes of farm households for the EU, including its costs, and the necessary
technical conditions that would be required for it to operate successfully.
When considering the need for support of incomes, the wealth of agricultural
holdings should be taken into account.
Suitable caveats should be used when FADN data are reported to make clear the
impact of the field of observation on the results.
Consideration should be given to the need to represent people (the operators of
farm holdings) rather than production. A suitable balance needs to be struck
between the current production/land use focus of FADN and the social impact of the
CAP.
Attention should be diverted away from interventions that attempt to combat
instability directly at the farm level and towards risk management schemes that
prepare farm operators to better anticipate and cope with instability. This could
involve further studies.
Consideration should be given as to how the occupiers of small farms can enhance
their economic prospects by building their skills and other forms of human capital.
We recommend that policies that increase market participation and ease the
adjustment of farm businesses and households should be further supported and that
current impediments to access be examined.
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
16
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
17
1. INTRODUCTION
The purpose of this detailed briefing note for the European Parliament, as set out in the
Terms of Reference, is to:
Provide an overview of the income developments of EU agriculture.
Examine the different dynamics of farming incomes (changes, amplitudes of
movements, stability) and their main drivers.
Analyse the disparities across Member States and aggregates.
Provide recommendations in order to adjust the CAP income support and national
policies to counteract current trends.
This purpose has to be achieved within the context of what the Terms of Reference describe
as the central aim of the Common Agricultural Policy to ensure a fair standard of living for
the agricultural community, in particular by increasing the individual earnings of persons
engaged in agriculture.
The Terms of Reference also make it clear that data sources and methodologies for making
the comparative analysis are the responsibility of the authors of the briefing note.
KEY FINDINGS
Entrepreneurial income (less formally called business profit’) has a number of
economic functions which make it a very important concept in the context of
farmers and agriculture.
Profits from agriculture are generally suffering from long-term downward pressure
and shorter-term instability and there are geographical and circumstantial
differences between groups within agriculture.
However, profit from agriculture is only part of the income picture for many
farm households and a focus on returns from agriculture will therefore present only
a partial picture of farm household income.
There are two possible approaches to measuring entrepreneurial incomes in
agriculture: aggregate accounting as used by the Economic Accounts for
Agriculture (EAA), drawn up by Eurostat, and microeconomic accounting as used
by the EU’s Farm Accountancy Data Network (FADN). Both have important
methodological limitations and there are also methodological differences between
them that have relevance for their use. Neither at present is capable of describing
the overall income situations of the households that operate farms, which represents
a major gap in the information needed to assess the performance of the CAP in
relation to its stated objectives.
The evidence on Comparison of Farmers Incomes in the EU Member States’ and its
accompanying analysis presented in this Report needs to be put in context. This section
does so by presenting the functions of income (for farmers the essential component of
which is profits from their agricultural activity), the characteristics of incomes in
agriculture, the approaches taken to incomes within accounting systems, and the
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
18
relationship between policy aims and measurements of income. Further contextual
information is provided in Hill (2012), FAO (2011) and UN (2008).
1.1. The economic function of profit from farming
The large majority of EU farms are arranged as independent units (businesses operated by
households or corporations) and thus farmers receive their rewards from agriculture in the
form of entrepreneurial income, or less formally, business profit. For household firms
entrepreneurial income is a hybrid, in the sense that it is a mix of rewards for the unpaid
labour provided by the family, for using its own land and capital, and for the risk-taking
and management function. Ways in which this income is defined and measured will be
considered later, but at the outset it is worth noting why there is interest for purposes
related to the CAP in observing changes and differences in entrepreneurial incomes
(various forms of comparisons over time and place and circumstance).
In the EU’s modern competitive market economy profit performs important economic
functions as shown in the Box below.
Box 1: The economic functions of profit
Profit is the reward from production, and is the residual remaining to the operators
of businesses (including farms) once the costs of inputs, wages paid to hired labour,
rent paid to landowners, interest paid on loans and an estimate of depreciation have
been deducted from the value of sales and other forms of revenue. Profit reflects the
risks that the farmer is taking and the use of his/her own factors of production
including labour.
Profits signal to producers where expansion or contraction of production should take
place as they reflect changes in market prices (driven by changes in demand) and
costs.
Profits enable the most efficient firms to expand.
Profits provide the incentive for innovation.
Profits are therefore key to explaining structural change, although it should be
noted that income from non-agricultural activities is also a factor here.
In addition to its economic functions, the business structure of EU agriculture, with the
numerical dominance of the small family farms
2
, means that profits from farming form an
important component of the personal incomes of most farmers’ households, though they
often also have other income sources (see below).
1.2. Characteristics of incomes in agriculture
The literature shows that agriculture is characterised by a number of features that have to
be understood if income comparisons over time and place and circumstance are to be
understood.
The long-term downward pressure on incomes (comparison over time).
Historical evidence shows that agriculture in economically developed countries is
caught in a cost-price squeeze. On the one hand, the prices that farmers receive for
their output is in long-run decline because the supply of farm products has
2
According to the 2010 Farm Structure Survey there were 12 million farms in the EU-28, 97% of which were
single holder operations.
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
19
expanded faster than the demand for them. Technological advances in production
processes (new varieties of crops, improved livestock, more and better machinery
and fertilisers, etc.), which it is in the interest of the individual farmer to adopt,
have led to greater volumes of production, whereas in contrast factors that affect
demand (such as the size of the market and willingness of people to spend more on
food) have changed much less. The outcome has been a fall in the real value of the
net margin between costs and revenues remaining to the sector as a whole, and
thus a fall in the relative position of average rewards to productive resources (in
particular labour) in agriculture compared with those available in the rest of the
economy. This in turn has led to structural change (such as the migration of labour
out of agriculture, the reduction in numbers of smaller farms and the absorption of
their land by larger ones). This downward pressure on incomes in agriculture is a
result of the basic economics of supply and demand and shows the competitive
market economy performing its normal role in bringing about change.
Shorter-term income instability (comparisons over time). Superimposed on
the long-term trend are shorter-term movements in income which, mostly, reflect
the market doing its job in better matching shorter-term supply and demand. There
are medium-term diversions from the long-term trend, resulting, for example, from
natural disasters or political events that interrupt supply or demand. There will be
inter-seasonal variations caused by good or poor growing conditions that lead to
temporary over or under-supply. There are also regular seasonal price variations
and random market ones. Thus farmers face an inherently unstable income
situation. Farmers are expected to manage most of these risk factors as part of their
normal operation.
The heterogeneous nature of agriculture (comparisons over space and
circumstance). Farms differ greatly in terms of the types of production taking
place on them (their farming type), their size (measured in terms of land area or
economic size), the diversity of natural conditions they face (climate, soil, slope,
altitude, etc.), labour force (numbers of workers and composition), and region. Even
within one type/size/region group there will be differences in income brought about
by differences in management ability, the age profile and experiences of farmers,
etc. It is worth noting that the Commission has drawn a distinction between income
disparities, income dispersion, and income distribution (CEC, 1985b). Disparities
refer to the differences in average incomes between groups (such as between
Member States or types of farming); a specific type of disparity which is of
significance to achieving the official aims of the CAP is the relative incomes of
farmers and those of the rest of the EU population. Income dispersion refers to
the deviations of the individual figures within a given group from the average for the
group. Income distribution refers to the breakdown of farmers (and/or other units
of labour) according to income classes. This in-depth analysis deals with all three,
within the constraints of available data.
Observation of the documentation, discussion and practice of policy suggests that farmers
and their households are caught up in income problems that are widespread and
characterise the agriculture industry. These income problems are as follows:
The particularly low incomes in certain regions or sizes of farm (the poverty issue).
At the same time the occupiers of other farms may have high incomes, so that the
heterogeneity of the income situation presents a problem in describing the (income)
poverty issue in agriculture as a whole and in designing policy to address it.
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
20
The variations of income experienced by the individual farm over time (the
instability issue). Again this may vary between region, type and size of farm.
However, it is readily shown that instability as measured by group averages greatly
understates the degree of instability experienced at the level of the individual farm
business (for a review of this evidence see Hill (2012), Chapter 4). An implication is
that the measurement of income in a single year is unlikely to be a reliable indicator
of the income of a farm over a run of years; empirical evidence suggests that an
average over three years is preferable and this is the approach we take in this
report where possible. While incomes from agricultural activity are inherently
unstable, the presence of other income may dampen the impact on total farm
household income; this appears to be usually the situation. This means that farm
household income is usually more stable than agricultural income.
The general levels of rewards of those engaged in farming compared with earnings
in other sectors (the parity issue). This is often expressed in terms of the incomes
of people working in agriculture compared with those in other groups in society or
the national average. However, for self-employed farmers these incomes are a mix
of rewards to labour, capital and land and the issue of parity includes the return to
investments in land and capital assets as well as to labour. A major factor in
explaining the apparently low reward to land is that its value is determined in a
market, typically very small in relation to the total stock that is often dominated, on
the demand side, by existing farmers trying to expand to reap the benefits of
spreading fixed costs and technical advances that require larger-scale production.
However, expanding farmers typically bid up land prices to levels that are
determined by their margins over variable costs, not by total costs, and thus land
appears very expensive in relation to average profits.
Partly as a result of this last point, and because in market economies public support
of farm incomes tends to be capitalised into higher land prices
3
, income problems
are often seen among farm occupiers that are often also owners of substantial
amounts of wealth. Wealth is even more unequally distributed than are incomes,
and farmers who own land are likely to have a markedly different economic status
from those who are tenants or where land rights are poorly defined. It is worth
noting that the wealth of farm households is usually ignored when discussing the
need for policy intervention to tackle income problems.
The first three of these points are the same trio of central components of the farm
problem that have been identified in the United States and summarised by Gardner
(1992).
Parity and poverty are concerned essentially with the welfare of farmers and their
dependants. Instability is somewhat different. A low farm income in a single year may not
immediately throw the recipients into the poverty category. Reserves will be drawn on or
borrowings made to maintain living standards through times of temporary financial
setback. Thus in industrialised countries it is important to distinguish between those farm
households that have to contend with occasional periods of low income and those that
suffer hardship from incomes that are persistently low. However, when year-to-year
fluctuations are anticipated, the level of consumption by farmers and their households may
have to be curtailed in order to set aside reserves for years of low incomes or to pay for
past borrowing in lean years. Farmers may have to be content with generating a safer but
3
See, for example, European Parliament (2013b); Swinnen, et al. (2008); and the Framework 7 project Factor
Markets, Grant agreement N°: 245123-FP7-KBBE-2009-3 http://www.factormarkets.eu/content/rural-land-
market
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
21
lower income, with consequences both for consumption possibilities and the potential for
the business to grow.
A further characteristic of agriculture in the EU that must be borne in mind is the business
structure of farms. As noted above, the large majority of EU farms, in terms of numbers,
are arranged as unincorporated businesses that are operated by households (the relevance
of this for income accounting is covered below). In EU structural statistics these are
returned as farms operated by ‘natural persons’, in contrast with farms arranged as
companies or similar forms which have their own legal status (‘legal persons’). In practice
this means that:
On farms operated by households no clear distinction can be drawn between the
business income and assets of the farm and the personal income and wealth of the
farmer and his immediate household. This is of importance when assessing the sums
that are available to support the living standards of the farm household.
Because many farm households have additional sources beyond what they receive
from farming, the income obtained from farming activity is not a reliable guide to
the total or disposable income of the household, usually taken as an important
determinant of potential consumption spending and thus of the standard of living of
the household.
Because in international accounting systems households are seen as being engaged
in both consumption and (as in agriculture) production activities, great care has to
be taken not to confuse and misuse indicators of one function for the other. As will
be seen below, in reality indicators of the rewards from farm production have often
been used as proxies for household disposable income, leading to importance
misunderstandings of the need for and effectiveness of spending under the
CAP.
1.3. Accounting systems and agricultural incomes
Accounting systems allow for the possibility of basing the measurement of incomes on
institutional units (e.g. family farms) or activities (e.g. agricultural production). Within this
structure, each approach can be taken at the level of the aggregate (industry/sector) or of
the individual unit (farm or household). Within the EU’s statistical system aggregate
accounting is represented by the Economic Accounts for Agriculture (EAA) (based in
national accounts) which are drawn up by Eurostat for the EU and Member States.
Microeconomic accounting, built up from individual units, is used to produce the EU’s
Farm Accountancy Data Network (EU-FADN) and household accounts, such as in the
EU Statistics on Income and Living Conditions (EU-SILC). For historic reasons,
accounting systems and income measurement in agriculture have been based on farming
activities and not the more appropriate farm household unit (when measuring incomes that
relate to the standards of living). This has resulted in misunderstandings and potentially
inappropriate policies.
The UN’s System of National Accounts (SNA) is probably the most universally accepted
set of international accounting conventions and is the basis of the European System of
Accounts (ESA). With roots going back some fifty years, the SNA has formed the basis of
much of the economic statistics that already exist for agriculture in countries at all levels of
economic development. The SNA, though aggregate in nature, also commonly acts as a
benchmark for micro-economic accounting.
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
22
Two main approaches towards accounting for agriculture can be found within the SNA
accounting framework:
accounts for the activity of producing commodities (goods and services) deemed
to be agricultural according to agreed international classification, together with their
residual income’ concepts;
accounts for institutional units that engage in agricultural production; these
form three main types:
households, in their role as units of production (household-firms), and for
which agricultural activity is one (possibly the only) form of independent activity
(self-employment) that the household members engage in. The household may
also engage in dependent activity (its members work as employees) and may
also receive resources in other ways (for example, from welfare transfers,
property income, etc.). The independent agricultural activity may account for
various shares of the total resources available to the household;
corporations, at least part of whose activity involves agricultural production;
and,
other types (including government and Non-Profit Institutions).
Of course, as these are part of a single system, they relate to each other (see Hill, 2003).
Figure 1 illustrates this relationship in an agricultural context. It shows that agricultural
activity is divided between the various types of institutional units that are involved
in entrepreneurial activity.
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
23
Figure 1: The relationship between agricultural activity and the institutional units
that generate it
4
REAL INSTITUTIONAL UNITS
Mixed income
(Operating
surplus of
agricultural Local
Kind of Activity
Units (LKAUs)
HOUSEHOLDS-AGRICULTURAL
OTHER
HOUSEHOLDS
CORPORATIONS
OTHER
Entrepreneurial income from
agricultural
activity
Other income
from independent
and dependent
activity transfers
etc.
Other
EI
Kitchen
gardens
Source: Hill (2003).
Activity accounts which cover the value of production of agricultural commodities and the
associated costs can only, strictly, be taken to the level of Operating Surplus (value
added minus the cost of paid labour). To go further to estimate Entrepreneurial Income by
the further deduction of interest and rent payments means attributing these to specific
activities. This requires assumptions about the extent to which the farm household is
involved in other (non-agricultural) activities and how these payments should be allocated.
For example, the extent to which any of the interest payment relate to non-farming
activities or consumption goods. However, such assumptions are often made by the array
of indicators commonly in use. Both aggregate income indicators developed by Eurostat
from the EAA and microeconomic indicators within FADN make such assumptions.
The nature of what constitutes an agricultural household (or an agricultural corporation)
is critical to the generation of statistics and can affect both the numbers of households and
the income levels and compositions relating to them. The concept of a household (which
may take a variety of forms) and the basis used to classify them as agricultural or non-
agricultural (for which several possibilities exist) is discussed in Chapter 3.1.
4
Also used in Hill and Platt (2003) and FAO (2011). An agricultural Local Kind of Activity Unit (LKAU) is the
fictional basic statistical unit concerned with agricultural production and for which accounting for output,
intermediate consumption, etc. is possible. It may form part of an institutional unit (such as a farm business
operated by a household), but does not include any non-agricultural activities in which the farm may engage
other than those that are inseparable in the data sources (such as minor farm-gate sales). See Eurostat
(2000).
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
24
1.4. Policy aims and appropriate measures of income
A major issue that has to be confronted when reviewing the information on incomes in EU
agriculture is that there is a mismatch between the declared aims of the CAP and the
indicators that are available to monitor the policy’s performance. As will become clear, in
reality accounts drawn up on the basis of institutions (such as farm households) are
relatively poorly developed, whether at sector or microeconomic levels. In contrast,
accounts for the activity of agricultural production are well established at both levels
and the indicators are in common use.
One source of the aims of policy is what appears in official statements. On the one hand,
the Treaty is clear that a central concern is with the living standards of the agricultural
community, though Hill (2012) points out that this rather general objective has not been
articulated in a more precise and testable form. First seen in the 1957 Treaty of Rome
(Article 39), the wording has been carried forward into subsequent Treaties, including the
2012 Consolidated Version of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union (Official
Journal of the European Union, C326, 26 October, 2012). The implication is that the 1957
wording has been the basis of giving legal validity to any proposed policy measures since
the start of the CAP and continues to do so.
Box 2: The Treaty statement of the objectives of the Common Agricultural Policy
5
The Treaty states that ‘The common agricultural policy shall have as its objectives:
a) To increase agricultural productivity by promoting technical progress and by
ensuring the rational development of agricultural production and the optimum
utilisation of the factors of production, in particular labour.
b) Thus to ensure a fair standard of living for the agricultural community, in
particular by the increasing of the individual earnings of persons engaged
in agriculture [emphasis added].
c) To stabilise markets.
d) To assure the availability of supplies.
e) To ensure that supplies reach consumers at reasonable prices.’
The Agenda 2000 agreement, though lacking the full authority of a Treaty, also
articulated the CAP’s aims, carrying over the fair standard of living’ phrase but also adding
an assurance of promoting income stability and of expanding on how farmers might be
assisted by providing alternative sources of livelihood.
5
Official Journal of the European Union, C326/47, Article 39, pp62-63.
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
25
Box 3: CAP aims as articulated in Agenda 2000 (European Commission, 1997)
[To] 'increase competitiveness internally and externally in order to ensure that
Union producers take full advantage of positive world market developments.
Food safety and food quality, which are both fundamental obligations towards
consumers.
Ensuring a fair standard of living for the agricultural community and contributing
to the stability of farm incomes [emphasis added].
The integration of environmental goals into the CAP.
Promotion of sustainable agriculture.
The creation of alternative job and income opportunities for farmers and
their families [emphasis added].
Simplification of Union legislation'.
To ensure that supplies reach consumers at reasonable prices.’
Another indication of the persistence of the CAP aim of ensuring a fair standard of living of
the agricultural communityis that these words are incorporated into the Regulations that
give the legal basis for spending on agriculture from the EU budget. For example,
Regulation (EC) No 1308/2013 establishing a common organisation of the markets in
agricultural products uses these same words, following a convention demonstrated in the
superseded legislation. When referring to support of particular commodities, the aim of
ensuring the living standards of growers concerned is also mentioned. The apparent
requirement for this aim to be stated in Regulations, linking back to the fundamental
Treaties, should be noted, even if what the phrase means is far from transparent.
The need for income information relevant to the standard of living of farmers, as a major
component of the agricultural community however defined, is supported by a number of EU
and other international organisations. It was the basis of Eurostat’s establishment of its
Income of the Agricultural Households Sector (IAHS) statistics in the late 1980s (see
Eurostat 1996, 2002), was commented on by the European Court of Auditors as something
that the Commission should monitor
6
(ECA, 2004), was the subject of studies and a policy
brief by the OECD (OECD 2002, 2003, 2004), and was the driver for the drafting of a
Handbook covering statistics on agricultural households (in two editions, UNECE 2007 and
FAO 2011) under the auspices of the UNECE, FAO, OECD, the World Bank and Eurostat.
Agra CEAS Consulting (2007) investigated the feasibility of reintroducing a rebased IAHS
for Eurostat, although this has not been acted upon. There are many other commentators
and researchers who also interpret the income situation of farmer households as at the
centre of the purpose of the CAP (reviewed in Hill 2012).
Given that there would appear to be an obvious need to know about the standard of living
of the agricultural community for policy purposes, statisticians are faced with the task of
turning the concepts of standard of living and agricultural community into operational
entities (indicators) before the process of actual measurement by data collection can take
place. Indicators should be closely aligned with the policy impact that is required and be
sensitive to the extent of that impact. When attempting to devise practical indicators for
the standard of living it is conventional to use disposable income of the household or the
average per household member, as this represents their potential command over the
consumption of goods and services, though it has to be acknowledged that some factors
which may be important to farm families (such as their independence and work
6
The ECA (2004) noted that ‘Although this is only one of the five objectives of agricultural policy expressly stated
in the EC Treaty, the income of the agricultural community runs like a leitmotif through the CAP’.
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
26
environment) are not captured. Farm families are typically asset-rich, and there are ways
in which the wealth of farm households can be taken into account; wealth itself provides a
potential command over goods and services, and estimates of economic status’ combine
current income with an annuitized value of net worth, though this indicator has not so far
taken a significant part in EU agricultural statistics.
The agricultural community is similarly a concept that has to be made operational.
Again, alternatives approaches are possible (see Hill, 1990). The consensus is that (a) this
is made up of households, rather than individuals; (b) it is made up of the households
where income from independent activity in agriculture (that is, entrepreneurial income) is
part of the household’s total income, though various criteria can be used to, for example,
separate those households where farming is the main source of income from those where it
is a minor part. It should be noted that hired workers on farms are not treated as part of
the agricultural community according to this approach as their incomes are not residual
profits; this is not considered satisfactory in some countries where agriculture is dominated
by large corporate (and similar) units, and even where farms in other countries are
arranged as private companies; to answer such problems Eurostat proposed a series of
add-ons’ to the strict coverage.
As has been noted above, despite the apparent need for income statistics to be available
that relate to agricultural households and to agricultural activity, in practice there is no
working system for agricultural household income statistics in the EU. Eurostat’s
IAHS statistics, which was a pioneer in this area when it started in the late 1980s, was
terminated in 2002 for reasons that included problems with quality (especially in Member
States using national accounting methodology), lack of comparability across Member
States, low priority given to developing these statistics at a time of declining resources,
and, in some administrations, concerns with the results that showed farmers as a group to
have household incomes broadly comparable with the rest of society (with some
exceptions). Instead, indicators taken from activity accounts are dominant, though they are
incapable of answering central questions on the income of agricultural households that are
crucial to illuminating the living standards of farmers.
UNECE 2007 offers some suggestions as to why (taken from Hill, 2000), which can be
adapted to the present circumstances (see Box 4).
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
27
Box 4: Reasons for non-adoption of household statistics
Lack of political demand. Politicians have not requested this information, perhaps
because of a too-simple perception of the agricultural industry, or a fear of the electoral
consequences of drawing attention to results that suggest that farmers are in a
relatively favourable income position.
Historical precedent. Activity accounts, at both aggregate and farm levels, and their
related incomeindicators are long-established, having been set up when there were
stronger grounds for assuming that the only source of incomes of farm households was
from farming. In the EU, the EAA adopted the Branchconcept at its outset in 1964; as
did the FADN basic legislation of 1965.
Operational requirement. The fact is that the CAP has operated apparently
successfully for many years in many countries without information on the incomes of
agricultural households. The administration of income support systems has rarely if ever
required the data (though some tests of eligibility have been applied within individual
structural schemes).
‘Rational ignorance’ among many users. There is a tendency among users,
especially non-specialists, to adopt satisficing behaviour. That is, they take the first
available indicator that appears to meet their needs, so that measure of the income
from agricultural activity may be assumed to show the income of farmers. Among some
users there may be a suspicion that the information revealed by household-firm data
could be against their political and/or bureaucratic interests.
Self-interest of bureaucracies. Government departments for agriculture have often
taken a pro-farmer stance and might therefore not wish to draw attention to anything
that might lead to a reduction in support for the industry, as might be revealed by
statistics on household income. There is also an understandable aim of wishing to
maintain continuity with long-established systems of activity accounting.
Data availability. Lack of basic data of suitable quality in some countries is a major
constraint in the development of statistics on the complete activities of farm businesses
and their households. In countries where it has not been conventional to ask questions
on non-farm income, agencies that collect data have been reluctant to ask new
questions about non-farm income for fear of harming response rates.
The importance of knowing about the income situation of farm households does not remove
the importance of knowing what is happening to the rewards from the activity of
agricultural production. For example, these would be helpful in understanding changes in
the supply of farm commodities, in explaining why farmers diversify and take steps to
reduce risk, and why structural change occurs in the industry. The indicators of the rewards
from agricultural production, though superficially more agreed upon among statisticians in
EU Member States than those relating to agricultural households, in fact are based on
concepts that are by no means self-evident. Principle among these are the following:
In both the aggregate Economic Accounts for Agriculture and microeconomic FADN
the basic unit is not the complete farm business. Rather it is only the
agricultural activities taking place on farms and excludes (with small exceptions) any
other gainful activities in which the farm may engage. This may involve
misattribution of the costs of inputs where these are used by both the agricultural
and other activities (such as energy usage). These other activities (which may take
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
28
place on or off the farm) may well be important in explaining the overall
performance and viability of the farm business as an economic unit
7
.
