265
H
umans not only live incredibly social lives,
but they also live incredibly prosocial
lives. Biologists and social scientists have long
marveled at the human ability to join together in
efforts to produce public goods that could not be
achieved by any single person alone. The abil-
ity for humans to cooperate, that is, to engage
in behaviors that benefit others (sometimes
even at a cost to oneself), underlies some of the
most notable human accomplishments. Yet co-
operation can sometimes be very challenging
for individuals in a group (or between groups)
because some situations can contain a conflict
of interest, such that it is in each individuals
immediate self-interest to free ride and take
advantage of others’ cooperation (i.e., social
dilemmas; De Dreu, 2010; Fehr, Fischbacher,
& Gächter, 2002; Van Lange, Rockenbach, &
Yamagishi, 2014).
For decades theorists and researchers have
attempted to understand why humans cooper-
ate in social dilemmas (Dawes, 1980; Komorita
& Parks, 1995; Pruitt & Kimmel, 1977; Van
Lange, Balliet, Parks, & Van Vugt, 2014). One
of the most long-standing traditions has been
from a biological perspective. According to
Darwinian theory of evolution, a species cannot
evolve to be cooperative unless there are sur-
vival and reproductive benefits from coopera-
tion, and cooperative traits must compete with
noncooperative alternatives, which can result in
potentially greater fitness benefits if social in-
teractions are modeled as a social dilemma (see
Rand & Nowak, 2013). This problem of coop-
eration has attracted some of the greatest minds
across a number of scientific disciplines in the
biological and social sciences.
Since the 1960s, many theories have been
proposed to explain why humans evolved to
cooperate. Hamilton (1964) formalized the idea
that cooperating with kin can increase the rep-
lication of ones own genes by increasing the
chance of survival and reproduction of others
who share ones genes (i.e., inclusive fitness).
This was followed by Trivers’s (1971) model
that people may cooperate with others from
whom they expect future cooperation (i.e., di-
rect reciprocity). With direct reciprocity, actors
receive (sometimes delayed) benefits directly
from the individual they helped. Several addi-
tional candidate models have been forwarded
in more recent years, including costly signaling
(Gintis, Smith, & Bowles, 2001), generalized
reciprocity (Pfeiffer, Rutte, Killingback, Ta-
borsky, & Bonhoeffer, 2005), and geneculture
coevolution (Richerson et al., 2016).
CHAPTER 14
Indirect Reciprocity, Gossip,
and Reputation-Based Cooperation
Daniel Balliet
Junhui Wu
Paul A. M. Van Lange
VanLange_Book.indb 265VanLange_Book.indb 265 6/30/2020 11:17:37 AM6/30/2020 11:17:37 AM
266 I. PRINCIPLES IN THEORY
In this chapter, we draw attention to a model
of how humans evolved to cooperate (and also
avoid interactions with noncooperators)rep-
utation-based indirect reciprocity—and this
model carries rich potential for understanding
some basic cognitive and motivational process-
es underlying social behavior. Indirect reciproc-
ity involves two events: (1) An actor extends a
benefit (or not) to a recipient and (2) a third party
obtains knowledge of the actor’s behavior and
decides to cooperate (or not) with the actor at
some point in the future (Alexander, 1987/2017;
Boyd & Richerson, 1989; Nowak & Sigmund,
1998b). An essential element for indirect reci-
procity to occur is that a third party directly
observes the interaction between the actor and
the recipient or learns about the actor’s behavior
through communication, such as gossip. Direct
and indirect reciprocity vary in how an actor
acquires benefits from his or her own coopera-
tion. Direct reciprocity occurs when the recipi-
ent of the benefit of a cooperative action returns
a benefit to the cooperative actor. Indirect reci-
procity, on the other hand, occurs when anyone,
except for the recipient of the benefit of a co-
operative action, delivers a benefit to the coop-
erative actor. Direct and indirect reciprocity can
also involve responding to others’ noncoopera-
tive actions by imposing either direct or indirect
costs on the noncooperative actor, respectively.
In this chapter, we focus on indirect reciprocity
and reputation-based cooperation. Indirect reci-
procity could be a unique evolutionary pathway
to human cooperation, although a few examples
suggest that indirect reciprocity can also occur
in other species, such as cleaner fish (Bshary
& Grutter, 2006) and song sparrows (Akçay,
Reed, Campbell, Templeton, & Beecher, 2010).
Regardless, the capacity for language has en-
abled humans to exploit this route to coopera-
tion in large groups of genetically unrelated
individuals (Dunbar, 2004).
Although much of the theoretical work on
indirect reciprocity emerged from the biologi-
cal sciences, the topic of indirect reciprocity
is now widely studied by a growing number of
scientists across numerous disciplines, includ-
ing behavioral economics and psychology. They
have studied (1) the influence of indirect reci-
procity on cooperation in the lab and field, (2)
environmental conditions that facilitate indirect
reciprocity, and (3) the proximate psychological
processes that underlie this human ability. Our
purpose in this chapter is to integrate biological,
economic, and psychological research on how
indirect reciprocity facilitates cooperation. In
doing so, we use models in evolutionary biolo-
gy to generate insights about how humans have
evolved to engage in reputation-based indirect
reciprocity and discuss ideas and research about
the proximate psychological mechanisms oper-
ating to make this form of cooperation possible.
Evolutionary Dynamics, Direct
Reciprocity, and Indirect Reciprocity
With the exception of species that reproduce
incredibly fast (e.g., fruit flies), we cannot ob-
serve how the process of evolution selects for
the adaptive design of a species. Because it can
be exceedingly difficult, or even impossible, to
study the process by which evolution shapes
organisms