The main indicator at both levels (Net Value Added per Annual Work Unit, in
absolute or index form), though usually labelled as income, is a concept distinctly
different from that of business profit and even further from personal or household
income. It represents the reward to all the fixedfactors of production (all the land
and all the capital irrespective of whether or not owned by the farm operator, and all
the labour whether hired or part of the farmer’s family). When looking at changes
over time the practice of dividing the NVA factor reward by the size of the factor
base has some logic, but taking account of changes in only one fixed factor (labour)
can be objected to on both theoretical grounds (such as attributing any productivity
gains to labour whereas increases in capital may be partly responsible) and practical
ones (at least in some countries statisticians have reservations about the quality of
data on labour input where most of this consists of the contribution of the self-
employed farmer and spouse) (Hill, 1991).
While the EAA Entrepreneurial Income and FADN Family Farm Income
8
(both of
which involve removing the costs of paid labour, paid interest and paid rent) are
reasonable approximations of profit from agricultural production, indicators that go
further and attempt to remove costs for the farmer’s owned land, owned capital and
family (unpaid) labour, singly or together, are on weak ground because of the
difficulty of agreeing on imputed values. This was proposed by the Commission
(CEC, 1982) but soon abandoned. Nevertheless, attempts to use the same dubious
process have been repeatedly made, most recently in 2014
9
.
7
This problem has been behind suggestions that agricultural income statistics at both macroeconomic and
microeconomic levels should be re-engineered and based on real institutional units (in effect, households and
companies). While this would represent a hiatus in agricultural statistics, it would place agriculture on a similar
footing as other industries.
8
The term Farm Net Income (FNI) is used for farms that are arranged as legal entities (such as companies)
within FADN.
9
In EU farm economics overview (European Commission, 2014a) two indicators involving imputation are used.
The concept of Remuneration of family labourinvolves imputing a charge for owned capital and land. The
concept of ‘Return on assets’ involves imputing a cost for family (unpaid) labour.
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
29
2. DATA SOURCES AND METHODOLOGICAL
EXPLANATION
KEY FINDINGS
For statistics on the incomes of agricultural households key definitions for use in
the monitoring and guidance of agricultural policy have been worked out by Eurostat
and at international level by the FAO. The most appropriate indicator is considered
to be the net disposable income of households (covering income from farming
and other gainful activities, from property, pensions and other transfers, and after
the deduction of personal taxes and other non-optional payments). Possible data
sources to furnish these statistics are considered; these vary between Member
States.
For income that arises from agricultural activity the Economic Accounts for
Agriculture calculated by Eurostat are only available at the national level. However,
the Farm Accountancy Data Network (FADN) calculates indicators at the level of the
farm business and can be used to illustrate detailed patterns in the agricultural
industry.
Two indicators are appropriate in the present context. Farm Net Value Added
(FNVA) represents the rewards to all the fixed factors used in the farm business,
irrespective of their ownership. Farm Family Income (FFI) is after the deduction of
the costs of hired labour, interest paid and rent paid and is the return to the farmer
for the use of his own labour, own land and own capital.
FFI expressed per business or per work unit of family (unpaid) labour (FFI/FWU) is
the preferred income concept for this analysis because it corresponds most closely
to the concept of the profit from farming that is available to support the living
standards of farmers.
The evidence on the comparisons required in this report has comprised three main
components. First there was a literature review to establish the nature of the comparisons
of incomes that can be expected to be of concern to policy makers (which will include those
that have featured in regular and occasional reports by the services of the European
Commission). This has been followed by an in-depth analysis of the methodology used by
the statistical systems that generate data about EU agriculture (especially those of the
Commission). Thirdly, and potentially of greatest concern to the European Parliament,
there has been a fresh and independent analysis of the data on the incomes from farming
in the EU and a presentation of results with a commentary on the findings. This means
that, with a few exceptions, our results are not dependent on what is found in
existing publications from the European Commission.
In the light of the objectives of the CAP that appear in the Treaty on the Functioning of the
European Union (TFEU, 2012), attention is given first to data on the incomes of
agricultural households before moving to the rewards from agricultural activity.
Data are not the same as information; information implies the analysis and interpretation
of data in the context of some problem. However, data form an integral part of the
information required for agricultural policy directed at achieving the objects set. As has
already been noted, a major aim of the CAP is directed at the living standards of the
agricultural community, though there are reasons why there is also interest in the levels of
production of agricultural commodities and the way in which these are changing.
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
30
2.1. Data sources on the incomes of agricultural households
As explained above, there is currently no EU statistical system that is capable of
providing information on the living standards of the agricultural community, either
directly or through the conventional proxy of the disposable income of agricultural
households. Despite this, a substantial amount of national information exists, much of
which is relevant to understanding the income problems faced by farmers and their
responses to policy interventions. Data come from three main types of source, each of
which has drawbacks:
National surveys of farm accounts that contribute to FADN (see below) where
these collect information beyond the narrow requirements of FADN and extend to
questions relating to the household (such as income from other gainful activities
and from property and social transfers). However, in many Member States such
surveys do not collect this sort of data.
Taxation and administration records where persons that are members of
agricultural households can be distinguished from those in other socio-professional
groups. Problems with this source are that, in many Member States, some or all
farmers are not taxed according to their personal incomes as shown in accounts
but by various flat rate systems (per hectare, etc.). Operators of farms arranged
as companies may escape coverage (as their directors may not have income from
self-employment in agriculture).
National surveys of households. There are EU-wide networks of household
surveys of expenditure and income and the EU Statistics on Incomes and Living
Conditions (EU-SILC); each of these is capable of providing data on the household
incomes of agricultural households. The main limitations for both are the small
number of cases of farmer households (sometimes very small) that are found
within these surveys at national level and, for countries where numbers are
adequate, issues over the quality of the income data relating to self-employment.
Sometimes these sources are used in combination (for example, France which periodically
combines FADN and tax records, and Ireland which uses farm accounts surveys in
association with its household survey). The situation in each EU-27 Member State is
described in detail in Hill (2012), Chapter 5 and in the online edition of the Wye Group
Handbook
10
.
Though within a single data source the income of agricultural households will generally be
assessed in a consistent way compared with those of other households, care has to be
taken in interpreting results for consistency between sources and between Member
States in three key methodological issues:
Definition of a household. The main alternatives are the single dwelling unit
(individuals under the same roof) and the single budgetary unit (individuals
sharing income and consumption expenditure). Households containing several
generations or siblings are thought to be more common among farmers than
among the general population in some Member States, and these do not
necessarily pool income and expenditure, so a single dwelling may contain several
financially independent budgetary units. Also, it is important to record the number
of individuals in the household and their ages, since income per person and per
10
http://www.fao.org/economic/ess/ess-capacity/wyegroup/wyehandbook/en/
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
31
adult-equivalent (or per consumer unit) is more relevant to potential consumption
expenditure (and hence standards of living) than income of the entire household.
Equivalence scales are used to calculate the number of consumer units.
Definition of an agricultural household. Classification can be on the basis of
income from farming, labour input to farming, or occupation of a farm. The
Eurostat preferred narrow definition for its IAHS statistics was where the main
source of income of the head of household (reference person) was from self-
employment in farming (independent activity in agriculture), though some
countries apply this to the composition of the entire household income. Others
have applied a definition based on the main occupation of the reference person,
which can generate rather different numbers of households and income levels.
Both approaches allow a complete and consistent breakdown of households into
socio-professional groups. A Eurostat broad definition was to include all
households where any member of the household had some income from self-
employment in agriculture, which produces coverage close to that of all farm
occupiers. Such broad approaches include many households for which agriculture is
a very minor component of household income
11
.
Definition of income. There are relatively few contentious issues in the definition
of household income. Total income conventionally includes income from self-
employment, from employment, property and social transfers (including pensions);
capital gains on property (which may be important to farmers in the long-run) are
not included. Disposable income is after the deduction of direct taxes and other
compulsory contributions (such as to social security schemes). FAO 2011 sets out a
definition, based on the recommendations of the Canberra Group (2001), but
slightly adapted to suit farming, that was agreed by contributing international
institutions. There remains the issue of whether income in kind provided by the
farm (such as the ability to acquire fuel for the farmhouse and food produced
directly things that in part determine consumption possibilities) are adequately
treated within the income computation, which suggests that changes over time are
probably more robust than comparisons of disposable income with other socio-
professional groups, such as wage-earners where the role of the household as a
producer (as well as a consumer) is absent or less prominent (such issues are dealt
with extensively in Hill 2012, Chapter 3).
2.2. Data sources on the rewards from agricultural production
Two separate but related systems currently exist by which the rewards from agricultural
production are measured and monitored the aggregate accounts for agriculture produced
by Eurostat using information supplied by statistical authorities in the Member States, and
the microeconomic approach of the Farm Accountancy Data Network (FADN) supervised by
the European Commission (DG AGRI) that gathers information from the accounts of
individual farm businesses. Each level produces an array of indicators, commonly described
as ‘income’ indicators, but in reality relating to the rewards to the owners of factors of
production used in agricultural activity. Both are described in Annex 1. The key points of
relevance to this study are set out in the sub-sections below.
11
In the USA a farm is defined as any place from which $1,000 or more of agricultural products were produced
and sold, or normally would have been sold, during the year. Thus statistics on farm household income has a
wide coverage of farms where agriculture is not the main income source of the operator.
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
32
2.2.1. Economic Accounts for Agriculture (EAA) and its indicators
The EAA methodology involves three current transactional accounts which when linked
together produce net entrepreneurial income for all agricultural production as shown in the
Box below.
Box 5: Definition of indicators used in the Economic Accounts for Agriculture
Output, minus intermediate consumption, minus consumption of fixed capital = Net
Value Added
Net Value Added, minus compensation of employees, minus other taxes on
production, plus other subsidies on production, minus interest paid, minus rent paid =
Net Entrepreneurial Income
Based on these aggregates, three indicators are derived.
Indicator A: Index of the real income of factors in agriculture per annual work
unit. This is calculated by taking the Net Value Added at basic prices that appears in
the Production account and adjusting it by adding ‘other subsidies on production’ (which
includes direct payments to farmers) and deducting ‘other taxes on production’, dividing
by the labour input, and expressing in deflated and index form. NVA in this form is
referred to as being at Factor Cost.
Indicator B: Index of real net agricultural Entrepreneurial Income per unpaid
annual work unit. This is appropriate for countries where agriculture is organised
almost totally as unincorporated holdings (family farms).
Indicator C: Net Entrepreneurial Income of agriculture. This aggregate is given in
absolute terms, but may also be expressed in index form. The important point is that it
is not calculated per unit of non-hired labour and so is suitable for uses involving
countries where the output from corporate farms is an important part of the total.
It is clear that the approach embodied in each of the present Indicators is essentially one of
trying to gauge the rewards to a hybrid bundle of factors used in the production of
agricultural commodities. NVA at Factor Cost is a long way from the personal incomes of
the agricultural community (unless there is no borrowing, no renting of land, no hired
labour and no other sources of income to the household). While Entrepreneurial Income
coincides broadly with what might be seen as profit, it only relates to that originating from
agricultural activity and excludes that which might come from other activities carried on
within the farm business, unless these are very minor.
2.2.2. Farm Accountancy Data Network (FADN) and indicators
At EU level, the farm accounts surveys of all the Member States are brought together under
the co-ordination of the Commission’s Directorate-General for Agriculture and Rural
Development (DG AGRI) as the Farm Accountancy Data Network (FADN). This was
established in 1965 with the specific objective of obtaining data enabling income changes
in the various classes of agricultural holding to be properly monitored (Commission, 1982).
The justification for FADN was rooted in policy, in that ‘...the development of the Common
Agricultural Policy requires that there should be available objective and relevant
information on incomes in the various categories of agricultural holdings and on the
business operation of holdings coming within categories which call for special attention at
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
33
Community level(EEC Regulation 79/65). The FADN is therefore not a single survey but is
an amalgamation of national surveys carried out by Member States.
There is a minimum size threshold, set to capture commercial farmsthat varies between
Member States, reflecting their different farm size structures as shown in the periodic EU
Farm Structure Survey. Consequently, while the overwhelming majority of farming activity
falls within the FADN field of observation, only 42% of the EU’s agricultural holdings found
in its farm structure survey are represented (2015). Figures vary widely between countries.
For example, in Slovakia only 17% of farms are covered by FADN, but these represent 96%
of the economic activity, whereas in Ireland 75% of the farms are covered, with 98% of the
activity. Though numerically important, holdings below the FADN size thresholds contribute
very little in terms of agricultural activity. In many Member States, especially more recent
additions to the Union, it is likely that the coverage of holdings within FADN is even lower
because some farms are small that they fall below the size for qualification for inclusion in
the Structure Survey. Altogether the FADN sample consists of just under 87,000 holdings
(2014), corresponding to about 1.7% of all holdings within the FADN’s field of observation.
FADN’s main income measures are Farm Net Value Added, expressed per farm or per
Annual Work Unit (FNVA/AWU) (that is, per full-time person equivalents working on the
farm) and Family Farm Income (FFI), per farm or per Family Work Unit (FFI/FWU). These
are calculated as follows:
Box 6: Definition of indicators used in the Farm Accountancy Data Network
Total Output, plus balance current subsidies and taxes, minus intermediate
consumption, minus depreciation = Farm Net Value Added (FNVA)
Farm Net Value Added, plus balance subsidies and taxes on investment, minus wages
paid, minus rent paid, minus interest paid = Farm Net Income (FNI) or Family Farm
Income (FFI) (depending on organisational structure)
FFI is often expressed per annual work unit of unpaid (family) labour (FFI/FWU), including
the farmer, in order to reflect the varying amounts of such labour used. As long as its
definition is borne in mind, FFI is a very useful measure on two counts: first, it represents
what would generally be accepted as being income derived from farming; and, second, by
excluding the hired labour force, it covers only those people whose welfare the CAP is in
practice primarily aimed – farmers and their families.
FFI is conceptually close to Eurostat’s Entrepreneurial Income and, when expressed per
unit of family labour input, to Indicator B.
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
34
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
35
3. OVERVIEW OF THE INCOME DEVELOPMENT OF EU
AGRICULTURE
KEY FINDINGS
It is important to be aware that farm families cannot be assumed to depend on their
incomes from farming, and that other incomes not only raise their household income
levels but also add to its stability.
The evidence points to farmers NOT being a particularly low-income sector of
society in most Member States judged on the basis of their household disposable
incomes. This is of obvious importance to the CAP’s aim to ensure a fair standard of
living of the agricultural community.
In terms of incomes from agricultural activity, the focus of this report, it is clear that
the income indicators at aggregate level (Eurostat) and farm level (FADN) move in
similar fashion. The two FADN indicators (FNVA/AWU and FFI/FWU) are also
closely aligned in their directions of change over time.
Among the various groups of Member States in common usage, in absolute terms
FFI/FWU is highest in the EU-15, then the EU-N10 and lowest in the EU-N2.
FFI/FWU increased over the 2004 to 2012 period with a substantial decline between
2007 and 2009 in all groupings with the exception of EU-N2.
For the EU-27, a strong relationship exists between the economic size of farm
business and the average levels of income generated. This applies not only to FFI
per farm (as might be expected) but, more importantly, income per unit of family
labour (FFI/FWU). This relationship permeates other differences, such as between
farms of different legal status and age of farmer, with the observed patterns largely
being explained by differences in farm size. In each farming type the smallest farms
have the lowest incomes and absolute incomes increase with farm size. Incomes
differ between the various types of farming, granivores having the highest incomes,
and mixed farms the least.
Incomes of farms in Less Favoured Areas (LFA) were lower than those in non-Less
Favoured Areas, even after including the special payments that the former receive.
It is clear that the variability of income over time in FADN results at the group
level is much greater in the smallest size class of farms, though it should be recalled
that this omits data from many Member States because of the differing size
thresholds applied. Beyond that, variation increases with farm size.
Granivore and Fieldcrop farms have the greatest volatility of income. The most
stable incomes are found in the ‘Horticulture’ and ‘Other permanent crops’ sectors.
When income volatility is measured at the level of the individual farm 55% of
large farms and 38% of small farms experienced income volatility of ±30% from the
previous three year average.
The distribution of income at the farm level is very unequal; 20% of the labour
force generates 78% of the FFI. Furthermore, incomes averaged over three years
2010-2012 were negative for large parts of the farm labour force, suggesting that
additional factors, such as income from other gainful activities (OGA), is important
in explaining the ability of such farms to survive.
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
36
Agricultural worker income (wages) increased steadily (in nominal terms) over
the 2004-2012 period with only the EU-N2 group experiencing a decline in 2008 and
the EU-N10 one in 2009.
The pay of agricultural workers in the EU-N10 converged with that in the EU-15
over the period, but pay in the EU-N2 did not.
Agricultural wages per hour differ across farming type, being highest in the wine
sector and lowest in ‘Other grazing livestock and ‘Fieldcrops’ farm types.
3.1. Incomes of farm households
A comparison that is key to monitoring the extent to which the CAP has achieved its stated
objectives, as shown in the Treaty (TFEU) is that between the disposable incomes of
household of farmers and the households of the rest of society; this is pertinent to the fair
standard of living for the agricultural communityaim (section 1.4 Box 2). Closely allied
to this is the proportions of farmers and other social groups that have incomes that place
them in poverty; a satisfactory group average income can nevertheless hide considerable
numbers of households whose standards of living can be taken as being less than ‘fair’.
Though the targeted agricultural community might be considered as somewhat broader
than the households of self-employed farmers, especially in some of the new Member
States, it is clear that households headed by farmers (or at least having a farmer as a
member) form the dominant sector in terms of numbers
12
. Furthermore, the CAP uses
intervention tools that almost exclusively impact on the entrepreneurial incomes of such
farmers; the fairness of the wages of farm employees (dependent workers) are not an
issue addressed directly by the CAP, being left to national legislation such as minimum
wage levels and social policies on poverty alleviation.
The European Commission has, on a number of occasions, asserted that incomes in
agriculture compare unfavourable with those in the rest of the economy (see for example,
European Commission, 2010a; 2010b; 2010c; and 2009 and Box 7). Disparities of the
order of 40% are mentioned which, if taken at face value, might give cause for concern as
being unfair and the basis of continuing support to EU agriculture. However, the basis of
this claim is not information on the incomes of farm households, though this impression
may be given. Rather, it comes from estimates of the rewards to factors engaged in
agricultural production compared with those in the broader economy (indicators from the
activity approach to income accounting). Objections can be made to comparing the incomes
of self-employed farmers (their entrepreneurial rewards from the factors they use in
agricultural production) with labour earnings in the economy as a whole, which will be
dominated by wages; the economic characteristics are different, including the spread of
factors to which they relate and the role of risk. Furthermore, the CAP policy aim is not
to secure fairness of returns to factors of production but, rather, to ensure fair
standards of living, which is a concept related to the disposable incomes of farm
households (or their consumption expenditures). The Commission assertions about low
incomes in agriculture are not borne out by evidence based on the incomes of agricultural
households (that is, making measurement according the institutional units principally
household-firms – involved in farming).
12
In EU-28 in 2010 the Farm Structure Survey showed that 97% of holders were natural persons (in contrast to
legal entities, such as companies and groups of natural persons). France alone accounted for more than two-
fifths of the holdings in the EU-28 that were under the control of legal entities or groups.
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
37
Box 7: Statements by the Commission on the relative position of incomes in
agriculture
2010 Consultation Document for Impact Assessment of the Reform of the CAP
towards 2020: Family labour is not sufficiently remunerated and family assets do not
provide adequate returns. Farm incomes are lower than that of the rest of the
economy. In 2008, the entrepreneurial income per worker employed in agriculture in
the EU-27 was estimated to be around 58% of the average wage in the EU. The gap is
more pronounced in the EU-N12 than in the EU-15. Since the year 2000, the gap has
decreased in the EU-12, but actually increased in the EU-15’.
2010 ‘Developments in the income situation of the EU agricultural sector’:
‘...the evidence clearly points to the conclusion that agricultural incomes in the EU are
significantly lower than earnings outside the sector. In 2008 the entrepreneurial
income per worker employed in agriculture in the EU-27 was estimated at around 58%
of the average wage in the EU. The gap was more pronounced in the EU-N12 than in
the EU-15.’
November 2010 Communication from the Commission: After a decade of mere
income stagnation, agricultural income dropped substantially in 2009 adding to an
already fragile situation of an agricultural income significantly lower (by an estimated
40% per working unit) than that in the rest of the economy, and income per inhabitant
in rural areas is considerably lower (by about 50%) than in urban areas’.
December 2009 ‘Why Do We Need a Common Agricultural Policy’: graphics are
given in which the relative income position of agriculture is shown as declining over the
period 2000 to 2008. Using as an indicator agricultural income (not specified in detail)
per AWU unit as % of total economy income/labour unit’ the relative position of
agriculture is shown as falling from about 22% to about 20% in EU-27 over the nine
years, the decline in EU-15 being from a relative income of almost 40% down to close
to 30%. For EU-N10 the relative position of agricultural income was broadly maintained
over the period, whereas in EU-N2 it fell sharply.
This section reviews the evidence on the incomes of agricultural households, in
particular how these relate to other households, details of which are given in FAO (2011)
and Hill (2012). This is in the form, first, of national data from eight Member States using a
mix of sources (farm accounts surveys, taxation data, household surveys, etc., either singly
or in combination); countries covered are Denmark, Finland, France, Ireland, Italy, Poland,
Sweden, and the United Kingdom (England). Second, the main findings of Eurostat’s
Income of the Agricultural Household Sector statistics should be noted; though suspended
in 2002 these remain the only attempt to generate harmonised statistics on this issue, and
many of the results were not invalidated by the disparities in methodology between
countries (the weakness that led inter alia to their suspension). Third, the OECD has
published an overview taking national results (including some from Eurostat’s IAHS project)
which has relevance here (OECD, 2003). Fourth, the Luxembourg Income Study
13
(LIS - an
international collaboration of which Eurostat is a member) has also analysed relative
income levels, though its basic sources of data (national household surveys) are
handicapped by, in many countries, few cases of households headed by farmers in the
sample
14
.
It is well-known that many households that operate farms are also active in other sectors
of the economy. Over a third of farmer/managers are known to have an ‘Other Gainful
13
http://www.lisdatacenter.org/
14
See Hill (2012), Chapter 5 for a critique of de Frahan, et al. (2008).
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
38
Activity (OGA) with earnings from outside the farm businesses (see Box 8), and this
proportion would be larger if spouses/partners were to be included. For many of these,
particularly where the farm is very small, farming is likely to be a very minor activity
15
.
Hence there is a need to draw a distinction between those where agriculture is the main
source of livelihood, which might be termed ‘agricultural households’, and the others.
The lack of a harmonised and working statistical system way of measuring the total and
disposable incomes of agricultural households in the EU is a major impediment in providing
an authoritative picture. Having said that, bringing together the evidence for the EU it is
clear that:
The definition of what is an agricultural household is important to both the numbers
of households and their income situation. The number of agricultural households
(where the main income of the reference person comes from farming) is
substantially smaller than the number of households where there is some income
from farming, and generally smaller than the number of agricultural holdings. Where
data exist over time, absolute numbers of agricultural households have been falling,
in some instances very rapidly. The fact that results do not relate to a constant set
of households must be borne in mind when interpreting changes in incomes per
household over time.
Agricultural households (defined as above) in all countries are recipients of
substantial amounts of income from outside agriculture. Though typically about a
half to two thirds of the total comes from farming, there are large differences
between Member States and some differences between years. Other households
with farms will have even more reliance on incomes from outside the farm business.
It follows that knowing the income that a farm operator obtains from farming is not
a reliable guide to their level of household income, so that statistics on incomes
from farming should not be used to draw conclusion relating to household
living standards of farm operators.
The total income of agricultural households is more stable than their income
from farming alone. Non-agricultural income (taken together) is less variable from
year to year than is farming income. Disposable income seems to be less stable than
total income, but the relationship between the two depends on a variety of factors,
including the way that taxation is levied. Because of short-term variability, figures
for total and disposable household incomes in single years should be treated with
caution; this applies to an even greater extent to data on the income from farming
alone.
The average disposable incomes of households headed by farmers (in the sense
that farming is the main income source) are generally of similar levels to those
of society in general. This is rather different from the 58% implied by the
Commission’s 2010 statements. In a few countries they are rather lower (Portugal
and Poland for example), but in a greater number of Member States they can be
substantially higher than national household averages. It seems likely that national
circumstances (farm structures, which reflect histories of adjustment, patterns of
land inheritance, pluriactivity rates, etc.) influence relative income positions.
15
European Commission (2013) reports that over 60% of managers of farms with less than 5 ha UAA spend less
than a quarter of their working time on farm. Over 70% of managers of farms with more than 100 ha UAA
work full-time on the farm. The CAP context indicators show the relative unimportance of agriculture as an
economic activity in most parts of the EU (European Commission, 2014a).
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
39
Incomes per household member (or per Consumer Unit) are typically somewhat
lower than per household because of the larger size of the average farm household
(though this characteristic varies between countries).
Box 8: Pluriactive farm operators in the EU-27
According to the 2005 Farm Structure Survey, 36% of EU farmer/managers were
pluriactive, in the sense that they had some other gainful activity (OGAs) outside the
farm businesses. These can fall into two main types: entrepreneurial rewards from
independent activity (self-employment); and, wages and salaries from dependent
activity (as employees). The incidence of OGAs was much higher among small farms,
but even among the largest size groups at least one fifth of farmer/managers had an
OGA.
Source: 2005 FSS given in Barthomeuf (2008).
Some types of farming are particularly associated with pluriactivity, such as specialist
olive farms and grazing and fattening of livestock, while its incidence is lower in others,
for example, specialist dairying and horticulture, where the type of activity seems to
provide less opportunity to be away from the farm. Having an OGA is also more
prevalent among younger farmers than older ones.
Source: 2005 FSS given in Barthomeuf (2008).
These statistics do not cover spouses and other family members, so the percentage of
households having income from involvement with occupations off the farm is likely to be
higher.
0%
10%
20%
30%
40%
50%
<1 ESU 1-<2 ESU 2-<4 ESU 4-<8 ESU 8-<16
ESU
16-<40
ESU
40-<100
ESU
100-<250
ESU
>=250
ESU
Share of sole holder managers with another gainful activity
% of potential gross value added of EU-27
0%
10%
20%
30%
40%
50%
60%
<35 y.o. 35-<44 y.o. 45-<54 y.o. 55-<64 y.o. >=65 y.o. Total
2003 2005
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
40
If, as seems very likely, living standards of farmers as a group can be shown to be already
‘fair’ (as indicated by approximate parity of disposable incomes) in most EU countries, this
is important from the perspective of social welfare policy. It suggests that farm households
are not a particularly low-income group and points to the need to be able to spot the low
income cases that undoubtedly exist in order to target support at them. The fact that the
mean (or median) disposable incomes of some other groups (such as households headed
by other self-employed persons) are higher than those of farmers is not of much concern in
this context, though it points to the need to be careful in the choice of comparators.
Little attention has been given here to the wealth of farm households. What little
information exists at Member State level suggests that farm operators form a relatively
high net-worth group, largely because of the land assets they control. When considering
support on social grounds, some systems take wealth into account when testing eligibility
(e.g. the English approach to Social Service departments paying for care in retirement and
nursing homes). If the support of low household incomes in agriculture is seen as a
function of social policy rather than agricultural policy, the likelihood of being able to
reflect wealth would appear to be greater than if it were a function of the CAP.
3.2. Incomes from agricultural activity
Income from agricultural activity is only a contributor to what should be understood as
farmers’ income, though the extent of its contribution depends on how broadly the
boundaries of an ‘agricultural household’ are drawn (see the discussion on agricultural
household income above). This will be especially true among small farms where other
gainful activities are the most prevalent, though those that are unmistakably commercial in
their farming operations will tend to be mainly dependent on their profits from agriculture.
As has been explained in Chapter 1.3, there are two approaches to establishing income
derived from agricultural activities: the aggregate approach using sector data (Eurostat)
and the farm-level approach using individual farm data (FADN). Eurostat’s approach covers
all the agricultural activity in the Member State whereas FADN only covers that on holdings
that are deemed to be commercial by exceeding a given economic size (which varies
between Member States). The former has attracted the attention of EU policymakers
because of the speed with which results can be made available, whereas the latter contains
much of the detail that is important to CAP decisions. Income from agricultural activity is
set out using both approaches in the sub-sections below.
3.2.1. Aggregate levels (Eurostat)
Chapter 2.2.1 explained the income indicators developed by Eurostat from the Economic
Accounts for Agriculture. Indicators A (income of factors in agricultural activity per AWU)
and B (Entrepreneurial Income per AWU of unpaid labour) are relevant here; both are in
real terms and expressed as indices. Figure 2 presents the evolution of both these
indicators for the EU-27, the EU-25 and the EU-15 (no other aggregations are available).
The general trend is the same for both indicators with Indicator B showing greater
volatility; this difference results from the difference in definition (Indicator B reflects what
is left over from NVA after the further deduction of payments for rent, interest and wages
of hired workers, which tend to be quite stable from year to year). Although there were
decreases in these indicators in 2005 and, more seriously, in 2008/2009 due to declining
commodity prices and increasing input costs, both have since recovered to finish the 2000-
2014 period substantially higher (see Chapter 4 for a discussion on the drivers of income
development). The EU-27 group has outperformed the EU-25 and the EU-15 since 2009
which reveals that incomes in the EU-N10 grouping have converged with those in the EU-
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
41
15 while those in the EU-N2 have converged with those in the EU-25 from this point
onwards.
Figure 2: Evolution of index of real income of factors in agricultural activity per
annual work unit (Eurostat Indicator A) and index of real net agricultural
entrepreneurial income per unpaid work unit (Eurostat Indicator B) (2005=100)
Source: Eurostat.
Eurostat’s aggregate indicators cannot, by definition, be used to describe income
developments by sub-groups such as farm size and types; this analysis has to be
undertaken using farm-level data in the FADN (Chapter 3.2.3).
3.2.2. Comparing aggregate to farm level data
Before analysing the farm-level FADN data it is worth investigating how the dataset
compares to the aggregate Eurostat data. The most appropriate income indicators for this
analysis are
16
:
FADN Farm Net Value Added per Annual Work Unit compared with Eurostat
Indicator A (index of real income of factors in agricultural activity per AWU); and,
FADN Family Farm Income per Family Work Unit compared with Eurostat
Indicator B (real net agricultural entrepreneurial income per unpaid annual work
unit).
Figure 3 presents an index of these variables in real terms where 2007 = 100. From 2007
both series are EU-27. Prior to this date the FADN series is EU-25 only, and this helps
explain why the series only move together from 2007; Indicators A and B evolved
differently in Bulgaria and Romania prior to 2007 and this is reflected in Eurostat index for
these years. The conclusion to draw from this analysis is that the two approaches to
calculating farm income provide very similar results in terms of annual fluctuation. It
is reasonable therefore to treat them as broadly comparable.
16
Eurostat income indicators are expressed in real terms while FADN data are nominal. For the purposes of this
comparison we have converted FADN data into real terms.
0
20
40
60
80
100
120
140
160
2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014
Indicator A
0
20
40
60
80
100
120
140
160
2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014
Indicator B
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
42
Figure 3: Comparison of FADN FNVA/AWU against Eurostat Indicator A and
FFI/FWU against Eurostat Indicator B, EU-25/EU-27 (2007=100, real terms)
Source: Eurostat and DG AGRI EU-FADN.
3.2.3. Farm level data (FADN)
FADN data are available for all EU-25 Member States from 2004 to 2012; Bulgarian and
Romanian data are included from 2007 onwards. Where possible we have presented EU-25
data for 2004 to 2006 and EU-27 data for 2007 to 2012 showing a structural break
between the two. Where this is not possible (in the interests of clarity) we have used a
vertical line to divide graphs to make this structural break clear.
It is also important to understand the basis on which FADN data are compiled because this
influences the results produced. The key point is that the FADN field of observation does
not include all agricultural holdings but rather those that are above certain size thresholds
(Economic Size expressed in Standard Output terms), which vary between Member
States to reflect their agricultural structures. In practice this means that FADN covers
almost all production (around 90% or more which comes mostly from what might be
termed ‘commercial farms’) but a much smaller share of farms by number (typically nearer
50% though again there are differences between Member States (these data are presented
in Annex 1).
This means that no farms below a Standard Output (SO) size threshold of
€2,000 are
included in FADN at all and no farms below €25,000 SO are included in Belgium, Germany,
Luxembourg, Netherlands or Slovakia, or below
€8,000 in Austria, Czech Republic,
Denmark, Finland, France, Ireland, Sweden or the UK. The consequence of this is that
FADN results for farms within these lower size classes must be treated with caution
as they do not encompass farms from every Member State.
For example, in published EU-27 results, farms in the
€2,000 to €8,000 size class only
come from 14 countries
17
and those in the
€8,000 to €25,000 size class 22
countries
18
.
Only in results for farms with SO of
€25,000 and over are all Member States represented.
This is important in making observations about the relationship between income and farm
size using EU-level results and also when drawing comparisons between Member States.
Also there are some farmers at the smaller end of the scale for which information on
income from agricultural activities is simply not covered in FADN (see above), an omission
17
Bulgaria, Cyprus, Greece, Spain, Estonia, Hungary, Italy, Lithuania, Latvia, Malta, Poland, Portugal, Romania,
Slovenia.
18
The additional eight Member States are Czech Republic, Denmark, France, Ireland, Austria, Finland, Slovenia,
United Kingdom.
0
20
40
60
80
100
120
140
2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012
FNVA/AWU Indicator A
0
20
40
60
80
100
120
140
2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012
FFI/FWU Indicator B
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
43
that is important when viewing the CAP as a policy directed at the standards of living of the
persons engaged in agriculture, but of less significance when the focus of concern is on the
level of agricultural production. By definition, farmers on very small farms are likely to be
earning only small incomes from farming, although they are also likely to earn income from
other gainful activities.
FADN also classifies farms by type, using two standard breakdowns (into fourteen and eight
types: TF14 and TF8 respectively). There is considerable overlap between the two and we
have used the latter which classifies farms as (1) Fieldcrops; (2) Horticulture; (3) Wine; (4)
Other permanent crops; (5) Milk; (6) Other grazing livestock; (7) Granivores; (8) Mixed.
The relative importance (in SO terms) of the different farm enterprises is used to determine
farm typology.
Before presenting analysis at the farm level, it is worth setting out the correspondence
between farm size and type within the FADN sample because there are areas of correlation
between the two which should be kept in mind. Figure 4 shows that the smallest Economic
Size group contains a disproportionate number of mixed farms (the fact that only 14
Member States are represented should also be borne in mind) while the largest group
contains a disproportionate number of granivore enterprises. Dairy enterprises are
more likely to be between
€50,000 and €500,000 in Economic Size terms (groups 4 and 5).
Other permanent crop enterprises tend to be of small Economic Size. Horticultural
enterprises increase in proportion with scale (although here it is especially important to
note the exclusion of small farms in half the Member States; horticulture is often a small-
scale enterprise).
As a result of these relationships, when discussing farm income for granivores, for
example, there will be some correspondence with findings for the largest Economic Size
grouping and vice versa.
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
44
Figure 4: Distribution of farm size by farm type in the FADN sample, 2010-2012
average
Source: DG AGRI EU-FADN.
3.2.3.1. Overview
As has been explained above (Chapter 2.2.2 Box 6), the two main indicators of farm
income within the FADN dataset are Farm Net Value Added per Annual Work Unit
(FNVA/AWU) and Family Farm Income per Family Work Unit (FFI/FWU) (this only relates
to family farms, not those arranged as legal entities). Of the two, FFI is closer to the
concept of farmer incomein that is represents the profits generated by the farm business
which are available to the farm operator to help fund consumption spending, personal
taxation and saving. FFI is the reward to all the factors of production owned by the farm
operator – the land, labour and capital owned plus the physical labour and managerial input
of the farmer and any other non-hired workers; it is therefore a hybrid of all these. In
contrast, FNVA measures the reward to all the fixed factors used, irrespective of who owns
them. It should be noted that an estimate for the depreciation of capital assets is deducted
from both of these indicators, in line with the conventional approach to income
measurement (in the short-term actual spending on capital items can be delayed or
brought forward).
These two measures are compared in Figure 5 for the EU-27 where it can be seen that their
movements are closely correlated. FFI/FWU equated to 85% of FNVA/AWU in 2004,
increased to 89% in 2007 before falling to 78% in 2009, from which position it increased to
84% by 2012. On average over the 2004 to 2012 period FFI/FWU was 84% of FNVA/AWU.
The close correlation of these measures mean that analyse of FFI/FWU, the most
appropriate measure, does not need to be universally accompanied by a separate analysis
of FNVA/AWU.
0%
10%
20%
30%
40%
50%
60%
70%
80%
90%
100%
(1) 2 000 - < 8
000 EUR
(2) 8 000 - < 25
000 EUR
(3) 25 000 - <
50 000 EUR
(4) 50 000 - <
100 000 EUR
(5) 100 000 - <
500 000 EUR
(6) >= 500 000
EUR
(1) Fieldcrops (2) Horticulture (3) Wine
(4) Other permanent crops (5) Milk (6) Other grazing livestock
(7) Granivores (8) Mixed
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
45
Figure 5: Indicators of farm income, EU-25 2000-06, EU-27 2007-12, 2004-2012
Source: DG AGRI EU-FADN.
Both of these indicators relate to the rewards earned by self-employed (independent)
farmers). Wages paid to the hired workers (who may include managers employed by farms
organised as legal entities) are considered later in section 3.2.3.10. The rationale is that, in
some Member States, such workers are generally considered as part of the agricultural
community and thus potential targets for support under the Common Agricultural Policy.
Within the EU there are important differences between groups of countries that were
Member States before 2004 and those that joined subsequently (the treatment of incomes
in single countries are presented separately in Chapter 5). Figure 6 disaggregates FFI/FWU
by EU-15, EU-N10 and EU-N2. The key points to note are:
In absolute terms FFI/FWU is highest in the EU-15, then the EU-N10 and lowest in
the EU-N2; and,
FFI/FWU increases over the 2004 to 2012 period with a substantial decline between
2007 and 2009 in all groupings with the exception of EU-N2.
The Figure shows some convergence in absolute levels of income between FFI/FWU in the
EU-15 and EU-N10. In 2004 and 2005, FFI/FWU in the EU-15 was just over four times the
magnitude of FFI/FWU in the EU-N10, but by 2012 was only 2.7 times larger. There was
similar convergence between FFI/FWU in the EU-N2 and the other groups. Although the
decline in FFI/FWU between 2007 and 2009 was greater in absolute terms in the EU-15, in
percentage terms FFI/FWU declined more in the EU-N10 (30% c.f. 25%). The EU-N2
grouping showed no such decline. The drivers behind these changes are considered later
(Chapter 4).
€0
€2.000
€4.000
€6.000
€8.000
€10.000
€12.000
€14.000
€16.000
€18.000
€20.000
2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012
FNVA/AWU FFI/FWU
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
46
Figure 6: Evolution of FFI/FWU by EU groupings, 2004-12
Source: DG AGRI EU-FADN.
3.2.3.2. Farm size
When considering farm economic size it is important to bear in mind that the field of
observation of FADN does not cover any farms below
€2,000 Standard Output and that
coverage is not universal until an SO of
€25,000 is reached
.
With that in mind, it is nevertheless clear that a strong relationship exists between the
size of farm business and the average levels of income generated over the three year
period 2010-2012. This is evident in Figure 7 which shows both FNVA/AWU and FFI/FWU
increasing with scale. FFI/FWU edges above FNVA/AWU for the
€100,000
-€500,000 size
group and is considerably higher for farms above
€500,000 (more than double). Though
FNVA/AWU also shows a rise across the farm size spectrum, it is fairly similar between
these two largest size groups. Literature suggests that this association between farm size
and income level is mainly due to the ability of larger farms to take advantage of scale
economies, including crucially on returns to labour. The high FFI/FWU among the largest
farms reflects the large quantities of the capital and land in these businesses that are
combined with relatively small numbers of FWU of (family) labour; it should be recalled that
large farms arranged as legal entities are excluded from coverage by this indicator (though
they are covered by FNVA/AWU) so that this group will contain many large businesses that
are run as family (non-corporate) farms.
€0
€5.000
€10.000
€15.000
€20.000
€25.000
€30.000
2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012
EU-15 EU-N10 EU-N2 EU-25 EU-27
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
47
Figure 7: Indicators of farm income by farm size, 2010-2012 average
Source: DG AGRI EU-FADN.
The evolution of FFI/FWU by farm size between 2004 and 2012 found in FADN results
is shown in Figure 8. The first point to note is that FFI/FWU increases with the economic
size of farms. Within each size group, the general pattern is the same as shown above in
Figure 7, but the decrease in FFI/FWU from 2007 to 2008 is not only larger in absolute
terms (as would be expected) for the largest size group than it is for the smallest, it is also
much more substantial in relative terms (28% c.f. 9%). Prior to that, the apparent
decrease in FFI/FWU for the smallest size group in 2007 was largely the result of the
accession of Bulgaria and Romania which have a large number of small farms (see Chapter
3.2.3), and the move from EU-25 to EU-27.
€0
€10.000
€20.000
€30.000
€40.000
€50.000
€60.000
€70.000
€80.000
€90.000
€100.000
2,000 - < 8,000
EUR
8,000 - <
25,000 EUR
25,000 - <
50,000 EUR
50,000 - <
100,000 EUR
100,000 - <
500,000 EUR
>= 500,000 EUR
FNVA/AWU FFI/FWU EU-27 FNVA/AWU EU-27 FFI/FWU
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
48
Figure 8: Evolution of FFI/FWU by farm size, 2004-2012
Source: DG AGRI EU-FADN.
3.2.3.3. Farm type
Figure 9 examines FNVA/AWU and FFI/FWU (both taking the average for 2010-2012) by
farm type using the FADN TF8 classification system
19
. Although the relationship between
the two indicators varies by farm type, there is no change in the order of types, with
Granivoreshaving the highest farm income and Mixedfarms the lowest. These findings
are also influenced by scale (see section 3.2.3), with Granivores appearing
disproportionately among large farms and Mixed farms disproportionately among small
farms. ‘Other permanent crops’, Other grazing livestock’ and ‘Mixed’ farms all had FFI/FWU
below the EU-27 average while the other farm types all reported FFI/FWU above the
average. This is also the case with respect to FNVA/AWU.
19
The prevalence of farm types differs across the EU Member States; it should also be noted that Granivores
are not included in the Irish sample because the total number of these types of farm is too small.
€0
€20.000
€40.000
€60.000
€80.000
€100.000
€120.000
2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012
2,000 - < 8,000 EUR 8,000 - < 25,000 EUR 25,000 - < 50,000 EUR
50,000 - < 100,000 EUR 100,000 - < 500,000 EUR >= 500,000 EUR
EU-25
EU-27
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
49
Figure 9: Indicators of farm income by farm type, 2010-2012 average
Source: DG AGRI EU-FADN.
The evolution of FFI/FWU for each type between 2004 and 2012 is shown in Figure 10 while
some farm types show the same evolution as noted for all farm types at the EU-27 level
(Figure 9), others do not. In making this observation it is important to bear in mind the
impact of enlargement from EU-25 to EU-27 which generally reduced FFI/FWU at the
aggregate level. The 2006-2007 decline in the Horticulture sector is mainly due to the
accession of Bulgaria and Romania in which the horticulture sector is very fragmented.
Sectors which are less significant in Bulgaria and Romania, e.g. wine, do not show this
decrease at EU level.
The dip in FFI/FWU in the ‘Granivoresector in 2007 is partly influenced by the accession of
Romania and Bulgaria, but the main causes of the large decrease were a general decline in
FFI/FWU and negative FFI/FWU in Denmark and the Netherlands. Negative FFI/FWU in
Denmark in 2007 in the Other grazing livestock’ and the ‘Mixedsectors also contributed to
the large decrease seen here (in the later cases there were also large falls in the
Netherlands). The developments in these two countries, and in the other Member States,
are considered in more detail in Chapter 5.
€0
€5.000
€10.000
€15.000
€20.000
€25.000
€30.000
€35.000
FNVA/AWU FFI/FWU EU-27 FNVA/AWU EU-27 FFI/FWU
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
50
Figure 10: Evolution of FFI/FWU by farm type, 2004-2012
Source: DG AGRI EU-FADN.
3.2.3.4. Size and type
Figure 11 shows the evolution of FFI/FWU between 2004 and 2012 by farm size and
type. Although not marked on the Figure to improve readability, the reader should recall
the structural break between the EU-25 and EU-27 which took place in 2007 and which will
have a disproportionate impact for smaller size groups.
As would be expected, in each farming type the smallest farms have the lowest incomes
(though it should be borne in mind that not all countries are represented in these classes)
and that absolute incomes increase across the size spectrum. Within each type the pattern
was similar across the size classes with the exception of the largest farms which generally
show greater volatility (partly because of their higher dependence on hired labour).
FFI/FWU in the largest size class also evolved differently in some farm types such as Wine
and Other grazing livestock’; in others its movements were in the same direction as the
other size groups, but were more extreme. The dip in incomes between 2007 and 2009 is
present in all farm types and size classes, but the magnitude of the decreases varied by
farm type and size.
€0
€5.000
€10.000
€15.000
€20.000
€25.000
€30.000
€35.000
€40.000
2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012
Fieldcrops Horticulture Wine
Other permanent crops Milk Other grazing livestock
Granivores Mixed
EU-25
EU-27
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
51
Figure 11: FFI/FWU by type of farm and size class, 2004-2012
€0
€25.000
€50.000
€75.000
€100.000
€125.000
€150.000
€175.000
€200.000
2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012
Fieldcrops
€0
€25.000
€50.000
€75.000
€100.000
€125.000
€150.000
€175.000
€200.000
2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012
Horticulture
€0
€25.000
€50.000
€75.000
€100.000
€125.000
€150.000
€175.000
€200.000
2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012
Wine
€0
€25.000
€50.000
€75.000
€100.000
€125.000
€150.000
€175.000
€200.000
2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012
Other permanent crops
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
52
Source: DG AGRI EU-FADN.
3.2.3.5. Age of farmer
Age in the FADN farm return can be reported for up to six combinations of
holders/managers and whether they are paid or unpaid per farm. To classify farms by the
€0
€25.000
€50.000
€75.000
€100.000
€125.000
€150.000
€175.000
€200.000
2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012
Milk
€0
€25.000
€50.000
€75.000
€100.000
€125.000
€150.000
€175.000
€200.000
2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012
Granivores
€0
€25.000
€50.000
€75.000
€100.000
€125.000
€150.000
€175.000
€200.000
2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012
Other grazing livestock
€0
€25.000
€50.000
€75.000
€100.000
€125.000
€150.000
€175.000
€200.000
2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012
Mixed
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
53
age of the farmer, rather than just considering the principle farmer (which can be
misleading where other family members contribute to management), the age of each
holder/manager has been weighted by their respective contribution to their collective sum
of AWU. Indicators of farm income are assessed by this age of farmer indicator in Figure
12. The pattern of income is the same for both indicators and shows income increasing with
age up to the age of 54, after which income declines.
Figure 12: Indicators of farm income by age, EU-27 2010-2012
Source: DG AGRI EU-FADN.
3.2.3.6. Institutional structure
Figure 13 presents the indicators of farm income by ownership structure for the EU-27
and EU sub-groups. The first point to note is that, while FNVA/AWU is appropriate for farms
of all ownership structures, FFI/FWU is not meaningful for farms organised as legal entities
(company farms) where all the labour is treated as paid; FADN results do not calculate it
for farms that have zero unpaid labour. With that in mind, income (as measured by
FNVA/AWU) is lowest for all sub-groups for individual (family) farms and highest for farms
organised as partnerships; economic size provides part of the explanation for this with
partnerships tending to be more prevalent in larger size groups (European Commission,
2013). FNVA/AWU on company farms (other) falls between these extremes. For all sub-
groups with the exception of the EU-N10, FFI/FWU is considerably higher for farms
organised as partnerships than for individual (family) farms. The gap between FFI/FWU for
these organisational forms is greatest in the EU-N2 (a factor of 7.1) and least in the EU-15
(a factor of 1.8); for the EU-N10 FFI/FWU farms organised as partnerships exceeds that of
individual (family) farms by a factor of 3.2. It is expected that farm size is the key
explanatory factor of these differences rather than anything linked to the way in which
farms function under the three ownership structures shown.
€0
€5.000
€10.000
€15.000
€20.000
€25.000
<35 35-44 45-54 55-64 >65
Age of farmer
FNVA/AWU FFI/FWU EU-27 FNVA/AWU EU-27 FFI/FWU
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
54
Figure 13: Indicators of farm income by ownership structure and EU sub-group,
2010-2012 average
Source: DG AGRI EU-FADN.
3.2.3.7. Less Favoured Area status
Figure 14 shows the indicators of income for farms in Less Favoured Areas (mountain and
non-mountain areas) and those in non-Less Favoured Areas (including those with no
significant area). As one would expect from the designation, income is higher in the
non-LFA, despite the LFA payments made.
€0
€5.000
€10.000
€15.000
€20.000
€25.000
€30.000
€35.000
€40.000
€45.000
FNVA/AWU FFI/FWU FNVA/AWU FFI/FWU FNVA/AWU FFI/FWU FNVA/AWU FFI/FWU
EU-27 EU-15 EU-N10 EU-N2
(1) Individual (family) farms (2) Partnerships (3) Other
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
55
Figure 14: Indicators of farm income by Less Favoured Area status, EU-27 2010-
2012
Source: DG AGRI EU-FADN.
3.2.3.8. Volatility
Volatility can be considered at the group level (Member State, or type and size class) and
at the level of the individual farm. Group figures can be of interest, but they hide much of
what happens at the farm level because the short-run experiences of single businesses,
while significant to their operators, to an extent cancel each other out.
Group level volatility
The first approach is to examine the year-on-year changes seen in average result for
groups of Member States. While the direction of change is broadly similar in EU-15 and
EU-N10, the latter group shows a more pronounced variation, though in the last three
years of the series that is a closer commonality (Figure 15). The negative changes in the
middle of the period were generally recouped in following years.
€0
€5.000
€10.000
€15.000
€20.000
€25.000
LFA non-LFA
FNVA/AWU FFI/FWU EU-27 FNVA/AWU EU-27 FFI/FWU
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
56
Figure 15: Annual year-on-year change in farm income indicators
Source: DG AGRI EU-FADN.
Another, more formal, way of measuring volatility is using a coefficient of variation
20
; the
higher the coefficient, the greater the relative variation from year to year. The coefficients
have been calculated for 2004 to 2012.
The analysis here is carried out for size classes (Figure 16) and type of farming (Figure
17). It is clear that the variability of incomes, as measured by the coefficient of variation, in
FADN results is much greater in the smallest size class of farms, though it should be
recalled that this omits data from many Member States. Beyond that, variation rises with
larger farm size, though there is little difference between the medium size groups in terms
of FNVA/AWU. However, this must also reflect the domination of the largest size class by
Granivores’. Among farming types Granivores is characterised by volatility of income,
closely followed (in terms of FFI/FWU) by Fieldcrops’. At the other end of the volatility
spectrum, with the most stable incomes, are ‘Horticulture’ and ‘Other permanent crops’.
20
Standard Deviation/mean.
-40%
-30%
-20%
-10%
0%
10%
20%
30%
40%
2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012
FNVA/AWU
-30%
-20%
-10%
0%
10%
20%
30%
40%
2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012
FFI/FWU
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
57
Figure 16: Coefficient of variation of income indicators by farm size, 2004-2012
Source: DG AGRI EU-FADN.
Figure 17: Coefficient of variation by farm type, 2004-2012
Source: DG AGRI EU-FADN.
Farm level volatility
Almost all results reported in this document have been freshly calculated using the latest
FADN results. However, the data to construct a new assessment of farm-level volatility (an
0,00
0,05
0,10
0,15
0,20
0,25
(1) 2 000 - < 8
000 EUR
(2) 8 000 - < 25
000 EUR
(3) 25 000 - <
50 000 EUR
(4) 50 000 - <
100 000 EUR
(5) 100 000 - <
500 000 EUR
(6) >= 500 000
EUR
Var FNVA/AWU Var FFI/FWU EU-27 FNVA/AWU EU-27 FFI/FWU
0,00
0,05
0,10
0,15
0,20
0,25
0,30
(1)
Fieldcrops
(2)
Horticulture
(3) Wine (4) Other
permanent
crops
(5) Milk (6) Other
grazing
livestock
(7)
Granivores
(8) Mixed
Var FNVA/AWU Var FFI/FWU EU-27 FNVA/AWU EU-27 FFI/FWU
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
58
up to date version of (Figure 18) are not available, though it is unlikely that the overall
pattern would be much altered since the Commission published results for 1998-2007.
According to that analysis, a higher proportion of small farms appeared to see large
negative changes (more than 30%) in FNVA compared to the average of the three previous
years relative to large farms which in turn were more likely to see positive changes (up to
100%). Despite this general pattern, a high proportion of small farms recorded an increase
of more than 100% than did large farms. However, a key point to note from the Figure is
that 55% of large farms and 38% of small farms experienced income volatility of
±30% from the previous three year average. Such information is important to policy
that attempts to bring greater stability to the incomes of farm operators from their
agricultural activities.
Figure 18: Farm level volatility, 1998-2007
Source: Elaborated from European Commission (2010) based on EU-FADN data.
3.2.3.9. Distribution of incomes
Figure 19 presents the distribution of income (FNVA and FFI) among the labour force
(AWU) for the EU-27 using a Lorenz curve
21
. An average income at the farm level for the
period 2010-12 has been used. An equal distribution of income would be show a straight
line from the origin to the top right hand corner. The evidence seen here demonstrates that
the distribution of income is not equal. Furthermore, income for large parts of the farm
labour force was negative, much more so in the case of FFI. In FNVA terms, 20% of the
agricultural labour force generates 66% of FNVA with 10% accounting for 55% of FNVA.
21
A Lorenz curve is a graphical representation of the cumulative distribution of wealth or income. A straight line
from the origin to the top right hand corner at 45
o
would indicate perfect equality. The extent of deviation
from this straight line shows the extent of inequality.
0
5
10
15
20
25
30
More than
100%
-100 to -
70%
-70 to -30% -30 to 0% 0 to 30% 30 to 70% 70 to 100% More than
100%
Percentage of farms
Percentage change in FNVA compared to average of previous 3 years
Small farms (2-4 ESU) Large farms (above 100 ESU)
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
59
The lack of equality is even more noticeable in FFI terms where 20% of the labour force
generates 78% of the FFI but 10% generates 58% of FFI.
Given that these incomes cover three years, the numerical importance of labour units with
negative incomes from farming raises the question of how the holdings to which they
belong manage to stay in business. Income sources from outside the farm business are
expected to play a major part in explaining the persistence of such farms, though this
might also involve increases in borrowing against assets that may or may not be increasing
in value in real terms. Though non-agricultural income can be documented in countries
where farm accounts surveys collect such information (and, for example, is well
documented in the ARMS survey in the US), the lack of coverage of variables on other
household incomes by FADN means that no direct evidence can be drawn from the EU’s
main data source on farm economics. This is regrettable and points to the need for change
in the coverage of FADN to bring it in line with what many Member States already do in
their national surveys of farm accounts.
Figure 19: Lorenz curve of the distribution of FNVA and FFI, EU-27, 2010-2012
average
Source: DG AGRI EU-FADN.
The Gini coefficient can also be used to measure the distribution of income. This
coefficient is the ratio of the area between the line of equality
22
and the Lorenz distribution.
A value of 0 shows perfect equality of income and 1 perfect inequality.
Figure 20 presents the Gini coefficient for the various EU groupings. Some caution is
required in interpreting this data because the FADN field of observation differs by Member
State with smaller farms generally not included in the EU-15. That said, two patterns stand
out. First, the distribution of FNVA per AWU is less concentrated in the EU-15 than the EU-
N10 or EU-N2. Second, income concentration is generally decreasing in the EU-N10 and
EU-N2 showing a degree of convergence with the distribution in the EU-15. That said, it will
be at least five years before a definitive judgement on the extent of convergence can be
reached given annual fluctuations
23
. A final observation is that income concentration
increased in the EU-15 in 2008 and in the EU-N10 and EU-N2 in 2009 as a result of the
financial crisis before declining to pre-2008 levels in the case of the EU-15 and to trend in
the other groupings. The lack of change in income distribution between the beginning and
22
Straight line from the origin to the top right hand corner at 45
o
.
23
A reminder of the dangers of looking at short-term trends and focusing on annual data is provided by European
Commission (2014a) which, based on a data series finishing in 2011 concluded that income concentration was
increasing in the EU-15. With the addition of 2012 data this now looks incorrect with the 2008 to 2011 period
appearing to be a temporary phenomenon. However, this conclusion requires data from further years to be
confirmed.
-20
0
20
40
60
80
100
0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100
Cumulative share of FNVA
(%)
Share of AWU (%)
-20
0
20
40
60
80
100
0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100
Cumulative share of total
FFI (%)
Share of AWU (%)
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
60
end of the observation period in the EU-15 might suggest that a Gini coefficient of
around 60% is typical for the agricultural sector.
European Commission (2014b) notes that income inequality in the EU-N2 decreased as a
result of the increase in direct payments during the phasing-in process. An examination of
the balance of current subsidies and taxes reveals that subsidies did indeed increase by
higher proportions for smaller farms in both Bulgaria and Romania.
Figure 20: Development of the Gini coefficient of FNVA per AWU
Source: DG AGRI EU-FADN.
3.2.3.10. Wages of hired farm labour
Although the incomes of self-employed farmers are the main focus of our attention in this
report, there is interest in the earnings of hired workers, not least because they are
numerically significant in some Member States and opinion in some countries suggests that
there they are seen as part of the agricultural community for policy purposes. However, it
must be emphasised that the factors determining their incomes are fundamentally different
from those that drive the incomes of farmers; for example, wage levels are not directly
connected to the market conditions for agricultural commodities. FADN contains some data
that are relevant to the earnings of hired workers, and for completeness these are
reported. Figure 21 presents the evolution of agricultural wages from 2004 to 2012.
0,0
0,2
0,4
0,6
0,8
1,0
1,2
2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012
Gini coeffieicnt
EU-15 EU-N10 EU-N2 EU-25 EU-27
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
61
Figure 21: Paid labour (€/hour), 2004-2012
Source: DG AGRI EU-FADN.
The key points are that, firstly, agricultural wages increased steadily (in nominal terms)
over the 2004-2012 period with only the EU-N2 group experiencing a decline in 2008 and
the EU-N10 one in 2009. Secondly, agricultural wages in the EU-N10 converged with those
in the EU-15, but those in the EU-N2 did not.
Agricultural wages averaged over the years 2010-2012 by farm type are shown in Figure
22. There are some apparent differences. Wages per hour are highest in the wine sector,
followed by the horticulture and milk sectors (the three sectors where wages exceed the
EU-27 average) and are lowest in Other grazing livestock and Fieldcrops farm types.
However, the way in which FADN takes account of casual labour is not clear and, in
practice, low-waged casual labour in the wine and horticultural sector might reduce the real
average wages in these sectors.
€0
€1
€2
€3
€4
€5
€6
€7
€8
€9
€10
2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012
EU-15 EU-N10 EU-N2 EU-25 EU-27
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
62
Figure 22: Paid labour (€/hour) by farm type, 2010-2012 average
Source: DG AGRI EU-FADN.
Annual volatility in paid agricultural wages is shown in Figure 23. The main volatility is in
the EU-10 where wages have been rising more quickly (see above). There was a major
impact in 2009 in EU-10, which is possibly linked to the adverse economic conditions
experienced in these Member States at the time.
€0,00
€1,00
€2,00
€3,00
€4,00
€5,00
€6,00
€7,00
€8,00
€9,00
€10,00
(1)
Fieldcrops
(2)
Horticulture
(3) Wine (4) Other
permanent
crops
(5) Milk (6) Other
grazing
livestock
(7)
Granivores
(8) Mixed
Hourly wage EU-27
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
63
Figure 23: Annual year-on-year change in paid agricultural wages per hour
Source: DG AGRI EU-FADN.
-30%
-20%
-10%
0%
10%
20%
30%
2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012
EU-15 EU-N10 EU-N2 EU-25 EU-27
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
64
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
65
4. THE DYNAMICS OF FARM INCOMES AND THE KEY
DRIVERS
KEY FINDINGS
A substantial minority of holdings (at least a third) derive income from other
gainful activities, earnings from property, pensions and transfers. The drivers of
this income are largely those that shape the general economy. Some 12% of EU-27
farms also draw income from diversified activities and diversified activities increase
with scale. This income is also driven by general economic factors, although some
will be related to the agricultural economy.
The most important component of agricultural revenue is returns from the market
which account for 86% of FADN Total Output for the EU-27.
Market returns are driven by quantity of output and price. Yields have been
relatively stable, but prices, especially for crops, have fluctuated considerably over
the 2005 to 2012 period.
Subsidies make up the balance of Total Output; there is no suggestion that
changes in subsidies have played a major role in the evolution of income.
The most important cost element is total intermediate consumption which
accounts for two-thirds of total expenses for the EU-27. Depreciation accounts for
15% of total costs, wages paid 9%, rent 5% and interest payments 3%.
Total intermediate consumption is made up of total specific costs (crop and
livestock) and overheads (machinery and building costs, energy, contract work and
direct inputs).
These elements of intermediate consumption have all increased between
2004 and 2012, but specific crop costs have increased the least. Within specific crop
costs, fertiliser cost is the most volatile element. Within overheads, energy costs
have been the most volatile and showed the sharpest absolute increase.
Although the use of paid labour has declined, wages paid per farm increased
steadily between 2007 and 2012
The importance of these income components differs by farm type. Subsidies
account for a quarter of the value of total output in Other grazing livestockfarms,
but less than 5% in the horticulture, granivore and wine sectors. There is less
difference in the relative importance of costs by farm type, although paid wages are
more important in the horticulture and wine sectors.
Analysis by farm size shows that the relative importance of subsidies decreases
as farm size increases.
The way in which farming incomes have been changing over time has been described in
previous sections. Here we are concerned with the explanations for these changes and the
factors that drive them. While the emphasis has to fall on the incomes that farmers derive
from their agricultural activities, it is necessary to first outline the broader picture that
embraces the incomes of the households of farmers, as this bears a close relationship with
the CAP’s core aim of ensuring a fair standard of living for the agricultural community.
When examining drivers, it is helpful to break these down according to scale (from global to
local, following the model of Hazell and Wood (2008)) and by time period.
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
66
4.1. Farm household income
By definition, farm households will receive part of their incomes from farming, and in many
cases where farming is carried on as a commercial activity this will be a major source
though not necessarily the largest in terms of earnings. As noted in Chapter 1, a
substantial minority of holdings in the Farm Structure Survey (at least a third and
probably a much higher proportion if spouses and partners are included) have some other
gainful activity (OGAs) outside the farm businesses, to which should be added earnings
from property (interest and rent) and various forms of pensions and transfers.
The important point to recognise in connection with OGAs and earning from property is that
the drivers are largely those that shape the general economy rather than those specific to
agriculture. The opportunity for farm households to take employment off the farm or build
a business will be affected by issues such as the general level and growth in consumer
spending growth, interest rates, government interventions to stimulate economic activity
and so on.
Then there is the issue of diversification on the farm into activities that are not strictly part
of the farm business, e.g. tourism, handicraft, processing of farm products, wood
processing, aquaculture, contract work using farm equipment, etc. Some 12% of EU-27
farms are diversified in this sense, and the proportion increases with farm size (see
Barthomeuf, 2008).
While pressure to consider on-farm diversification will mirror inversely what is happening to
profitability of agriculture, the opportunities to diversify and the earnings from them are
again likely to be driven primarily by what is happening in the general economy, though for
the process of farm products and for contract work using farm equipment (which may be
for other farms and forestry holdings) a case could be made that there may be a partial
connection with developments in the agricultural economy.
At the farm level the growth of OGAs and of diversification are commonly associated with
inter-generational change, so factors that impinge on decisions on succession and on
career choices by younger family members will act as drivers to the non-farming incomes
of farm households (Hill, 2012).
It should not be forgotten that, in the long-term, changes in the real value of assets
constitute an element in personal income. Farm families tend, as a group, to hold more
assets than society in general in most countries principally because of the value of the
agricultural land that they own. They are thus in a position to make substantial real capital
gains when land prices rise, even when these movements are brought about by non-
agricultural factors; these gains help explain why some farmers persist in remaining in
agriculture. Of course, were land prices to fall they would make capital losses. It follows
that factors that determine land prices are drivers of long-term income change
24
. One of
these is the preferential treatment given in taxation systems in many Member States to
wealth in the form of agricultural assets, particularly to capital gains on agricultural land
and on its transfer between generations (OECD, 2005). It follows that national government
policy in this area of tax legislation can materially affect long-term income. As things stand
24
Drivers of land prices are considered by European Parliament (2013b); Swinnen, et al. (2008); and the
Framework 7 project Factor Markets. Grant agreement N°: 245123-FP7-KBBE-2009-3.
http://www.factormarkets.eu/content/rural-land-market
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
67
and despite the commonality of preferential treatment, there are differences between
countries in capital taxation that are significant both to the comparisons between farmers
4.2. Income from agricultural activity
Any analysis of the drivers of change in the income from agricultural activity, the patterns
of which were described in Chapter 1 above, has to reflect the elements that compose the
indicators used to measure income and its changes. In this report they are, at
microeconomic level, FNVA/AWU and FFI/FWU and their equivalents at macroeconomic
level of NVA/AWU and Entrepreneurial Income per AWU of Family Labour Input (Indicators
A and B respectively when expressed in real terms and in index form). The definitions of
these indicators were given in Chapter 2 above. In short, the main elements are the value
of outputs, the costs of producing that output (which differ between the indicators),
subsidies received that are related to that production (though not necessarily coupled to it),
and the volume of the labour among which the rewards are divided. These are the main
groups of drivers that we need to examine.
4.2.1. Results by EU group
In order to focus on the most important drivers of change and to understand other
comparisons it is necessary first to know about the main components of both the revenue
received and the costs.
Figure 24 presents the composition of income and expenses/income by EU grouping using
an average for the 2010-2012 period. The difference between income and expenses is
Family Farm Income (FFI), shown in the right hand bar for each grouping
25
. Most family
farmers draw their income from what they would understand as profit (FFI), the difference
between income and expenditure.
The first point to note is the large difference between the absolute amounts of
revenue and expenditure per farm between EU groups. Average income in the EU-15 is
2.3 times that in the EU-N10 and 6.5 times higher than that in the EU-N2. However, the
focus of attention here has to fall on their compositions.
The most important revenue component seen in FADN results is returns from the
market. This accounts for 86% of FADN Total Output for the EU-27 and EU-15, 82% for
the EU-N10 and 88% for the EU-N2; subsidies (the sum of net current and investment
subsidies) make up the balance. These include EU coupled and decoupled payments, less
favoured area (LFA) payments, rural development payments and national aid, in all cases
net of any relevant taxes (but not, of course, taxes on incomes).
The most important cost element for all groupings is total intermediate consumption
which accounts for just over two-thirds (68%) of total expenses for the EU-27 grouping
26
.
This is a broadly consistent proportion across the sub-groups. The next most important cost
component is depreciation which accounts for 15% of costs in the EU-27; again this is
25
European Commission (2014b) presents similar information, but instead of showing FFI, shows the estimated
opportunity costs of own factors’, which comprises imputed values for the farmers’ time, own land and own
capital. This sometimes leads to expenses being higher than income which leads to statements about
profitability which are somewhat misleading.
26
Note that European Commission (2014b) states that intermediate consumption accounts for only half of total
expenses; this is because these total expenses include own factors, the rewards to the farmer’s input, which is
potentially misleading.
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
68
consistent across the sub-groups. Wages paid account for 9% of total costs for the EU-27,
rent for 5% and interest payments 3%. While the importance of wages is comparable
across the groupings, rent is highest in the EU-N2 at 7% and lowest in the EU-N10 at 3%
(the EU-15 is the same as the EU-27). Interest payments are lower in both the EU-N10
(2%) and the EU-N2 (1%) while again, the EU-15 is the same as the EU-27. In summary,
there are in fact few differences in the components of income.
The biggest difference between the groups is in fact in Family Farm Income which is
equivalent to a quarter of total output (24%) in the EU-27, EU-15 and EU-N10, but is a
third (33%) of total output in the EU-N2, although in absolute terms it is smallest there.
Figure 24: Income components per farm by EU group, 2010-12 average
Source: DG AGRI EU-FADN.
In addition to the components of farm income it is also necessary to consider the impact
of structural change over time. As farms increase in scale returns per labour unit will
increase. Average farm size tends to increase over time (European Commission, 2013) and
this will exert some upward influence on farm incomes when measured at the level of the
farm or, as we do throughout this analysis, per unit of labour.
€0
€20.000
€40.000
€60.000
€80.000
€100.000
€120.000
Receipts Expenses
and income
Receipts Expenses
and income
Receipts Expenses
and income
Receipts Expenses
and income
EU-15 EU-N10 EU-N2 EU-27
0%
10%
20%
30%
40%
50%
60%
70%
80%
90%
100%
Receipts Expenses
and income
Receipts Expenses
and income
Receipts Expenses
and income
Receipts Expenses
and income
EU-15 EU-N10 EU-N2 EU-27
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
69
Another factor which is not a component of income, but which influences income as
measured per labour unit, is the quantity of labour used. This tends to decrease over
time as labour efficiency increases (European Commission, 2013). This will also manifest as
an upward influence on income when measured as a return to labour over time.
4.2.2. Results by type of farming
In absolute terms per farm both the values of revenues and the costs were highest
among granivores, horticulture and milk farms, and these also had the largest sales to the
market (Figure 25). The lowest, both for total revenue and for sales to the market,
occurred among the other permanent cropsfarms. While it is clear that the market is the
main source of revenue for all farming types, accounting for some 85% of the total, and
hence changes there will be the main revenue drivers, the importance of subsidies is not
uniform. They accounted for about a quarter of the value of total output in the Other
grazing livestockgroup, but a far lower share (less than 5%) in horticulture, granivores
and wine farms; even quite large changes in subsidies are thus unlikely to make major
impacts on the total value of output among these farming types.
On the costs side, the balance between the ways in which the various categories of costs
absorb revenues, and what is left to form FFI, is broadly similar across the farming types.
Paid wages are relatively more important in horticulture and wine, so what happens to
labour costs could be expected to be a more significant driver there than among other farm
types. However, in all farm types the largest costs are those that make up ‘intermediate
consumptionrather than those of the fixed factors(payments for rent, interest and hired
labour) and hence this is likely to be where the biggest cost-based drivers of income are
located.
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
70
Figure 25: Income components per farm by EU farm type, 2010-12 average
Source: DG AGRI EU-FADN.
4.2.3. Results by size of farm
Some interesting patterns emerge from examination of income components by farm size
(Figure 26), though the relationship between farm size and the dominant farm
types, and of coverage of Member States should be borne in mind (particularly the
importance of mixed farms and Bulgaria, Romania and Portugal to the smallest size class
and of granivores and horticulture to the largest size classes). Nevertheless, a general
relationship is seen in which the relative importance of subsidies declines with
increasing size of farm, more than halving between the smaller size classes and the
largest (from about one fifth to less than one tenth of the total value of output). Another
feature is the rise in relative importance among the costs of intermediate consumption with
increasing farm size. Wages paid take a larger share among the biggest farms, but this is
probably a reflection of the dominance of granivores and horticulture in this size class.
Perhaps surprising is the finding that the proportion of total output that remains to the
operators as FFI declines as larger farm classes are encountered, though of course the
absolute amounts will be larger.
€0
€50.000
€100.000
€150.000
€200.000
€250.000
€300.000
R E & I R E & I R E & I R E & I R E & I R E & I R E & I R E & I
Fieldcrops Horticulture Wine Other
permanent
crops
Milk Other
grazing
livestock
Granivores Mixed
0%
10%
20%
30%
40%
50%
60%
70%
80%
90%
100%
R E & I R E & I R E & I R E & I R E & I R E & I R E & I R E & I
Fieldcrops Horticulture Wine Other
permanent
crops
Milk Other
grazing
livestock
Granivores Mixed
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
71
Figure 26: Income components per farm by economic size, 2010-12 average
Source: AGRI EU-FADN.
4.2.4. Changes in income components between 2004-2006 and 2010-2012
A further method of identifying the key drivers of income is to look at the changes in
absolute amounts of each element between two representative periods, in our case
between the averages of two three-year periods (2004-2006 and 2010-2012). From this it
is possible to identify which items were responsible for overall changes in income. For
example, was there a rise in the value of output and no change in costs, or static output
and a fall in costs, or some other combination? On the costs side, some elements may
have changed dramatically in percentage terms but, because they are small in
absolute terms, have very little impact on overall costs and incomes.
By way of summary, the absolute change in the components of income between the
average for the 2004-2006 and 2010-2012 periods is set out in Figure 27 for the EU-25 and
the two EU sub-groups that it is possible to examine over this period. The figure makes
clear that the key components which drive the development of income are, on the revenue
side, total output, and on the cost side, total intermediate consumption. There is some
difference in the scale of changes by EU grouping, most notably the greater increase in
subsidies in the EU-N10. This aside, changes to the components of income were lower in
€0
€200.000
€400.000
€600.000
€800.000
€1.000.000
€1.200.000
€1.400.000
R E & I R E & I R E & I R E & I R E & I R E & I
(1) 2 000 - < 8
000 EUR
(2) 8 000 - <
25 000 EUR
(3) 25 000 - <
50 000 EUR
(4) 50 000 - <
100 000 EUR
(5) 100 000 -
< 500 000 EUR
(6) >= 500
000 EUR
0%
10%
20%
30%
40%
50%
60%
70%
80%
90%
100%
R E & I R E & I R E & I R E & I R E & I R E & I
(1) 2 000 - < 8
000 EUR
(2) 8 000 - < 25
000 EUR
(3) 25 000 - <
50 000 EUR
(4) 50 000 - <
100 000 EUR
(5) 100 000 - <
500 000 EUR
(6) >= 500 000
EUR
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
72
the EU-N10 than in the EU-15, although this is largely because these changes are from a
lower base.
Figure 27: Change in value of income components 2004-06 average compared to
2010-12 average by EU sub-group
Source: DG AGRI EU-FADN.
Figure 28 presents similar analysis for farm type. The same general pattern prevails in
that total output and total intermediate consumption are the key components of income in
terms of change over the period. Key points to note are that the granivore sector saw the
greatest changes in these components, although as has been explained above, this is partly
the result of the correlation between this farm types and increased scale. The larger
increase in wages paid in the horticultural sector should also be noted, as should the
greater increase in depreciation in the granivore and milk sectors.
€0
€5.000
€10.000
€15.000
€20.000
€25.000
€30.000
Total Output Total
subsidies
Total
intermediate
consumption
Depreciation Wages paid Rent Interest
EU-25 EU-15 EU-N10
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
73
Figure 28: Change in value of income components 2004-06 average compared to
2010-12 average by farm type
Source: DG AGRI EU-FADN.
4.2.5. Changes in the key drivers
Agricultural income varies substantial from one year to the next as a natural consequence
of weather and other short-term factors and is anticipated by farmers (though they may
occasionally represent disasters for individuals). This is why in this report we focus on
income averaged over a three year period. In this section we focus on medium and long-
term variation and trends.
From the above, and from the literature, it is clear that the main drivers of income are on
the revenue side of the income calculation, the value of total output, which is the
combination of market output (price and quantity) as well as subsidies. Prices are affected
by trends, medium-term slumps and high-price periods. Quantity is affected by changes in
productivity or more/less factors of production, such as capital. Subsidies can be changed
by policy decision.
On the cost side of the income calculation, the main items are the costs of intermediate
production (price and quantity, trends and medium-term movements) and labour costs,
which are a combination of wage levels (trends) and quantities of labour employed (to give
labour costs). Other relatively minor drivers are interest costs (again a combination of
levels of charges, although in the period considered these were largely static, and the
amount of borrowing) and rents. Depreciation is a cost that has changed in absolute
amounts more than labour, though we have not treated it as a main driver because, by its
nature, the rate at which capital items are assumed to be consumed is set administratively
-€20.000
€0
€20.000
€40.000
€60.000
€80.000
€100.000
€120.000
€140.000
Total output Total
subsidies
Total
intermediate
consumption
Depreciation Wages paid Rent Interest
Fieldcrops Horticulture Wine Other permanent crops
Milk Other grazing livestock Granivores Mixed
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
74
and is independent of market conditions, and the stock to which it applies can only change
gradually.
When looking at indicators expressed per work unit (either total labour or only family
labour), it is necessary to look at how the amount of labour used in agriculture has
changed. These issues are considered in turn in the sub-sections below.
4.2.6. Total output
Figure 29 shows the two principal components of Total output’: crops and crop products
and livestock and livestock products on FADN farms. When using this data source to trace
developments in drivers over time care has to be taken to account for the enlargement that
took place in 2007, so that the series should be properly interpreted as falling into two
sections, 2004-2006 and 2007-2012 (this is not the case for Eurostat data which is EU-27
throughout the period of interest). It is also necessary to recall that FADN results are given
in nominal values, and that inflation will have caused small but gradual changes in values
over the runs of years studied (annual inflation of the Euro averaged a little less than 2%
over the period).
In the pre-enlargement period shown in Figure 30 there is no noticeable trend in either the
value of crop or livestock output. Following the drop in levels associated with the inclusion
of Bulgaria and Romania into the EU, the first three years were characterised by stagnation
or decline to 2009, after which there was a noticeable rise.
Figure 29: Evolution of the components of Total Output per farm, EU-25 2004-
2006, EU-27 2007-2012
Source: DG AGRI EU-FADN.
€0
€5.000
€10.000
€15.000
€20.000
€25.000
€30.000
€35.000
€40.000
2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012
Total Output: crops and crop products Total Output: livestock and livestock products
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
75
Total output is the product of quantity of output and price. Of the two, when looking
at group average results the more volatile element is the market prices obtained by
farmers, and this is particularly clear with farm crops.
Figures from Eurostat (that cover the EU-27 throughout the period) show that prices of
crop products rose substantially from 2005 to 2008, typically by about 50%, but then fell
dramatically in a single year, with prices in 2009 almost back to the 2005 level. However,
from 2009 to 2012 there was a sustained recovery to levels that exceeded the previous
peak. Prices for livestock and livestock products were relatively more stable, with only
milk showing a similar pronounced fall in 2009. Other categories were quite stable, while
poultry showed a rising trend.
Figure 30: Evolution of crop and livestock prices, EU-27, 2005 = 100
Source: Eurostat.
Of course, at the farm level there can be changes in physical crop output and animal
performance that can affect the business revenue, and occasionally there will be disease or
climatic conditions that are more widely experienced. However, at group average level
there is a remarkable consistency of yields over time. Figure 31 shows wheat and maize
yields and milk output per dairy cow, taken from FADN. Bearing in mind the break in the
series associated with enlargement in 2007, across the EU wheat yields and maize yields
have been stable though perhaps with a slight downward trend. In contrast, milk yields per
cow have shown a small but steady rise.
0
50
100
150
200
2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012
Crop price index (2005=100)
Cereals (including seeds)
Oil seeds and oleaginous fruits (including seeds)
Protein crops (including seeds)
0
50
100
150
200
2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012
Livestock price index
(2005=100)
Cattle excluding calves Pigs Sheep and goats Poultry Cows' milk
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
76
Figure 31: Evolution of yield per unit of output, EU-25 2004-06, EU-27 2007-12
Source: DG AGRI EU-FADN.
Turning to the other main element in the revenue of farms, subsidies, we see that at EU
level the accession of Bulgaria and Romania lowered the average received per farm (Figure
32). However, from 2007 there was a modest rise to 2010, since when the level has been
approximately sustained. Certainly, at EU-27 level there is no suggestion that changes in
subsidies have had a major part to play in the evolution of incomes. However, the
importance of payments for public goods via subsidies, for example agri-environment
payments under the second pillar of the CAP should be noted, although these are
replacing more production related subsidies rather than increasing the total amount of
subsidy available.
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012
Yield per hectare/yield per cow
Wheat yield (tonnes/ha) Maize yield (tonnes/ha) Milk yield (tonnes/cow/year)
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
77
Figure 32: Evolution of subsidies, EU-25 2004-06, EU-27 2007-12
Source: DG AGRI EU-FADN.
4.2.7. Costs of intermediate production
From the analysis of income components above, the key cost element to focus on is total
intermediate consumption”. This is defined within FADN as total specific costs (including
inputs produced on the holding) and overheads arising from production in the accounting
year”. “Total specific costsincludes specific crop costs (bought and home-grown seeds and
plants, fertilisers, crop protection and other crop specific costs) and specific livestock costs
(bought and home-grown feed for grazing livestock, bought and home-grown feed for pigs
and poultry and other livestock specific costs). Overheads includes machinery and
building current costs, energy, contract work and other direct inputs.
Figure 33 shows the evolution of specific crop costs, specific livestock costs and total
farming overheads
27
for the EU-27. Specific crop costs per hectare increased gradually
after enlargement, but without large variations between years. Livestock costs per
livestock unit appeared to be quite stable either side of enlargement, but fell in 2009 and
then increased steadily but quite rapidly, rising by some
€103 per farm between 2007 and
2012). In contrast, farming overheads per farm were on a rising trend before
enlargement (a 10% rise between 2004 and 2006), and this has continued consistently
since 2007 with a steady upward trend from 2007 to 2012 that resulted in a 33% increase
over this period, or just over €4,000 per farm.
27
It is not possible to calculate overheads with reference to any other unit than the farm. The requirement for
FADN to be representative in terms of farm sizes mitigates against the risk that the trend is influenced by
structural change.
€0
€2.000
€4.000
€6.000
€8.000
€10.000
€12.000
€14.000
€16.000
€18.000
2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012
EU-27 EU-15 EU-N10 EU-N2
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
78
Figure 33: Evolution of specific crop and livestock costs and total farming
overheads, EU-25 2004-16, EU27 2007-12
Source: DG AGRI EU-FADN.
Among the specific crop costs, fertilisers are clearly the category that has been the most
volatile and has increased the most per farm at EU level (Figure 34). Costs were rising
before EU enlargement, but among EU-27 there was a rapid upward shift from 2007 for two
years, a sharp drop in 2010, subsequently followed by a further short rise to leave
spending per farm almost double the 2007 level and representing an increased cost of
some
€2,500 per farm. In contrast, the other elements of crop costs were more stable and
showed gentler upward trends.
Among the costs of producing livestock, expenditures per farm showed no clear trend up to
2009, but since then have risen quite sharply, by in the region of
€2,000 per farm for both
grazing livestock and for pig and poultry farms.
€0
€2.000
€4.000
€6.000
€8.000
€10.000
€12.000
€14.000
€16.000
€18.000
€0
€100
€200
€300
€400
€500
€600
€700
€800
€900
2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012
Total farming overheads
Specific crop and livestock costs
Specific crop costs per hectare Specific livestock costs per Livestock Unit
Total farming overheads per farm
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
79
Figure 34: Evolution of specific crop and livestock costs per farm, EU-25 2004-06,
EU-27 2007-12
Source: DG AGRI EU-FADN.
Turning again to overheads, energy costs stand out as being the least stable and showing
the sharpest absolute rise (Figure 35). Not only was there a sharp increase in EU-25 for the
period 2004-2006, but since enlargement to EU-27 these has been an addition to costs of
some
€1,500 per farm between 2007 and 2012. The
rises of the other components have
been persistent, but steadier.
€0
€1.000
€2.000
€3.000
€4.000
€5.000
2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012
Seeds and plants (including home-grown) Fertilisers
Crop protection and pesticides Other specific crop costs
€0
€2.000
€4.000
€6.000
€8.000
€10.000
€12.000
2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012
Feed for grazing livestock (including home-grown)
Feed for pigs & poultry (including home-grown)
Other livestock specific costs
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
80
Figure 35: Evolution of the elements of total farm overheads, EU-25 2004-06, EU-
27 2007-12
Source: DG AGRI EU-FADN.
4.2.8. Interest costs
As might be expected, costs of the so-called fixed factors(hired labour, borrowed capital
and rented land) tend not to be major short-term drivers of income. Rents change so
slowly that they can be ignored as drivers of income change at group level, though or
course for individual farmers a rent increase can be a significant event.
A ‘fixed factor’ that carries the potential for cost changes that are volatile and unpredictable
is borrowed capital, in that, while the size of loans taken for land purchase and other
investments is unlikely to vary much in the short-term, this does not necessarily apply to
short-term loans taken to finance working capital and to assist farmers dealing with
fluctuation in their profitability. Also, interest rates are generally determined by factors
outside the control of farmers, and even outside the influence of agricultural policy; interest
rates may, in some circumstances shift in unpredictable and potentially damaging ways.
However, the evidence from FADN farms is that, over the period under study interest costs
have not been placing increasing pressure on the incomes from farming. This has happened
despite rises in level of borrowing. On average, the average size of long and medium-
term loans has been trending upwards, both before and after enlargement (Figure 36). So
too have short-term loans, though at a much lower level per farm. However, after a sharp
rise between 2007 and 2008, the overall amount of interest paid per farm has been in
decline.
€0
€1.000
€2.000
€3.000
€4.000
€5.000
€6.000
2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012
Machinery & building current costs Energy Contract work Other direct inputs
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
81
Figure 36: Evolution of value of outstanding loans and annual interest per farm,
EU-25 2004-2006, EU-27 2007-2012
Source: DG AGRI EU-FADN.
4.2.9. Labour costs
Costs of hired labour are not a particularly major driver of the incomes of farms for EU
agriculture as a whole, though they can be important for some types of farming, such
as horticulture and granivores. Some countries will be more sensitive to changes in labour
costs than others because of their greater dependence on hired labour.
Labour as a factor of production can be important as a driver of farm income change for
two main reasons. First, there is the cost that farm businesses have to pay for hired labour.
Second there is the number of hired workers. Analysis of FADN results shows that the
volume of paid labour used on the average FADN farm (measured in hours of input) is
much smaller (less than a third) than the amount of unpaid (‘family’) labour (Figure 37).
Both categories have been declining, but the wages paid to the hired labour had been
rising, the result of increases in wages more than offsetting falling numbers of employees.
The average cost per farm has risen by almost
€1,000 between 2007 and 2012.
However, at EU-27 level the change is gradual.
€0
€200
€400
€600
€800
€1.000
€1.200
€1.400
€1.600
€1.800
€2.000
€0
€5.000
€10.000
€15.000
€20.000
€25.000
€30.000
€35.000
€40.000
2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012
Interest paid
Value of outstanding loans
Long & medium-term loans Short-term loans Interest paid
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
82
Figure 37: Evolution of labour use and wages paid per farm, EU-25 2004-2006,
EU-27 2007-2012
Source: DG AGRI EU-FADN.
Another critical influence of the volume of labour is in the construction of income indicators.
As has been shown earlier, at both aggregate and farm levels, the most cited income
indicators are expressed per work unit (total or unpaid familylabour), depending on the
indicator. It is quite possible that income per farm or for the agricultural sector is declining
over time, but income per work unit will increase if the volume of labour declines
sufficiently quickly, as has commonly been found. This makes the accurate measurement of
labour inputs critical, though the ability to quantify it, especially the unpaid labour of self-
employed farmers and their families, is notoriously difficult, especially in the short-term.
€0
€1.000
€2.000
€3.000
€4.000
€5.000
€6.000
€7.000
0
500
1.000
1.500
2.000
2.500
3.000
3.500
2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012
Wages paid
Paid and unpaid labour (hours)
Unpaid labour (hours) Paid labour (hours) Wages paid
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
83
5. DIFFERENCES BETWEEN MEMBER STATES
KEY FINDINGS
A Common Agricultural Policy does not result in a common absolute level of
income for the average farm in different Member States. Belgium, Denmark,
Germany, France, Luxembourg, the Netherlands and the UK stand out as having
high farm income. Amongst the EU-N10 Member States, only in the Czech Republic,
Estonia and Hungary do farm income indicators exceed or come close to the EU-27
average.
The main reason for this is the size of farms; the mix of farm types also plays a
role. However, when farms of the same size and type are compared, performance is
often equivalent throughout the EU-28 and sometimes higher in the EU-N10 and EU-
N2 than it is in the EU-15.
The influence of farm structure is also important at the regional level with farm
incomes varying widely within Member States. This regional variation is especially
noticeable in France and Germany.
In terms of the growth in farm incomes between figures averaged for the 2004-2006
and 2010-2012 periods, EU-N10 Member States have outperformed EU-15 Member
States as a result of higher market prices, access to the single market and
increased public support. The increase in farm income per unit of labour in these
Member States also reflects decreases in total labour use. Despite these increases,
farm income in the EU-N10 and especially the EU-N2 lags behind that in the
EU-15.
Within this overall trend, farm incomes are highly variable from year to year, but
farm incomes in different Member States move in different directions and by
different magnitudes, partly the result of structural difference in farm type.
Some Member States have higher levels of income variation than others. Again this
is partly structural with income in the granivore and fieldcrop sectors relatively
instable while income in horticulture and permanent crops is relatively stable.
The relatively low variability in farm income seen in Greece, Spain and Italy reflects
the substantial proportion of other permanent crop farm types in these Member
States.
There is a tendency for EU-N12 Member States to have higher coefficients of
variation than EU-15 Member States, but this is partly the result of the general
upward trend in farm incomes that these Member States have experienced.
Farm income levels differ between Member States within farm type, although this
is partly the result of the structure of farms within FADN. A key factor in differences
between Member States by farm type is actually farm size within the FADN sample.
As economic size increases, it becomes more common for farms from the EU-N10
to show higher FFI/FWU than farms in the EU-15. For the largest size group, only
farms in Italy and the UK from the EU-15 have farm income higher than the EU-27
average.
Agricultural wages differ markedly between Member States. In Denmark, the
Netherlands and Sweden wage levels average more than €15 per hour while in
Bulgaria, Greece, Latvia, Lithuania, Poland and Romania the average is
€3 or less.
Agricultural wages vary little within Member States, although there are some
exceptions with wages higher in Champagne than in the rest of France and higher in
the east of Germany where the wages of company farm managers and
administrators are included in the figures.
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
84
Comparisons between Member States with regard to the incomes of farmers from
agriculture can be based on differences in a number of parameters. The most useful are
specific levels, directions of change and variability. While the focus of attention must be on
the rewards of self-employment in farming, the earnings of hired workers should not be
ignored as they are also seen as members of the agricultural community in some Member
States.
As in earlier chapters, there are two main source of information: Eurostat’s income
indicators based on the aggregate Economic Accounts for Agriculture, and the European
Commission’s Farm Accountancy Data Network EU FADN). Both are used here.
5.1. Differences in income levels
The main conclusion when comparing absolute incomes across Member States is that a
Common Agriculture Policy does not result in a common absolute level of income
in an average farm in different Member States, largely because size structure differs
by Member State. Using FADN results
28
, absolute levels of FNVA/AWU and FFI/FWU in
Member States, averaged of for the years 2010-2012 to allow for short-run changes at
group level, are shown in Figure 38. Seven Member States stand out as having relatively
high levels of both indicators during this period - Belgium, Denmark, Germany, France,
Luxembourg, the Netherlands and the UK. FNVA/AWU was considerably higher in Denmark
than in any other Member State
29
. The Czech Republic, Estonia and Hungary were the only
EU-N10 Member States where farm income indicators exceeded or were close to the EU-27
average.
28
The reader should recall that the field of observation of FADN differs by Member State meaning that in some
Member States small farms are not included in the results (see Annex 1). This has implications for EU level
results.
29
The difference between FNVA/AWU and FFI/FWU in Denmark (FNVA/AWU is more than twice FFI/FWU) reflects
the unusual dominance there of an approach to inter-generational transfer that involves children borrowing
from financial institutions to buy the farm from parents. This provides an asset which can provide a pension for
the parents but results in substantial interest payments which are included within FNVA, but are removed in
the FFI calculation. Heavy interest costs are often a stimulant to seeking off-farm jobs.
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
85
Figure 38: FNVA/AWU and FFI/FWU by Member State (2010-2012 average)
Source: DG AGRI EU-FADN.
The explanation for these differences will include factors such as the predominant types of
farming and the market situation these faced in the period 2010-2012; it will also be a
function of management skill and other determinants of productivity. However, the main
factor will be the distribution of farms by size (and hence the average farm size). The
clear relationship between farm size and income levels (both FNVA/AWU and
FFI/FWU), which applies both generally and within types of farming, has already been
commented upon (Chapter 1). Those Member States that have predominantly large farm
business in FADN tend to have the highest incomes in Figure 39, and those with
predominantly small farms (Bulgaria, Romania, Greece and Portugal) are among the
countries that have the lowest incomes (see Map 1 for distribution by farm size within the
FADN sample). Supplementary analysis has shown that for farms of the same size and
type, farm performance is often equivalent throughout the EU-28 and sometimes higher in
the EU-N10 and EU-N2 than it is in the EU-15
30
.
30
For example, FFI/FWU averaged for the three years 2010-12 in the Romanian milk sector was €58,561 and
€55,388 in the Latvian milk sector compared to values between €26,473 in France and €50,709 in Ireland and
encompassing Belgium, Germany, Spain and the UK, amongst others.
€0
€10.000
€20.000
€30.000
€40.000
€50.000
€60.000
€70.000
€80.000
€90.000
€100.000
BE BG CY CZ DK DE EL ES EE FR HU IE IT LT LU LV MT NL AT PL PT RO FI SE SK SI UK
FNVA/AWU FFI/FWU EU-27 FNVA/AWU EU-27 FFI/FWU
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
86
Figure 39: FADN coverage of economic farm size (ES) by Member State, 2010-
2012
Source: DG AGRI EU-FADN.
In countries that have a regional FADN structure there are often differences between
regions in absolute income levels, reflecting the geographical distribution of types of
farming and, to some extent, farm sizes (for example, Germany). Thus care has to be
taken, when comparing Member States in terms of absolute incomes, to recognise that a
single country average can hide substantial regional variations.
In terms of FNVA/AWU in the years 2010-2012 incomes were relatively high (>€40,000 per
AWU) in Belgium, the Netherlands and Denmark but also in most of England (not the South
West or West Midlands) much of northern France (Nord Pas de Calais, Picardy, Normandy,
Ile de France, Champagne, Lorraine, Centre, Burgundy and Poitou-Charentes) and northern
Germany (Schleswig-Holstein, Mecklenburg-Vorpommern, Niedersachsen and Sachsen-
Anhalt), and in the Lombardy region of Italy. France and Germany demonstrated a
particularly wide range of regional comparisons. In term of the lowest levels of FNVA/AWU,
these typified Latvia and Lithuania and many, though not all, of the regions of Poland,
Bulgaria and Romania, together with the Norte region of Portugal.
0%
10%
20%
30%
40%
50%
60%
70%
80%
90%
100%
BE BG CY CZ DK DE EL ES EE FR HU IE IT LT LU LV MT NL AT PL PT RO FI SE SK SI UK
Proportion of farms represented in the FADN sample by
consolidated ES class
(1+2+3) 2 000 - <50 000 EUR (4+5+6) >=50 000 EUR
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
87
Map 1: FNVA in Euro per AWU by FADN region, 2010-2012 average
Source: DG AGRI EU-FADN.
When turning to our preferred income indicator (FFI/FWU) for 2010-2012 a pattern
emerges that, while echoing that shown by FNVA/AWU, has substantial differences (Map 2).
The highest levels of income are no longer in Belgium and the Netherlands though they are
still found in regions of England, France and Denmark. In Germany the higher incomes are
concentrated in fewer regions (Mecklenburg-Vorpommern and Sachsen-Anhalt), and in
France there is a greater degree of regional differences than shown by FNVA/AWU with the
highest FFI/FWU in Picardy, Ile de France, Champagne, Centre and Poitou-Charentes. The
locations of regions with the lowest levels of income are broadly similar using either
indicator.
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
88
Map 2: FFI in Euro per FWU by FADN region, 2010-2012 average
Source: DG AGRI EU-FADN.
5.2. Differences in direction of change
The second income issue to examine is the way that income levels have changed over time.
In doing this it is important to bear in mind the potentially misleading impression that can
be gained by focusing on specific years. By using FADN’s FFI/FWU indicator averaged for
the 2004-2006 and 2010-2012 periods we have reduced the risk of presenting a misleading
impression somewhat (Figure 40). The data within FADN are nominal, so in real terms
increases would be rather less than suggested.
The average increase in FADN’s FFI/FWU between the two periods of 2004-2006 and 2010-
2012 was 59%. Only a small number of Member States saw a decrease in nominal terms
(Spain, Luxembourg and Malta). Belgium and Greece saw very small nominal increases
which in practice probably reflect a static real position. Most of the largest increases came
in the EU-N10, as might be expected given their lower starting point. Hungary, Lithuania,
Slovakia and Estonia all saw FFI/FWU more than double. Eurostat (2014) points to the
positive effects on these new entrants of an increase in public support granted to the farm
sector, higher market prices and access to the single market. The growth of incomes in
these countries reflects not only what is happening in the NVA (or FFI) per farm, but also in
the shedding of labour that was typical over this period. Eurostat (2014) also points out
that despite this positive performance, income in the EU-N10 still lags that in the EU-15;
income in the EU-N2 is further behind (see also Figure 6 in Chapter 3.2.3.1).
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
89
The large increase in FADN’s FFI/FWU in Sweden is the result of an unusually low starting
base while that in Denmark is a mixture of a very low value in 2004 and a very high one in
2012 which, despite the use of averages, has a substantial impact.
Other Member States saw growth in FADN’s FFI/FWU that was far smaller than typical;
most of the six with least growth were EU-15 countries (Luxembourg, Ireland, Belgium and
Finland), though two were EU-N10 (Malta and Hungary). However, Eurostat also points out
that, despite the successive income boosts experienced by the EU-N12, agricultural income
per AWU in 2014 for this group of countries came to an average around
€5,800 compared
to about
€24,500 for the EU
-15.
Figure 40: Change in FFI/FWU, average 2010-2012 vs average 2004-2006
Source: DG AGRI EU-FADN.
Note: Bulgaria and Romania compare 2010-12 with 2007-09.
5.2.1. Changes: short-term
Income levels and trends in income over a period do not insulate farmers from short-term
income movement. Though these may be anticipated and to some extent counteracted at
the farm level by steps such as choice of and mix between enterprises, informal and formal
insurance and other risk-reducing strategies, to which CAP and Member State policy
interventions may add further stability, nevertheless large short-term shifts in income will
place strain on the ability of farms to cope. Some indication of year-on-year change in
FFI/FWU is given in Figure 41. This shows that in any one year, while some Member States
saw a fall in FFI/FWU, others saw an increase. Member States which saw an increase
(decrease) in one year frequently saw a decrease (increase) in the next (17 Member
-50%
0%
50%
100%
150%
200%
BE BG CY CZ DK DE EL ES EE FR HU IE IT LT LU LV MT NL AT PL PT RO FI SE SK SI UK
Change in FFI/FWU 2004-06 average vs 2010-12 average
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
90
States). Of course, some types of farming and some sizes of farm will have experienced
shifts that are both greater and lesser than the national averages, and individual farms
(rather than the group averages shown here) will have shown a further degree of
instability.
Figure 41: Annual change in FFI/FWU, 2010-11 and 2011-12
Source: DG AGRI EU-FADN.
However, as has been noted repeatedly, looking at changes between individual years is not
a reliable guide to the typical level of income variability within a country, even at national
level. For this, it is necessary to consider the variation over a run of years and the
conventional way of expressing this is as a coefficient of variation (described in Chapter
3.2.3.8). The key point is that this takes into account the different absolute levels of
income. The coefficients for the period 2004-2012 are shown in Figure 42.
The most noticeable feature is that some countries have far higher levels of income
variation than others, though this does not necessarily apply equally to both of the
income indicators chosen. In particular, Denmark shows an extraordinary degree of
instability in FFI/FWU (also seen in Figure 41); this reflects primarily the small margin left
from NVA after its typically high interest charges are deducted
31
(as well as rent and
wages) and hence small changes in NVA (which are not exceptional by the standards of
many other Member States) are transformed into very large shifts in FFI. There is a
tendency for EU-N12 Member States to have somewhat higher coefficients of variation than
the EU-27 average, but in part this will reflect the general trend of increasing incomes seen
in them.
31
See, for example, van der Veen, et al. (2002) who explain that this is partly a function of family farm transfer
between the generations using credit.
-50%
0%
50%
100%
150%
200%
250%
300%
350%
BE BG CY CZ DK DE EL ES EE FR HU IE IT LT LU LV MT NL AT PL PT RO FI SE SK SI UK
2010-11 change 2011-12 change
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
91
Attention has already been drawn to what appears to be inherent instability over time in
some types of farming (granivores and fieldcrops) and stability in others (horticulture
and other permanent crops), and variability at Member State level will reflect their
relative composition by type. The relatively low variability seen in Greece, Spain and Italy
reflects the substantial proportion of other permanent crop farm types in these Member
States (28% to 44% c.f, EU-27 average of 14%). Cyprus also has a high proportion of
permanent crops (42%), but incomes appear to be less stable because they have risen
steadily over the period.
Figure 42: Coefficient of variation of farm income indicators by Member State,
2004-12
Source: DG AGRI EU-FADN.
5.3. Comparisons between Member State incomes for each main
farm type (FADN data)
Figure 43 presents a comparison between FFI/FWU in all Member States for the main
eight farm types. This is presented in index form (EU-27 = 100) to facilitate comparisons
between farm types. Zero values (for example Fieldcrops: Luxembourg) indicate no data.
To a large extent the data reflect different national farm income levels such that for all farm
types incomes tend to be highest in EU-15 Member States.
For fieldcrops, the highest incomes are seen in Denmark, the UK and the Netherlands. The
Member States with above EU-27 average incomes are all from the EU-15. For
horticulture the largest incomes are found in the UK and Netherlands; FFI/FWU in
Hungary exceeds the EU-27 average. In the wine sector FFI/FWU is highest in Luxembourg
followed by France. Incomes in the Romanian wine sector are relatively low in FFI/FWU
0,00
0,10
0,20
0,30
0,40
0,50
0,60
0,70
0,80
0,90
1,00
BE BG CY CZ DK DE EL ES EE FR HU IE IT LT LU LV MT NL AT PL PT RO FI SE SK SI UK
Var FNVA/AWU Var FFI/FWU EU-27 FNVA/AWU EU-27 FFI/FWU
DK = 6.11
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
92
terms. For other permanent crops FFI/FWU is again relatively high in EU-15 Member
States, in this case Belgium and Denmark. Incomes in Greece and Portugal are below the
EU-27 average and comparable with the level in many EU-N12 Member States. In the milk
sector FFI/FWU is highest in Italy, with high levels also seen in the UK, Netherlands Ireland
and Belgium. The Czech Republic, Hungary and Malta all have approximately average
FFI/FWU in this sector. FFI/FWU in the other grazing livestock sector appear less
heterogeneous than in many other sectors and a number of EU-N12 Member States have
incomes at or above the EU-27 average (Cyrus, Czech Republic, Hungary, Latvia and
Slovakia). Denmark stands out as having had negative average FFI/FWU for the 2010-12
period
32
. FFI/FWU in the Italian granivore sector is more than three times the EU-27
average; this indicator is more than twice the EU-27 average in the UK. FFI/FWU in
Bulgaria, Malta and Romania is very much lower than is typical. FFI/FWU is more than five
times higher than the EU-27 average in the Belgian and UK mixed farm sectors and more
than four times the average in France and Netherlands. However, this result is partly the
result of the structure of farms within FADN. Some 29% of mixed farms in the sample are
in Poland and 44% in Romania and, because incomes are low in these Member States,
largely as a result of the number of small farms, this reduces the EU-27 average
considerably. FFI/FWU in Sweden was on average negative over the 2010-2012 period in
Sweden.
Figure 43: FFI/FWU by farm type and Member State, 2010-2012 average, EU-27 =
100
32
This is largely explained by the high borrowing and interest charges associated with inter-generational land
transfer which is a characteristic of this country.
-200
-100
0
100
200
300
400
500
600
BE BG CY CZ DK DE EL ES EE FR HU IE IT LT LU LV MT NL AT PL PT RO FI SE SK SI UK
Fieldcrops
-200
-100
0
100
200
300
400
500
600
BE BG CY CZ DK DE EL ES EE FR HU IE IT LT LU LV MT NL AT PL PT RO FI SE SK SI UK
Horticulture
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
93
-200
-100
0
100
200
300
400
500
600
BE BG CY CZ DK DE EL ES EE FR HU IE IT LT LU LV MT NL AT PL PT RO FI SE SK SI UK
Wine
-200
-100
0
100
200
300
400
500
600
BE BG CY CZ DK DE EL ES EE FR HU IE IT LT LU LV MT NL AT PL PT RO FI SE SK SI UK
Other permanent crops
-200
-100
0
100
200
300
400
500
600
BE BG CY CZ DK DE EL ES EE FR HU IE IT LT LU LV MT NL AT PL PT RO FI SE SK SI UK
Milk
-200
-100
0
100
200
300
400
500
600
BE BG CY CZ DK DE EL ES EE FR HU IE IT LT LU LV MT NL AT PL PT RO FI SE SK SI UK
Other grazing livestock
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
94
Source: DG AGRI EU-FADN.
5.4. Comparisons between Member States of farms by economic
size group
Figure 44 presents a comparison between FFI/FWU in all Member States for the six farm
size groups as defined by Economic Size. This is presented in index form (EU-27 = 100)
to facilitate comparisons between size groups. Zero values indicate no data as a result of
the minimum size thresholds in use. A key difference from the investigation by farm type is
that there is much less difference between Member States suggesting that a key
factor in differences between Member States by farm type actually reflect the different
size structure which itself is influenced by the size thresholds used in FADN. In other
words, a comparison between Member States of a specific farm type is confounded by the
difference in size structure.
That said, FFI/FWU in Bulgaria and Romania is below the EU-27 average for the smallest
two size groups, although farm incomes in Slovenia were lowest in both cases. From the
25,000-50,000 EUR size group upwards, farm incomes in Romania start to be higher than
the EU-27 average and for farms in the two groups in excess of 100,000 EUR this is also
true for Bulgaria. In fact, as economic size increases, it becomes more common for farms
from the EU-N10 to show higher FFI/FWU than farms in the EU-15. For the largest size
group, only farms in Italy and the UK from the EU-15 have farm income higher than the
EU-27 average (farm incomes in Portugal equal the EU-27 average in this size class).
-200
-100
0
100
200
300
400
500
600
BE BG CY CZ DK DE EL ES EE FR HU IE IT LT LU LV MT NL AT PL PT RO FI SE SK SI UK
Granivores
-200
-100
0
100
200
300
400
500
600
BE BG CY CZ DK DE EL ES EE FR HU IE IT LT LU LV MT NL AT PL PT RO FI SE SK SI UK
Mixed
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
95
Figure 44: FFI/FWU by Economic Size and Member State, 2010-2012 average, EU-
27 = 100
0
100
200
300
400
500
600
BE BG CY CZ DK DE EL ES EE FR HU IE IT LT LU LV MT NL AT PL PT RO FI SE SK SI UK
(1) 2 000 - 8 000 EUR
0
100
200
300
400
500
600
BE BG CY CZ DK DE EL ES EE FR HU IE IT LT LU LV MT NL AT PL PT RO FI SE SK SI UK
(2) 8 000 - < 25 000 EUR
0
100
200
300
400
500
600
BE BG CY CZ DK DE EL ES EE FR HU IE IT LT LU LV MT NL AT PL PT RO FI SE SK SI UK
(3) 25 000 - < 50 000 EUR
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
96
Source: DG AGRI EU-FADN.
5.5. Agricultural wages in Member States
For reasons that have been given above, agricultural wages are not treated alongside the
entrepreneurial incomes of farmers in this analysis. However, in view of the opinion among
some that they constitute part of the agricultural community for agricultural policy
purposes, they are included here. That said, it should be recalled that the determinants of
wage levels for hired workers are radically different from those that determine the residual
incomes of independent farmers. In particular, the level of wages paid in the rest of the
local economy will be a major determining factor.
0
100
200
300
400
500
600
BE BG CY CZ DK DE EL ES EE FR HU IE IT LT LU LV MT NL AT PL PT RO FI SE SK SI UK
(4) 50 000 - < 100 000 EUR
0
100
200
300
400
500
600
BE BG CY CZ DK DE EL ES EE FR HU IE IT LT LU LV MT NL AT PL PT RO FI SE SK SI UK
(5) 100 000 - < 500 000 EUR
0
100
200
300
400
500
600
BE BG CY CZ DK DE EL ES EE FR HU IE IT LT LU LV MT NL AT PL PT RO FI SE SK SI UK
(6) >= 500 000 EUR
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
97
Comparisons between countries (and regions) have been made in terms of the average
calculated wage rate within FADN (the average amount spent on hired labour in the
national FADN sample divided by the average number of hours of labour supplied); this
may differ from other metrics (such as average wages or that found by national surveys of
hired employees working in agriculture).
The average of annual figures for the years 2010-2012 are shown in Figure 45. The degree
of difference between the highest wage countries and the lowest wage ones is very large
the ratio between wages per hour in Denmark and in Bulgaria is in the order of 10:1. Three
countries (Denmark, the Netherlands and Sweden) have wage levels averaging more than
€15 per hour, whereas in six (Bulgaria, Greece, Latvia, Lithuania, Poland and Romania) it is
€3 or less.
Figure 45: Paid wages per hour (2010-12 average)
Source: DG AGRI EU-FADN.
5.5.1. Regional differences in wages paid
The regional variation of wages paid within countries is noticeably less than was observed
with the income of farmers (Map 3). For example, in France only one region (Champagne)
appears to have wages that are outside the range
€10
-15 per hour, whereas FFI/FEU was
spread over four different levels. Wages in Germany are similarly more homogeneous,
although are higher in the East where farm managers and administrators on large farms
are included which increases the average. This is in line with the hypothesis that the wages
paid are generally determined more by wages levels in the general national economy than
by the profitability of farming in particular regions (the Champagne region of France may
well be an exception).
€0
€5
€10
€15
€20
€25
BE BG CY CZ DK DE EL ES EE FR HU IE IT LT LU LV MT NL AT PL PT RO FI SE SK SI UK
Average wages paid EU-27
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
98
Map 3: Average nominal wages paid by FADN region, 2010-12 average
Source: DG AGRI EU-FADN.
An analysis of the variation of wages paid per hour was carried out along similar lines to
that applied to the income of farmers (Figure 46). This is difficult to interpret because the
level of wages has been rising relatively quickly in the EU-N12 Member States which is
included within the variation (whereas in the EU-15 they have been far steadier suggesting
less volatility). The countries with the seven highest coefficients of variation are all new
Member States. That said, Spain, Luxembourg, Austria and Finland are countries among
the EU-15 that have displayed relatively high coefficients of variation in the wages levels.
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
99
Figure 46: Coefficient of variation in paid wages by Member State, 2004-2012
Source: DG AGRI EU-FADN.
0
0,05
0,1
0,15
0,2
0,25
0,3
0,35
BE BG CY CZ DK DE EL ES EE FR HU IE IT LT LU LV MT NL AT PL PT RO FI SE SK SI UK
Var hourly wage EU-27
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
100
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
101
6. RECOMMENDATIONS FOR FUTURE INCOME
SUPPORT UNDER THE CAP
KEY FINDINGS
Based on our analysis the recommendations to the European Parliament are that:
Further consideration is given to the re-establishment of IAHS statistics, since
they are needed to assess the extent to which the CAP is achieving this core
objective of a fair standard of living.
Data sources that relate to the entire economic activities of the households
(and other institutional units) that operate farms should be encouraged.
A study be undertaken to assess the relative attributes of a safety net for the
incomes of farm households for the EU, including its costs, and the necessary
technical conditions that would be required for it to operate successfully.
When considering the need for support of incomes, the wealth of agricultural
holdings should be taken into account.
Suitable caveats should be used when FADN data are reported to make clear the
impact of the field of observation on the results.
Consideration should be given to the need to represent people (farm holdings)
rather than production. A suitable balance needs to be struck between the current
production/land use focus of FADN and the social impact of the CAP.
Attention should be diverted away from interventions that attempt to combat
instability directly at the farm level and towards risk management schemes that
prepare farm operators to better anticipate and cope with instability. This
could involve further studies.
Consideration should be given as to how the occupiers of small farms can enhance
their economic prospects by building their skills and other forms of human capital.
We recommend that policies that increase market participation and ease the
adjustment of farm businesses and households should be further supported and that
current impediments to access be examined.
In the terms of reference for this study on Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU
Member Statesthe European Parliament pointed out that the central aim of the CAP is to
support the incomes of farmers. It drew attention to Article 39(1)(b) of the TFEU which,
carried over the words of the earlier Treaties concerning the aims of the CAP specifically the
objective of ensuring a fair standard of living for the agricultural community, in particular
the individual earnings of persons engaged in agriculture’. As noted in previous chapters,
neither the fair standard of living nor the agricultural community have been officially
defined in the policy context. However, it is clear that, where farm families have income
sources additional to what they receive from farming, these can be important in
determining their overall standard of living.
6.1. The need for reliable statistics on agricultural household
incomes
Our ability to describe and comment on the central components of the farm problem in the
EU poor comparability of incomes between farmers and other groups in society, poverty
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
102
among farm households, and income instability (or volatility) is severely hampered by poor
data availability. As has been established earlier in this analysis, in many Member States
data do not currently exist by which the disposable income of agricultural households
(proxies for their standards of living) might be assessed.
Although Eurostat has in the past attempted to set up statistics on this subject (Income of
the Agricultural Households Sector IAHS statistics), currently no operational official EU
monitoring system exists by which the total household incomes of farmers can be assessed
and compared with other groups in society or their evolution monitored. This represents a
major gap in information relevant to the performance of the CAP. While a feasibility study
has been made to rebase the Eurostat statistics on a uniform basis in Member States,
following comments by the European Court of Auditors (2004) and endorsed by the
Council, and potential data sources by which this could be done have been identified, no
action has been taken since it reported in 2007. A recommendation to the European
Parliament is that further consideration is given to the re-establishment of IAHS
statistics, since they are needed to assess the extent to which the CAP is
achieving this core objective of a fair standard of living.
The EU system of monitoring incomes at the farm level (FADN) does not currently collect
data on incomes received by farm operators from non-farm sources, though in some
Member States the national survey that contributes to FADN does cover this other income.
At national level there is often little or no information on the numbers of farm households
that are considered to be in poverty
33
. Also, variability of household income is likely to be
less extreme than that seen in the profits from farming because of the more stable other
sources of income that many farm families receive. This lack of farm household data is for
a range of reasons but primarily because farmers in many countries are not taxed
according to their accounted income but on other bases; in many instances these special
treatments provide benefits (‘tax expenditures’ or concessions) that are not usually counted
when measuring the public support of agriculture, but can form part of the explanation why
some operators remain in agriculture (Defra, 2012; OECD, 2005). In such countries
taxation records are not a source of relevant information on incomes. A second
recommendation, closely allied to the first, is that data sources are encouraged
that relate to the entire economic activities of the households (and other
institutional units) that operate farms. In addition to assisting with income
measurement, such data are highly likely to be relevant to understanding issues such as
the viability, sustainability and resilience of farm firms
34
, their intensity of land use,
investment levels and succession patterns. In other words, the sort of issues which are
addressed through the second pillar of the CAP (although take up of specific measures,
such as risk management tools, is a decision for Member States
35
).
Although the picture is currently imperfect and incomplete, from the fragmented statistics it
appears that, as a group, farmer households in most Member States are not a particularly
33
A rare exception is Ireland where there are special payments for landholders whose incomes fall below
specified thresholds (the so-called ‘farmers dole’). Some 20-25% of holders seemed to qualify in the 1980s. A
sharp rise was noted between 2008 and 2010 in numbers who actually received the means-tested benefit (the
Farm Assist Scheme), a period over which incomes from farming dropped sharply; in the latter year about ten
thousand farmers had their income poverty means tested and were paid, about 10% of the total number of
self-employed farmers. It was evident that this benefit was regarded as a last resort by farm households and,
according to the farming press, many more who might have qualified did not apply (quoted in Hill (2012) Farm
Incomes, Wealth and Agricultural Policy, CABI p. 49.)
34
For example, see Defra (2012).
35
Under Commission Delegated Regulation (EU) No 807/2014 and Implementing Regulation (EU) 808/2014, the
detail of the risk management tools to be used is largely left to the Member State which means that they will
not be uniform across the EU.
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
103
low income sector in society. This finding potentially eases the path of CAP reform. If
approximate parity can be assumed, attention could then be focused on other aspects of
the income problems that agriculture faces, such as instability, including the provision of
(stable) policy payments for the provision of environmental services and risk management
tools. Of course, change to the current support system might threaten the relative income
position of the farming community in the short-term, but action to counter this could not be
justified without the sort of evidence that a robust monitoring system, currently lacking but
which has been proposed, could provide. Sector-average figures would not be enough, and
information necessary to enable targeting on low-income cases would be needed. Whether
the problem of low disposable incomes among certain types of farmers is addressed
through the CAP or through general policies on poverty is a matter that would need debate.
When considering policy alternatives it would be wise to look beyond the current poor
statistical situation. Data availability can change. Thus it would be wrong to ignore a radical
socialapproach to supporting the income of poor farmers that identified farm households
that had incomes below some level deemed to be the minimum fair level and provided
payments to bring them up to that level (supplying a household safety net). Though no
assessment of the impact and costs of such a system for the EU or any individual Member
State seems to have been published, analysis for the US (Gundersen et al., 2000) suggests
that such payments directly targeted at low-income farm households could not only
achieve the living standard objective more effectively than the current system but that the
total public cost would be lower than under the present support arrangements (Box 9). In
the US there would be an unmistakeable redistribution so that, while low income
households would receive more than at present, many of the recipients of large payments
would experience falls; this is probably a factor that caused the attention in the US to shift
over the first few years following the publication of this ERS analysis from the notion of a
safety net applying to farm households to one applying to the revenues or profits from the
farm business.
Box 9: Safety net for farm households (based on Gundersen et al., 2000)
Government assistance to the US farm sector provides relatively little to small farms.
Instead, most government assistance through traditional farm program instruments is
to larger farms. This report looked at the issue from a different perspective, one which
might have reduced government spending and ensure that all full-time farmers received
an income to meet basic needs. It applied the concept of a farm household safety net
based on a set of standards commonly used in the economics literature and in Federal
assistance programs for low- to moderate-income households.
The report considered four safety net scenarios that would assure farm households a
certain level of income or consumption:
Income equal to that of the median non-farm household in the region.
Income equal to 185% of the poverty line.
Income equal to the average nonfarm household's annual expenditures.
Income equal to the median hourly earnings of the non-farm self-employed ($10 per
hour).
The analysis estimated the distribution effects and costs of the four scenarios for two
time periods: 1993-97 and 1999-2003. Under any of the four safety net scenarios all
very small farm households would receive payments and payments per recipient to
other small farms would be more than twice as high as under existing programs.
Larger farms would lose in the new system. In terms of the total cost the new system
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
104
would result in lower public expenditure as long as the safety net threshold was less
than about $30,000. Of course, this mechanism could be combined with the
continuation of some programs (such as environmental ones), in which situation the
overall cost would reflect that mix.
Given that evidence for the EU points to a similar distribution of benefit under the CAP, with
the bulk of payments going to the larger farms and small farms getting relatively little, the
general findings are likely to apply too (although it should be noted that there is a greater
element of redistribution under the 2014-2020 CAP, see European Parliament (2015b)).
However, the absence of adequate data on household income of farmers in many Member
States currently prevents detailed assessment. Nevertheless, a further recommendation
is that a study be undertaken to assess the relative attributes of a safety net for
the incomes of farm households for the EU, including its costs, and the necessary
technical conditions that would be required for it to operate successfully.
36
It
should be noted that our use of the term safety net”, which relates to the household,
differs from that in Agrosynergie (2013) where the term relates only to the transformation
of market intervention under Council Regulation (EC) 73/2009.
Moving from incomes to wealth, from the perspective of social equity it does not seem
reasonable that the assets held by farm families, and real gains made on them, should be
ignored when considering support for their standards of living. Current income
measurement, whether of household incomes or of the income from farming alone, ignores
wealth and capital gains (or losses), yet such factors are important to strategic decisions,
such as that to stay in or exit from farming. One of the drivers of land prices is the
preferential treatment given in taxation systems in many Member States to wealth in the
form of agricultural assets, particularly to capital gains on agricultural land and on its
transfer between generations (OECD 2005). A recommendation is that, when
considering the need for support of incomes, the wealth of agricultural holdings
should be taken into account. A step in this direction would be a comprehensive
inventory of the way in which Member States treat agricultural assets in capital taxation.
6.2. Statistics based on people rather than production
One of our main sources of data from which we have calculated results is FADN. It is worth
noting that this dataset is oriented towards covering production rather than individual
farmers. A consequence of this is that Member States apply thresholds based on Economic
Size that vary between countries. As an outcome, the smallest sizes of farms only contain
data from a limited number of Member States. Only when an economic farm size of
€25,000 is reached are all Member States present in the data.
This can lead to some misconceptions when discussing the situation among small farms and
also means that average income in those Member States where data from small farms are
included is biased downwards. However, it is still the case that average farm incomes in
Member States with a large proportion of small farms will be lower than in Member States
with fewer small farms, even though these are excluded from FADN.
36
It is worth noting that such a ‘social approach’ to support was outlined, and roughly costed, by the Commission
in its 1985 Green Paper Perspectives for the Common Agricultural Policy (Commission 1985c). Thought to
concern some 1 1.5 million farmers at the time and imply a cost of 1,000 million Ecu per year at the
beginning, it could be limited to the existing generation of farm holders and thus become self-eliminating.
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
105
We therefore recommend that suitable caveats be used when FADN data are
reported to make clear the impact of the field of observation on the results. A
related recommendation is that consideration be given to the need to represent
people (farm holdings) rather than production. A suitable balance needs to be
struck between the current production/land use focus of FADN and the social
impact of the CAP.
6.3. Income stabilisation
The issue of income stabilisation can be considered at the level of the farm household or of
the farm business. The two are, of course, related, since the main cause of household
variation between years is likely to be the profits from farming
37
. Instability (volatility) at
the farm business level may lead to inefficiencies in resource use and (in extreme cases not
seen for some time in the EU) threaten security of supply. Chapter 1 presented evidence on
the extent of income variation at the group and individual farm levels, the latter being the
larger, and the case for averaging over three years as a norm when assessing farm
incomes. It is clear that income instability is greater in some types of farming than in
others, and that the main driver of short-term variation is price volatility in the markets for
farm products. It is also clear that, in retrospect, concerns over income levels in single
years and shifts between years can give an exaggerated impression of longer-term
movements; for example, 2009 proved to be a passing experience of depressed income
levels rather than a precursor of persistent low incomes. It is also apparent than the
incomes from farming are relatively less stable among small farms than among large ones.
Knowing about income instability is one thing. Taking action to combat it, with the intent of
producing a net benefit to society, is quite another. Some EU countries (UK, Ireland and
the Netherlands) already achieve a degree of smoothing of year-on-year income
fluctuations by means of averaging in the tax system. France enables farmers who are
taxed on their accounted income to deduct as an expense payments deposited in a
‘professional savings account’ that can be drawn down in circumstances such as a sharp
decrease in income. Sweden has a similar arrangement.
At the EU level, since Agenda 2000, an explicit aim of the CAP has been to contribute to the
stability of farm incomes. Reforms, notably the introduction of the Single Payment Scheme
and now the Basic Payment Scheme, have changed the economic environment of farming
with support now more targeted
38
. Opinion is not uniform on the impact of direct income
support on farm income stability. However, it is clear that farmers are now expected to
take prime responsibility for coping with market-related risk and uncertainty. This has led
to a much increased level of policy interest in risk management initiatives by the European
Commission, which published or sponsored several important studies on the management
of risk and uncertainty between 2001 and 2009 (European Commission, 2001, 2005a,
2005b; JRC 2006, 2009; LEI, 2007)
39
. It concluded that successive reforms to the CAP,
while encouraging European farmers to be more market oriented, left agriculture open to
crises caused by natural disasters, livestock diseases or plant pests, or economic crises
such as caused by the unexpected closure of important export markets. These may
endanger a farm's viability or even affect the economic stability of an entire rural area.
37
Incomes from OGAs and on-farm diversification may also be variable, but data are not yet available through
FADN, although information on diversification will be collected in the future. If income from these activities is
unrelated to agricultural income then it will stabilise household income, although if it varies in the same way as
agricultural income it could make household income more volatile.
38
For a review of the latest CAP reform, see European Parliament (2015b).
39
Other, more recent, work on this subject includes European Parliament (2015a) and Meuwissen, et al. (2008).
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
106
Among the options considered by the European Commission (2001) as potential fields of
action’ for intervention using public funds were:
Providing the conditions in which private markets in risk reduction instruments can
work (such as the legislative framework, or training on risk management tools for
farmers)
40
.
Lowering the costs of risk-management tools, such as by providing subsidies for
insurance or re-insurance (see more recently European Parliament, 2015a).
Subsidies could also be justified on a temporary basis to encourage the development
of market solutions. This might include assistance to setting up mutual support
schemes, or tax concessions for establishing reserve funds.
Providing public risk coverage, e.g. by providing disaster aid payments, public
insurance and re-insurance, or a specific safety net in which payments are made
direct to farmers, the last being a new form of instrument within the CAP.
The OECD has also issued a number of studies on risk in agriculture (OECD 2000, 2008a,
2008b, 2009). Points made that are significant in the present context are (a) the
widespread lack of information on whole-farm income instability; and, (b) the ability to tier
risks into layers, though their margins are rather blurred. The layers comprise, first, normal
commercial risk that farm operators could be expected to shoulder and cope with by
traditional means such as diversifying their business (a move that runs counter to the trend
towards greater specialisation seen among EU farms) or entering into contracts with buyers
or more sophisticated financial instruments such as hedging. Second, there are risks for
which market insurance is available (such as fire). Third, there is market failure risk,
where, for reasons including lack of information, private insurance solutions do not present
themselves. Examples of the last include catastrophic drops in income caused by prolonged
droughts, outbreaks of animal disease that disrupt normal patterns of trade, and historical
incidents and events. Typically these depress incomes in a widespread way, perhaps of all
the farms in a particular region.
The distinction between periods of low incomes flowing from natural disasters and those
resulting from other causes is important, as different sets of rules apply under international
trade agreements as to what can trigger government intervention and the degree of
support that can be offered. Safety-nets, applied to the farm business (as opposed to the
household, discussed earlier), whereby direct payments (counter-cyclical payments’) are
made to individual farms suffering low incomes, are superficially attractive in that they give
support only when needed and not when incomes are satisfactory, thereby improving the
efficiency of public spending. Rules under the Agreement on Agriculture that forms part of
Uruguay GATT Agreement of 1993 (formally signed in 1994 and carried forward into the
World Trade Organisation rules) have the effect of constraining the amount of safety net
support. These say a farm can only be eligible for safety-net payments if its income (the
definition of which is not specified) from agriculture becomes less than 70% of its average
income of the preceding three years (or an average of three out of the previous five,
leaving out the highest and lowest, the so-called ‘Olympic average’). Moreover, the
payments must not be greater than 70% of the shortfall between the income of the
particular year and the three-year average.
40
See European Parliament (2014a) on the limits of EU regulation on agricultural derivatives and the issue of
competence for this topic within Commission Services.
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
107
A few non-EU countries have used safety-net scheme following these trade rules (the main
examples being USA and Canada)
41
. Though the EU has not operated schemes along the
lines used in the US or Canada, simulation exercises have been conducted by the European
Commission using FADN data. In 2001 the Commission published estimates of the cost of
topping up income (Family Farm Income) of the individual farm to 70% of the average
income in its previous three years. In 1997, 20% of FADN farms (EU-12) would have
qualified for safety net payments and cost a total of
€3
.5 billion. In the UK in 1996 some
12.5% of farms would have received payments, but this rose to 24.5% in 1997.
A similar exercise using FADN (EU-15) was carried out as part of the Impact Assessment of
the 2008 CAP Health Check. The period covered was 1989 to 2003. Eligibility for
stabilisation payments was again restricted to farms that had suffered an income fall of
greater than 30% compared with its historical average, but Farm Net Value Added (FNVA)
was this time the preferred income indicator. The largest shares of expenditure for the
period as a whole, if such a programme were introduced, were found to be Italy (20%),
Spain (18%), France (15%) and Germany (14%). Total cost varied from
€8
billion to
€12
billion per year, averaging
€9.3
billion (which might be compared with Pillar I spending in
2007 of
€43
billion).
The Commission has revisited this issue in the context of the 2013 CAP reform. European
Commission (2011a) examined extending the current framework for insurances and mutual
funds; an Income Stabilisation Tool (IST); and, a crisis fund. The annual cost of the IST
was estimated at
€7 billion on the assumption that about 20% of farmers were
compensated for a 30% income loss. This compares to an appropriation of between
€36
billion and
€40 billion on direct payments in the 2014 to 2020 programming period
(European Parliament, 2015c). The Commission concluded that insurances and mutual
funds could contribute to both increasing the stability of income and mitigating the effects
of production risks, although care would be needed to avoid distorting production decisions.
The Commission also concluded that a "one size fits all" solution would not be appropriate
given the heterogeneity of risks faced.
42
Though the budgetary cost of making countercyclical direct payments to farms
specifically to help them cope with income instability, up to the limits permissible, is low
compared with that of Single Payments/Basic Payments
43
which gives support irrespective
of income need, such safety nets have some substantial drawbacks as far as the
Commission is concerned. These include the wide variability from year to year in the
number of farms qualifying for payments and in the aggregate cost
44
, an unwelcome
feature when generally the move has been towards making the costs of the CAP more
rather than less predictable; some additional tool to limit the expenditure might be needed.
Differences between the relative amounts of benefit going to particular Member States
compared with what they receive under the present arrangements could be a political
stumbling block. From the perspective of the farmer, support may be available only when
the most pressing need for support has passed and possibly too late, though a system of
interim payments may circumvent this disadvantage.
41
In the US ‘Agricultural Gross Revenue’ and ‘Agricultural Gross Revenue-Lite’ were introduced in a pilot capacity
in 2001 and 2003 respectively. In Canada the Income Stabilisation (CAIS) programme, introduced in 2003.
The later scheme AgriStability – retained the essential characteristics of its predecessor. These are reviewed
in Hill (2012).
42
Mary, et al. (2013) investigated the impact of an Income Stabilisation Tool and concluded that the impact
would vary from farm to farm.
43
See European Parliament (2013a) for details at the Member State level.
44
Variability in annual cost would also be an issue given that annual (rather than multi-annual) payments form a
principle of the EU Budget.
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
108
Most recently, Article 39 of Regulation (EU) No 1305/2013 on support for rural
development provides Member States with the option of supporting an income stabilisation
tool in the form of financial contributions to mutual funds and providing compensation to
farmers for a severe drop in their income. Under this measure, up to 70% of lost income
can be reimbursed by a mutual fund if income drops by at least 30% below a three-year
average figure
45
. For every
€1 paid in by the farmer, an additional €0.65 is to be added
from the CAP’s second pillar. Direct payments and all other public support are considered
as ‘income’ under the rules. At the time of writing it is not clear how farmers will
demonstrate their income levels, especially where they are not required to keep an
account. European Commission (2015) reports that, as of 21 May, 2015, 13 Member States
had taken up the risk management option in 15 RDPs. Some
€2.7 billion of
public funds will
be spent and 675,000 holdings will participate. Almost all the funds (€2.2 billion) will be
allocated to insurance premiums, €417 million to mutual funds and €130 million to income
stabilisation.
A key factor that apparently rules out the use of a comprehensive income safety net within
the CAP is the lack of a data system to enable it to operate
46
. Information of high quality
from each individual farm in the EU would be needed. Both the US and Canada base their
safety nets on data supplied by farmers from their accounting systems to their national
taxation authorities. There are severe penalties for false accounting. The data therefore
has a good degree of quality assurance, within the conventions used for the purposes of
taxation. As has been pointed out, in many EU Member States some or all farmers do not
have to submit income accounts for taxation, being assessed on a flat-rate (area-linked)
basis. Though income data will be available for holdings that happen to be in the FADN
sample, these form only a small minority. The lack of reliable income data for a large
number of EU farms rules out the possibility of introducing a safety net along the lines
allowed under international trade rules. To set up a special system to enable a CAP safety
net to work would take time and involve a large administrative burden, both on national
governments and on individual farms, factors which make it highly unattractive. Also
because personal taxation is something over which Member States retain sole competence,
there is no practical possibility of all EU countries adopting tax systems that compel their
farmers to keep tax accounts that might supply the income data necessary to implement an
income safety net.
We therefore recommend that attention is diverted away from interventions that
attempt to combat instability directly at the farm level and towards schemes that
prepare management on farms to better anticipate and cope with instability.
6.4. Support for small farms
One feature of the CAP reforms agreed in late 2013 and to be applied from 2014 or 2015
was the special support system for small farms (the Small Farmers Scheme - SFS).
Optional for Member States, any farmer claiming support may decide to participate in the
Small Farmers Scheme and thereby receive an annual payment fixed by the Member State
of normally between
€500 and €1,250, regardless of the farm size. Member States may
choose from different methods to calculate the annual payment, including an option
whereby farmers would simply receive the amount they would otherwise receive. The
Commission claimed that this will be an enormous simplification for the farmers concerned
45
Either the farmer’s average income in the past three years or a three year average from the preceding five
years excluding the highest and lowest values.
46
See also European Parliament (2015a) for other complicating factors.
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
109
and for national administrations. Participants will not be subject to cross-compliance
controls and sanctions, and will be exempt from greening. The related impact assessment
(quoted in European Commission, 2011b), showed that approximately one third of farms
applying for CAP funding have an area of 3 hectares or less, but this accounts for just 3%
of the overall agricultural area in the EU-27.
Evidence presented in this report suggests a clear link exists between the economic
size of farm business and the income per Work Unit received. Also, farms of
economic size greater than
€25,000 of Standard Output in Member States that joined the
EU in 2004 and 2007 seem to perform at levels similar to those seen in EU-15, and in the
largest size groups farms in N-2 appear to outperform those in other countries. If there is a
problem of a low income level from farming activity, the strategic solution is to facilitate the
growth of farm sizes, and specifically the exit of operators who currently depend on the
farm for their incomes, but whose scale of operations are too small
47
. This will enable
remaining farms to absorb the released land, though history suggests that this may not go
primarily to enable small farms to expand, but may be absorbed by larger units that are in
a strong position to bid for it by purchase or rent.
The appropriate policy response is to put in place forms of support that assist
households with small farms to develop other sources of income, either on the farm
or elsewhere in the economy (this is distinct from the Small Farmers’ Scheme under the
2014-2020 CAP). Rural Development Programmes, funded in part by the CAP’s Pillar 2,
often already have schemes to provide vocational training, but the strategic need is for a
broader range of enabling skills. While diversification frequently requires business training,
factors such as the general level of education may also be important, together with the
ability to work in sectors that are often little connected with agriculture, but which can be
carried on in combination with farming. In Member States where there are fewer non-
agricultural employment opportunities, these require creation, something that Rural
Development Programmes can assist with. History and empirical evidence suggests that
there is almost no professional or commercial activity that cannot be found in combination
with farming, lending important attributes to the farm operator’s existence that often goes
beyond additional incomes, such as financial stability, resilience in times of adversity, more
social contacts and other benefits.
A recommendation for policy is that consideration is given as to how the
households that occupy small farms can enhance their economic prospects by
building their skills and other forms of human capital.
6.5. Balance between support and market orientation
Our analysis has established that subsidies (which include the increasingly important
payments to farmers for the provision of public goods such as environmental services) are
not the main source of revenue of EU farms, and sectors that generate the highest incomes
(FFI/FWU) for their operators tend to be those where subsidies have the least relative
significance. This greater market orientation, and the flexibility to respond by
adjusting size and other characteristics, seems to be an important characteristic of
successful farms.
47
There is a small incentive under the second pillar of the CAP for farmers who are eligible for SFS to transfer
their holding permanently to another farmer. The value of this incentive is 120% of the eligible payment.
However, this is only a weak incentive and may lead to the creation of notional transfers that will not impact
on operational structure.
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
110
Discussions on support have been conducted primarily with direct payments under the
CAP’s Pillar 1 in mind (these have accounted for the main expenditure). However, this is
often a too narrow approach. Provision of assistance to structural adjustment has
already been mentioned above, but there are several other measures within Pillar 2 that
are important in supporting indirectly the incomes of farm occupiers and in facilitating their
development, thereby assisting in achieving the CAP’s central objective of a fair standard of
living for the agricultural community.
Rural Development Programmes frequently aim to increase farm productivity and
competitiveness by measures that facilitate knowledge transfer, develop management
capacity, encourage better marketing and the establishment and maintenance of
cooperation. The assistance they offer to the development of on-farm diversification and to
off-farm occupations, mentioned above in the context of small farms, is, of course, more
generally relevant and applicable across the size spectrum. We recommend that policies
that increase market participation and ease the adjustment of farm businesses
and households should be further supported and that current impediments to
access be examined.
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
111
REFERENCES
Agra CEAS Consulting (2007) Feasibility Study on the Implementation of Income of
Agricultural Households Sector (IAHS) Statistics. Final Report for European Commission
(Eurostat).
Agra CEAS Consulting (forthcoming) Costs and Good Practice in FADN Data Collection.
Final report for DG AGRI, European Commission. AGRI-2014-EVAL-01.
Agrosynergie (2013) Evaluation of the Structural Effects of Direct Support. Final Report
to European Commission. July, 2013.
Barthomeuf, L.-T. (2008) Other Gainful Activities, Pluriactivity and Farm Diversification
in EU-27. LTB D(2008), 17488, European Commission, Directorate General for
Agriculture and Rural Development, G.2. Economic analysis of EU agriculture, Brussels.
Canberra Group (2001) Expert Group on Household Income Statistics The Canberra
Group: Final Report and Recommendations. Ottawa.
Commission of the European Communities - see also European Commission below.
Commission of the European Communities (1982) Indicators of Farm Income. Working
document of the Services of the Commission, VI/308/82 EN (0082d). The Commission,
Brussels.
Commission of the European Communities (1985a) Agricultural incomes in the
Community. Green Europe Newsflash 29. The Commission, Brussels.
Commission of the European Communities (1985b) Income Disparities in Agriculture in
the Community. Green Europe 208. The Commission, Brussels.
Commission of the European Communities (1985c) Perspectives for the Common
Agricultural Policy The Green Paper of the Commission. European Community
Newsflash: Green Europe. 33. The Commission, Brussels. Also COM(85) 333 final.
Commission of the European Communities (1989) The European Farm Accountancy
Data Network: an A,–Z of Methodology. Directorate General for Agriculture, Unit A-3,
Analysis of the situation of Farm Holdings, The Commission, Brussels.
Commission of the European Communities (2001) Risk management tools for EU
agriculture, with a special focus on insurance. Working Document, Agriculture
Directorate-General. The Commission, Brussels.
Commission of the European Communities (2005a) Communication from the
Commission to the Council on risk and crisis management in agriculture. COM, 74. The
Commission, Brussel
Commission of the European Communities (2005b) Commission Staff Working
Document on risk and crisis management in agriculture. SEC (2005) 320 [COM(2005)
74]. The Commission, Brussels.
Cordts, W., Deerberg, K. H. and Hanf, C. H. (1984) Analysis of the intrasectoral income
differences in West German agriculture. European Review of Agricultural Economics, 11,
pp323–342.
de Frahan, B. H., Nkunzimana, T., De Blander, R., Gaspart, F. and Sumner, D. A.
(2008) Farm Household Incomes and Reforming the CAP. Paper prepared for the 109th
EAAD Seminar; The CAP after the Fischler Reform: National Implementations, Impact
Assessment and the Agenda for Future Reforms', Viterbo, Italy.
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
112
Defra (2012) Farm Household Income and Household Composition: Results from the
Farm Business Survey: England 2010/11. Published 30 August, 2012.
ECA (2004) Measurement of Farm Incomes by the Commission. Special Report No
14/2003, Court of Auditors of the European Communities, Luxembourg [also appeared
as Court of Auditors (2003)].
European Commission (1997) AGENDA 2000: for a stronger and wider Union.
Document drawn up on the basis of COM(97) 2000 final. Bulletin of the European Union
supplement 5/97. ISBN 92-828-1034-8.
European Commission (2008) COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT
accompanying the Proposals for COUNCIL REGULATION establishing common rules for
direct support schemes under the common agricultural policy for farmers and
establishing certain support schemes for farmers COUNCIL REGULATION on
modifications to the common agricultural policy by amending Regulations (EC) No
320/2006, (EC) No 1234/2007, (EC) No 3/2008 and (EC) No […]/2008 COUNCIL
REGULATION amending Regulation (EC) No 1698/2005 on support for rural
development by the European Agricultural Fund for Rural Development (EAFRD)
COUNCIL DECISION amending Decision 2006/144/EC on the Community strategic
guidelines for rural development (programming period 2007 to 2013) Impact
Assessment. {COM(2008) 306 final} {SEC(2008) 1886}. Brussels, 20.5.2008.
SEC(2008) 1885.
European Commission (2009) Why Do We Need A Common Agricultural Policy?
Discussion Paper by DG Agriculture And Rural Development December 2009.
European Commission (2010a) Consultation Document for Impact Assessment of the
Reform of the CAP towards 2020.
European Commission (2010b) The CAP towards 2020: Meeting the food, natural
resources and territorial challenges of the future. Communication from the Commission
to the European Parliament, the Council, the European Economic and Social Committee
and the Committee of the Regions. Brussels, 18 November 2010, COM(2010) 672 final.
European Commission (2010c) Developments in the income situation of the EU
agricultural sector. Brussels, December 2010.
European Commission (2011a) Commission Staff Working Paper, Impact Assessment on
Risk Management, Common Agricultural Policy towards 2020, Annex 6. SEC (2011)
1153, October 2011.
European Commission (2011b) CAP Reform an explanation of the main elements.
MEMO/11/685. Brussels, 12 October 2011.
European Commission (2013) Structure and dynamics of EU farms: changes, trends and
policy relevance. EU Agricultural Economics Briefs. No 9, October, 2013.
European Commission (2014a) CAP context indicators 2014-2020, December 2014
(http://ec.europa.eu/agriculture/cap-indicators/context/2014/full-text_en.pdf)
European Commission (2014b) EU farm economics overview based on FADN data 2011.
September 2014. DG Agriculture and Rural Development.
European Commission (2014c) Definition of variables in FADN standard results. RI/CC
882 Rev. 9.2. Community Committee for the Farm Accountancy Data Network.
December 2014.
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
113
European Commission (2015) The CAP towards 2020: Implementation of Rural
Development Policy. State of Play of RDPs. Based on information available on
21.05.2015.
European Parliament (2013a) European Council Conclusions on the Multiannual
Financial Framework 2014–2020 and the CAP. Note for Directorate-General for Internal
Policies Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies Agriculture and Rural
Development. Authors: Little, J., Massot, A., Ragonnaud, G. and Tropea, F.
European Parliament (2013b) Possible effects on EU land markets of new CAP direct
payments. Study for Directorate-General for Internal Policies Policy Department B:
Structural and Cohesion Policies Agriculture and Rural Development. Authors:
Swinnen, J., Ciaian, K., Kancs, d’A., Herck, K. van and Vranken, L.
European Parliament (2014) Financial Instruments and Legal Frameworks of Derivatives
Markets in EU Agriculture: Current State of Play and Future Perspectives. Study for
Directorate-General for Internal Policies Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion
Policies Agriculture and Rural Development. Author: Vander Stichele, M.
European Parliament (2015a) Comparative Analysis of Risk Management Tools
Supported by the 2014 Farm Bill and the CAP 2014-2020. Study for Directorate-General
for Internal Policies Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies Agriculture
and Rural Development. Author: Cordier, J.
European Parliament (2015b) First Pillar of the CAP: II Direct Payments to Farmers.
Fact Sheets on the European Union – 2015.
European Parliament (2015c) The Common Agricultural Policy in Figures. Fact Sheets on
the European Union – 2015.
Eurostat (1995) Manual of the Total Income of Agricultural Households (Rev.1), Theme
5 Series E. Eurostat, Luxembourg.
Eurostat (1997) Manual on the Economic Accounts for Agriculture and Forestry (Rev.1).
Eurostat, Luxembourg.
Eurostat (2000) Manual on the economic accounts for Agriculture and Forestry
(Rev.1.1). Theme 5. Eurostat, Luxembourg.
Eurostat (2002) Income of the Agricultural Households Sector 2001 Report. Theme 5,
Eurostat, Luxembourg.
Eurostat (2010) Draft Version of European System of Accounts: ESA 2010. Eurostat,
Luxembourg.
FAO (2011) Statistics on rural development and agricultural household income. Wye
Group Handbook: Second edition. Ed. Berkeley Hill and Graham Eele. 2011.
http://www.fao.org/wairdocs/am087e/am087e.pdf
Gardner, B. L. (1992) Changing economic perspectives on the farm problem. Journal of
Economic Literature. 30, pp62-101.
Gundersen, C., Morehart, M., Whitener, L., Ghelfi, L., Johnson, J., Kassel, K., Kuhn, B.,
Mishra, A., Offutt, S. and Tiehen, L. (2000) A Safety Net for Farm Households. AER-
788, Economic Research Service, USDA, Washington.
Hazell, P. and Wood, S. (2008) Drivers of change in global agriculture. Philosophical
Transactions of the Royal Society B (2008), 363, 495-515.
Hegrenes, A., Hill, B. and Lien, G. (2001) Income stability among agricultural
households - evidence from Norway. Journal of Farm Management, 11(1), pp1-12.
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
114
Hill, B. (1990) In search of the Common Agricultural Policy's "agricultural community".
Journal of Agricultural Economics, 41(3), pp316–26.
Hill, B. (1991) Calculation of Economic Indicators: Making Use of RICA (FADN)
Accountancy Data. Document series, Commission of the EC, Brussels.
Hill, B. (2000) Linking the established subsystems of economic statistics to provide a
rounded view of agriculture. In Pauli, P, (ed.), Agricultural Economic Statistics,
Proceedings of the Seventh IWG-AGRI Seminar, Luxembourg 5–7 July, 2000, pp46–74,
Eurostat, Luxembourg.
Hill, B. (2003) A conceptual framework for estimating agricultural household income in
EU countries. Paper to the OECD Seminar on Agriculture and Rural Incomes, Labour
Mobility and Rural Development Policies in Estonia, Latvia and Lithuania 10-12 June
2003, Tallinn, Estonia. p18 (OECD website).
Hill, B. (2012) Farm Incomes, Wealth and Agricultural Policy Filling the CAP’s Core
Information Gap. 4th Edition. CAB International. ISBN 978-1-84593-847-5.
Hill, B. and Brookes, B. (1993) Farm Incomes in the European Community in the 1980s.
Document Series, European Commission, Brussels.
Hill, B. and Platt, S. (2003) Measurement of farm household income and wealth versus
agricultural activity income: Methodological work to be undertaken. Who is doing it?
Joint ECE/Eurostat/FAO/OECD meeting on Agricultural and Food Statistics in Europe.
Geneva 2-4 July, United Nations Economic Commission for Europe.
Hyvönen, K. (2004) A short history of the FADN and other activities than agriculture.
In: Poppe, K. J. (ed.), PACIOLI 12: Income Issues in Farm Households and the Role of
the FADN, Report 8.04.03. Agricultural Economics Research Institute (LEI), The Hague.
JRC (2006) Agricultural insurance schemes. Joint Research Centre (European
Commission), Ispra, Italy.
JRC (2009) Risk Management and Agricultural Insurance Schemes in Europe. Joint
Research Centre (European Commission), Ispra, Italy.
LEI (2007) Data analysis on price, production and income volatility and crisis. LEI
working papers WP2, Income Stabilisation in European Agriculture, Madrid.
Mary, S., Santini, F. and Boulanger, P. (2013) An Ex-Ante Assessment of CAP Income
Stabilisation Payments using a Farm Household Model. Agricultural Economics
Society>87th Annual Conference, April 8-10, 2013, Warwick University, Coventry, UK
Meuwissen, M. P. M, van Asseldonk, M. A. P. M. and Huirne, R. B. M. (eds.) (2008)
Income Stabilisation in European Agriculture; Design and Economic Impact of Risk
Management Tools. Wageningen Academic Press, the Netherlands.
Meuwissen, M. P. M. and Huirne, R. B. M. (1998) Feasibility of Income Insurance in
European Agriculture. Paper to the American Agricultural Economics Association Annual
Meeting, 1998.
Meuwissen, M. P. M., Huirne, R. B. M., and Hardaker, J. B. (1999) Income Insurance in
European Agriculture. European Economy No 2, The Commission, Brussels.
Meuwissen, M. P. M., Huirne, R. B. M. and Skees, J. R. (2003) Income Insurance in
European Agriculture. EuroChoices, Spring 2003, pp12–17.
Meuwissen M., van Asseldonk M. and Huirne R. (2008) Income stabilization in
agriculture; reflections on an EU-project. P. 17-31 in Income Stabilisation in European
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
115
Agriculture Design and economic impact of risk management tools”, Wageningen
Academic Publishers, 222 p.
OECD (2000) Income Risk Management in Agriculture. Organisation for Economic Co-
operation and Development, Paris.
OECD (2002) Farm Household Income Issues in OECD Countries: A Synthesis Report.
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, Paris.
AGR/CA/APM(2002)11/FINAL. [Also published as OECD (2003)].
OECD (2003) Farm Household Income Issues and Policy Responses. Organisation for
Economic Co-operation and Development, Paris.
OECD (2004) Policy Brief: Farm Household Incomes towards better informed policies.
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, Paris.
OECD (2005) Taxation and Social Security in Agriculture. Organisation for Economic
Co-operation and Development, Paris. Main author Hill, B.
OECD (2008a) An Assessment of Risk Exposure in Agriculture: A Literature Review.
Working Party on Agricultural Policies and Markets. TAD/CA/APM/WP(2008)23/FINAL.
[Authors, Coble, K. H. and Barnett, B. J., Department of Agricultural Economics,
Mississippi State University], Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development,
Paris.
OECD (2008b) An Overview of Risk-related Policy Measures. Working Party on
Agricultural Policies and Markets. TAD/CA/APM/WP(2008)23/FINAL. [Author, Moreddu,
C.], Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, Paris.
OECD (2009) Risk Management in Agriculture - A Holistic Conceptual Framework.
Working Party on Agricultural Policies and Markets. [Author, Antón, J.].
TAD/CA/APM/WP(2008)22/FINAL. Organisation for Economic Co-operation and
Development, Paris.
Swinnen, J., Ciaian, P., and Kancs, d’A. (2008) Study on the Functioning of Land
Markets in the EU Member States under the Influence of Measures Applied under the
Common Agricultural Policy. Centre for European Policy Studies (CEPS) final report of a
study carried out on behalf of the European Commission, Directorate General for
Agriculture and Rural Development under contract 30-CE-0165424/00-86.
UN (2008) System of National Accounts 2008. Commission of the European
Communities - Eurostat, International Monetary Fund, Organisation for Economic
Cooperation and Development, United Nations, World Bank, Brussels/Luxembourg, New
York, Paris, Washington.
UNECE (2007) Rural Households’ Livelihood and Well-Being: Statistics on Rural
Development and Agriculture Household Income. The Wye Group Handbook.
Eds Berkeley Hill and Jan Karlson UNECE/FAO/OECD/The World Bank/Eurostat 2007.
van der Veen, H. B., van Rommel, K. H. M. and Venema, G. S. (2002) Family farm
transfer in Europe: A focus on the financial and fiscal facilities in six European countries.
Report 6.02.04. Agricultural Economics Research Institute (LEI), The Hague. May 2002.
LEGAL REFERENCES
Consolidated version of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union. Official
Journal of the European Union. 26/10/2012. C326.
Regulation No 79/65/EEC of the Council of 15 June 1965 setting up a network for the
collection of accountancy data on the incomes and business operation of agricultural
holdings in the European Economic Community. Official Journal of the European Union.
23/06/1965. 1859/65.
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
116
Council Regulation (EC) 73/2009 of 19 January 2009 establishing common rules for
direct support schemes for farmers under the common agricultural policy and
establishing certain support schemes for farmers, amending Regulations (EC) No
1290/2005, (EC) No 247/2006, (EC) No 378/2007 and repealing Regulation (EC) No
1782/2003.
Regulation (EU) No 1305/2013 of the European Parliament and of the Council of 17
December 2013 on support for rural development by the European Agricultural Fund for
Rural Development (EAFRD) and repealing Council Regulation (EC) No 1698/2005.
Official Journal of the European Union. 20/12/2013. L347.
Regulation (EU) No 1308/2013 of the European Parliament and of the Council of 17
December 2013 establishing a common organisation of the markets in agricultural
products and repealing Council Regulations (EEC) No 922/72, (EEC) No 234/79, (EC) No
1037/2001 and (EC) No 1234/2007. Official Journal of the European Union.
20/12/2013. C347.
Commission Delegated Regulation (EU) No 807/2014 of 11 March 2014 supplementing
Regulation (EU) No 1305/2013 of the European Parliament and of the Council on
support for rural development by the European Agricultural Fund for Rural Development
(EAFRD) and introducing transitional provisions. Official Journal of the European Union.
31/07/2014. L227.
Commission Implementing Regulation (EU) No 808/2014 of 17 July 2014 laying down
rules for the application of Regulation (EU) No 1305/2013 of the European Parliament
and of the Council on support for rural development by the European Agricultural Fund
for Rural Development (EAFRD). Official Journal of the European Union. 31/07/2014.
L227.
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
117
ANNEX: DATA SOURCES ON THE REWARDS FROM
AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTION
The two main data sources are the Economic Accounts for Agriculture (Eurostat) and the
Farm Accountancy Data Network (FADN) operated by DG AGRI.
The Economic Accounts for Agriculture
Aggregate economic accounts for agriculture have been published within the EU since 1964,
and from 1969 onwards the six original Member States adopted the common definitions
and procedures of the EU’s Economic Accounts for Agriculture (EAA). For long operated by
a ‘gentleman’s agreement’ between the statistical authorities in Member States, the EAA
was given its own legal basis in 2004 (Regulation (EC) No 138/2004), which served to
underline at the time of EU enlargement the national responsibility to apply the agreed
methodology and to supply data based on it to Eurostat.
An important feature of aggregate accounting for agriculture is that information used in
building the account mostly comes from industry-level sources and not from grossing up
the results of surveys of the accounts of individual farms (though survey data will be used
to fill in gaps). This means that all agricultural production is covered (including non-
agricultural activities which are not separable in the data sources). For example, the value
of output is estimated principally from data on the area of crops and average yields (to give
a volume of crop production) and numbers of livestock, each multiplied by appropriate
prices found from market reports and from the relatively small number of first
users/purchasers (such as dairies). The values of inputs, such as feedstuffs, fertilisers and
seeds, are derived principally from sales from other industries to agriculture, something
possible because of the largely agricultural nature of many of these inputs (animal
feedstuffs and agro-chemicals, etc. being mainly taken by farmers). Similarly, labour costs
can be estimated from multiplying the numbers of workers taken from censuses by annual
average earnings found by surveys.
Data sources vary between Member States and, although the methodology is harmonised,
detailed inventories of how Member States generate information have shown differences
that undermine the appearance of comparability of results, though probably not seriously
when changes over time are the focus of attention.
The advantage of this approach is largely one of speed; the estimates of the aggregate
value of outputs and costs of inputs can be more quickly produced than if reliance were to
be placed on surveys of sets of farm accounts. Preliminary calculations of the income from
agricultural production based on aggregate accounts can be available in Eurostat before the
end of the calendar year to which they relate. For policy-makers, rapid availability of
estimates is important, though perhaps less so now than when the CAP operated principally
using commodity support prices which were adjusted annually.
A substantial revision of the EAA methodology was made in 1997 and applied from 1999
(Eurostat 1997). First, a change of presentation was made. In line with changes in the UN
System of National Accounts and the European System of Accounts (SNA93/ESA95) the
EAA97 was split into a series of three current transactions accounts:
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
118
The Production account, with its balancing item of Net Value Added.
The Generation of Income account, with its balancing item of Operating Surplus
(termed Mixed Income where unincorporated businesses are concerned because it
includes the rewards both for self-employed labour and for capital (this term is used
in the SNA93)).
The Entrepreneurial Income account, with its balancing item of Entrepreneurial
Income (which is equivalent in the previous Eurostat methodology to Net Income
from Agricultural Activity of Family Labour Input).
Within the conceptual framework of the EAA97 there is also a Capital account, not dealt
with here because it cannot yet be compiled on a complete basis and because it attracts
relatively little attention among policy decision-makers.
Second, and more important than the change in presentation, are the revisions that
concern substance. In addition to many adjustments to individual items (such as the timing
of transactions, the calculation of own-account capital formation and the inclusion of
computer software as capital assets) there were some fundamental changes to the EAA
with regards to the basic unit, the measurement of output, the method of valuation and to
the calculation of capital consumption. These are explained fully in Hill (2012, Chapter 4).
Perhaps the most significant was the broadening of coverage to allow the value of
production to include not only that of strictly agricultural commodities but also non-
agricultural activities that could not be separated in the basic data sources (for example,
small-scale food processing and retailing on farms). However, it must be emphasised that
diversified activities on the farm that kept separate accounts and off-farm businesses run
by farms were still excluded. Furthermore, some long-established problems were
continued, including the issue of how to allocate the interest costs incurred by institutional
units (household-firms and companies) between agriculture and other activities that might
be carried on by the business (and in the case of households, their borrowings for
consumption purposes).
Table 1: Economic Accounts for Agriculture: current transactions accounts from
1999
PRODUCTION ACCOUNT
GENERATION OF INCOME
ACCOUNT
ENTREPRENEURIAL
INCOME ACCOUNT
Output
Net Value Added
Net Operating Surplus (Mixed
Income)
Minus Intermediate
consumption
minus compensation of
employees
minus interest paid
Minus consumption of fixed
capital
minus other taxes on
production
minus rent paid
plus other subsidies on
production
= Net Value Added
= Net Operating Surplus
(Mixed Income)
= Net Entrepreneurial
Income
Source: Eurostat (1997).
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
119
The EU also revised its previous indicators of income from agricultural production as part of
the EAA97 methodology. Bearing in mind that the coverage of output and basis of valuation
are both changed from the previous system, and that other detailed alterations took place,
the indicators applied since 1999 are as follows:
Indicator A: Index of the real income of factors in agriculture per annual
work unit. This is calculated by taking the Net Value Added at basic prices that
appears in the Production account and adjusting it by adding ‘other subsidies on
production’ and deducting ‘other taxes on production’, dividing by the labour input,
and expressing in deflated and index form. Without these adjustments, NVA (at
basic prices) would be sensitive to the classification of subsidies as being ‘on
products’ or ‘other subsidies on production’
48
. NVA in this form is referred to as
being at Factor Cost.
Indicator B: Index of real net agricultural Entrepreneurial Income per
unpaid annual work unit. Entrepreneurial Income contains the same broad
elements as the former ‘net income from agricultural activity of family labour input’,
though the label is now more appropriate. It is retained for countries where
agriculture is organised almost totally as unincorporated holdings.
Indicator C: Net Entrepreneurial Income of agriculture. This aggregate is
given in absolute terms, but may also be expressed in index form. The important
point is that it is not calculated per unit of non-hired labour and so is suitable for
uses involving countries where the output from corporate farms is an important part
of the total.
Despite the revisions, it is clear that the approach embodied in each of the present
Indicators remains essentially one of trying to gauge the rewards to a hybrid bundle of
factors used in the production of agricultural commodities. NVA at Factor Cost is a long way
from the personal incomes of the agricultural community (unless there is no borrowing, no
renting of land, no hired labour and no other sources of income to the household). While
Entrepreneurial Income coincides broadly with what might be seen as profit, it only relates
to that originating from agricultural activity and excludes that which might come from other
activities carried on within the farm business, unless these are very minor and inseparable
in the basic data sources.
The Farm Accounts Data Network (FADN)
At EU level, the farm accounts surveys of all the Member States are brought together under
the co-ordination of the Commission’s Directorate-General for Agriculture and Rural
Development (DG AGRI) as the Farm Accountancy Data Network (FADN), also known by its
French acronym RICA. This was established in 1965 ‘with the specific objective of obtaining
data enabling income changes in the various classes of agricultural holding to be properly
monitored’ (Commission, 1982). The justification for FADN was rooted in policy, in that
‘...the development of the Common Agricultural Policy requires that there should be
available objective and relevant information on incomes in the various categories of
agricultural holdings and on the business operation of holdings coming within categories
which call for special attention at Community level’ (EEC Regulation 79/65). FADN is
48
Decoupled payments under the Single Payment Scheme (now the Basic Payments) are an ‘other subsidy on
production’. While such payments could be easily handled within an accounting system based on the
institutional unit, they caused a difficulty in activity accounts. Treating them strictly would have resulted in
them not being included in the value of agricultural production or in Value Added at basic prices. This would
have shown a major fall in statistics on the Value Added from agricultural production at the point of revision of
the methodology, which was deemed to be unacceptable. Their inclusion in the calculation of Indicator A
preserves a degree of continuity with the preceding set of ‘income indicators’.
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
120
therefore not a single survey but is an amalgamation of national surveys carried out by
Member States. In some countries these predated RICA, as in the UK, but in others they
were started from scratch. The nature of FADN is in part a reflection of the approaches
inherited from these pre-existing surveys. Ways of collecting the data vary from country to
country, but there is a fundamental harmonised methodology which applies to the concepts
of income employed and, increasingly, to the selection of the sample (Commission, 1989).
FADN focuses on agricultural holdings deemed to be commercial, in the sense that they are
large enough to provide a main activity for the farmer and a level of income sufficient to
support his or her family (Commission, 1985a). The interpretation of what is commercial
has changed. The original Council Regulation 79/65 stipulated that the field of survey
should cover those agricultural holdings, which (a) are run as market-oriented holdings,
and (b) provide the main occupation of the operator.
During the first three years, data were taken only from agricultural holdings having an area
exceeding five hectares, with the exception of holdings producing wine, fruit, vegetables
and olives. In 1972 this was amended. In addition to being market-oriented, and providing
the main occupation of the operator, it was to be of a size capable of employing at least
one worker (1 work unit) over a year, though this threshold could be reduced to 0.75 work
units. (Hyvönen, 2004). These criteria implied a discrimination against part-time farmers in
the sample, but this was justified by the belief that ‘main-living’ farms constituted the most
important target for agricultural policy measures, an interpretation which should not go
unnoticed. However there was a revision of this thinking in 1981, and from 1982/3
selection thresholds have been made only in terms of size in Economic Size Units (which
are based on Standard Gross Margin). No notice is to be taken when selecting the sample
of any other gainful activities in which the operator may engage.
There is a minimum size threshold that varies between Member States, reflecting their
different farm size structures as shown in the periodic EU Farm Structure Survey. In
particular, Belgium, Germany, the Netherlands and the UK (excluding Northern Ireland)
have imposed size thresholds that exclude many holdings that would be eligible for
inclusion in FADN in the other Member States. Thresholds are periodically revised. Users of
published results at EU level should be aware that not all countries are presented in the
smallest size groups.
Consequently, while the overwhelming majority of farming activity falls within the FADN
field of observation, only 42% of the EU’s agricultural holdings found in its farm structure
survey are represented (2015). Figures vary widely between countries. For example, in
Slovakia only 17% of farms are covered by FADN, but these represent 96% of the
economic activity, whereas in Ireland 75% of the farms are covered, with 98% of the
activity. Though numerically important, holdings below the FADN size thresholds contribute
very little in terms of agricultural activity. In many Member States, especially more recent
additions to the Union, it is likely that the coverage of holdings within FADN is even lower
because some farms are small that they fall below the size for qualification for inclusion in
the Structure Survey. Altogether the FADN sample consists of just under 87,000 holdings
(2014), corresponding to about 1.7% of all holdings within the FADN’s field of observation.
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
121
Table 2: FADN field of observation
Member State
Farms in
the Farm
Structure
Survey
Farms in
the FADN
field of
observation
FADN field of
observation
Farms %
SO %
UAA %
AWU %
Belgium
42,850
31,010
72
98
95
87
Bulgaria
370,490
115,390
31
91
96
51
Czech
Republic
22,860
14,820
65
99
98
93
Denmark
42,100
29,340
70
99
96
89
Germany
299,130
196,520
66
97
93
87
Estonia
19,610
8,080
41
98
89
76
Ireland
139,890
105,170
75
98
92
84
Greece
723,010
341,180
47
90
85
79
Spain
989,800
597,970
60
98
92
84
France
516,100
317,360
61
97
91
85
Italy
1,620,880
838,740
52
97
91
82
Cyprus
38,860
10,530
27
92
76
70
Latvia
83,390
21,940
26
91
73
52
Lithuania
199,910
53,440
27
86
78
54
Luxembourg
2,200
1,610
73
98
97
90
Hungary
576,810
107,250
19
90
93
46
Malta
12,530
3,080
25
93
56
54
Netherlands
72,320
52,220
72
99
93
90
Austria
150,170
95,150
63
97
86
85
Poland
1,506,620
730,880
49
93
85
68
Portugal
305,270
114,170
37
93
89
53
Romania
3,859,040
1,042,570
27
83
78
59
Slovenia
74,650
41,300
55
92
85
74
Slovakia
24,460
4,260
17
96
95
76
Finland
63,870
42,630
67
97
89
90
Sweden
71,090
29,050
41
94
84
72
United
Kingdom
186,660
94,640
51
96
82
75
Source: DG AGRI EU-FADN.
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
122
Altogether the FADN sample consists of about 81,000 holdings (EU-27, 2007),
corresponding to about 1.5% of all holdings within the FADN’s field of observation. The
sample is stratified by economic size (in European Size Units), by farming type and by
region and all published results are weighted appropriately. In the strict sense, the sample
is not random, since it is drawn from holdings that keep accounts and participation by
farmers is voluntary. However, the representative nature of the sample is under constant
scrutiny.
Another feature of the sample is that its composition changes a little from year to year as
holdings enter or leave the survey. There are good statistical reasons why a turnover is
required; the experience in some national surveys is that the greater information that
becomes available to co-operating farms enables their performance to improve so that they
are no longer typical of the generality of farms. Part of any difference in results from year
to year can be laid at the door of this changing sample, though the impact is unlikely to be
substantial in countries where FADN is well established and the sample is of stable size.
Nevertheless, the gradual drift up in average size must be borne in mind when interpreting
income movement over time.
A comprehensive set of data relating to many aspects of the farm business is collected.
The items are specified on a standard Farm Return, which is established in Community
legislation (the latest of which is Commission Regulation (EC) 868/2008, operating from the
financial year 2009). This contains detailed instructions on how the Farm Return is to be
completed and provides definitions of the terms used. Though having the advantage that
Member States are obliged to provide this data, the legal basis of the Farm Return makes
any major changes to it a cumbersome process. Currently data are collected covering the
physical and value details of animal and crop output, the costs of crop variable inputs (such
as seeds and fertilisers), of animal feedingstuffs, labour, interest and land charges, details
of spending and receipts from livestock, deadstock and machinery, the debt situation,
grants, subsidies and Value Added Tax (VAT). The data relate to the whole farm, so that,
for example, it is not at present possible to allocate the input of fertiliser between the
various crops on the holding and to calculate measures of enterprise profitability. This has
severely limited the ability of FADN to monitor the impact of the CAP’s main policy
instruments at farm level.
The data collected relate only to farming activity on the holding (though for national
purposes some Member States collect additional information). For the FADN the borderline
between agricultural and non-agricultural is based on the standard industrial classification
used within the EU. Agricultural activity is deemed to include agricultural contracting
(primary stage activity, such as ploughing and harvesting for other farmers). Thus, if the
resources of the holding are used in food manufacturing or any other non-farming activity
which contributes to the income of the farmer and his household, in principle these are not
covered in the FADN. This exclusion also applies to any building activities which the farmer
may undertake himself rather than by employing a builder. However, it is clear that FADN
does not collect information on any off-farm activities which the farmer or his family may
engage in (as hired workers or as self-employed), or on pensions, property extraneous to
the agricultural holding, personal taxation or private insurance.
FADN’s main income measures are Farm Net Value Added, expressed per farm or per
Annual Work Unit (FNVA/AWU) (that is, per full-time person equivalents working on the
farm) and Family Farm Income (FFI), per farm or per Family Work Unit (FFI/FFI). For
farms with no family labour the residual is termed Farm Net Income and this is expressed
per unit of total labour input. Figure 47 shows how these are calculated. There are also
Cash Flow indicators.
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
123
NVA is the difference between the value of farm output and the variable inputs purchased
from other sectors of the economy, after adjustment for subsidies and taxes on production
and for the consumption of capital (in the form of a depreciation allowance). Produce
consumed by the farm household is valued as part of output. Changes in stocks of output
and inputs are taken into account. As a concept it is close to Net Value Added as used in
the aggregate Economic Accounts for Agriculture (described previously in this chapter),
though there are differences in detail. FNVA is the sum that is available for rewarding all
the fixed factors of production, that is, all the labour, land and capital used on the farm
irrespective of who owns them. As with the industry-level indicator, the reason why NVA
per AWU is used without distinguishing between farmer labour and hired workers seems to
do with interpretation of the intentions of Article 39 of the Treaty of Rome as relating to all
people working in agriculture (employed, self-employed and family help). However, such a
figure can mask marked differences between the rewards of hired workers and of farmers
and their families.
FNVA is capable of being distributed in a variety of ways. In the earlier phase of the FADN
attempts were made to calculate a Labour Income by deducting costs for all other inputs,
including imputed rents for owned land and a notional interest charge for the working
capital of the business. Such calculations were eventually abandoned because of the
difficulties of settling on the levels of imputed costs (Hill, 1991). However, a measure called
the remuneration of family labour has been reported recently (European Commission,
2014a) that once again involves imputation; it is calculated by deducting from FNVA the
costs of wages, rent and interest paid (as FNI below) and the opportunity costs of own land
and capital. This is expressed per family work unit (FWU). It is debateable whether the old
difficulties have been overcome or just forgotten.
As a measure of income, FNVA falls short of what most farmers would perceive as their
profit because no deductions are made for interest payments on loans, for rents on
tenanted land and for the cost of hired labour. In the early stages of FADN some Member
States experienced difficulty in obtaining reliable information on some of these fixed
factors, particularly interest payments, so FNVA was the most convenient common measure
which could be adopted.
For a time, FNVA tended to be replaced as a measure of income by Family Farm Income
(FFI). The same concept is now called Farm Net Income, a reflection that enlargement has
increased the proportion of farms that do not have the family-run structure that dominates
the EU-15, though the term FFI is still used in situations where family (unpaid) labour is
greater than zero and in the FADN definition of variables (European Commission, 2014c).
FFI is a concept first used in the 1984 report on incomes covering the years 1978/9 to
1981/2. This is the residual remaining to the farmer and the other unpaid labour of the
household after the deduction of interest payments, rent payments and the costs of hired
labour. It represents the reward to the farmer and his family from using their owned land,
capital and labour input in agricultural activity on the holding. In practice it accords broadly
with the notion of profit from farming which is available for consumption spending, for
saving and investment or for other calls on personal income (such as taxation). Of course,
there may be other income sources which contribute to this spending and saving, but they
are not derived from farming the holding and are therefore outside the coverage of FADN.
Capital gains (and losses) on land and other assets do not form part of FFI, though they too
might be considered as elements in the long-term rewards from farming and might form
the basis of borrowing for consumption and investment purposes. More recently the
Commission appear to have once again focused on FNVA.
Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies
____________________________________________________________________________________________
124
Figure 47: The calculation of Economic Indicators in the FADN
Source: European Commission (2014b)
Again, FNI/FFI is often expressed per annual work unit of unpaid (family) labour (Family
Work Unit, or FWU), including the farmer, in order to reflect the varying amounts of such
+
-
Opening Stocks of
Livestock Products
Closing Stocks of Livestock Products
+
Sales of Livestock Products
Farmhouse Consumption of
Livestock Products
Farm Use of Livestock Products
Sales of Livestock
+
+
+
Purchase of
Livestock
-
+
+
Farmhouse Consumption of Livestock
Livestock growth and appreciation
OTHER OUTPUT
(SE256)
TOTAL OUTPUT LIVESTOCK &
PRODUCTS (SE206)
Closing
Stocks
+
-
Opening
Stock
+
Sales
+
Farmhouse
Consumption
Farm Use
+
TOTAL OUTPUT CROPS
& PRODUCTS (SE135)
Total specific costs
(SE281)
Total farming
overheads (SE336)
TOTAL
OUTPUT
(SE131)
+
Taxes
(SE390)
Total subsidies excl.
investment (SE605)
VAT on
Sales
VAT
reimbursed
by the
State
VAT on
Purchases
VAT Balance excl.
Investment
(SE395)
Balance current
subsides & taxes
(SE600)
Total
Intermediate
consumption
(SE275)
GROSSFARM INCOME (SE410)
FARM NET
VALUE
ADDED
(SE415)
FARM NET INCOME
(SE420)
FAMILY FARM INCOME
(SE430N)
Annual
Work
Units
(SE010)
Balance subs & taxes on
investment (SE405)
Annual Work
Units (SE010)
Family Work
Units (SE015)
FARM NET
VALUE
ADDED per
Annual Work
Unit (SE425)
Subsidies on
investment
(SE406)
+
+
-
+
-
Depreciation (SE360)
Wages Paid (SE370)
Rent Paid (SE375)
Interest Paid
(SE380)
+
+
+
Total external
factors (SE365)
+
-
+
-
+
-
+
+
÷
Payments to
daily outgoins
(SE407)
VAT on
investments
(SE408)
+
+
-
÷
FARM NET INCOME
per Annual Work
Unit
÷
FAMILY FARM
INCOME per Family
Work Unit (SE430)
If family Work Unit (SE015)>0
Comparison of farmers’ incomes in the EU Member States
____________________________________________________________________________________________
125
labour used. As long as its definition is borne in mind, FNI/FFI is a very useful measure on
two counts: first, it represents what would generally be accepted as being entrepreneurial
income (or profit) derived from farming; and, second, by excluding the hired labour force,
it covers only those people whose welfare the CAP is in practice primarily aimed farmers
and their families.
FFI is conceptually close to Eurostat’s aggregate Net Income from Agricultural Activity of
Family Labour Input and, when expressed per unit of family labour input, to Indicator B. A
number of additional income indicators have been proposed and investigated by FADN (Hill,
1991).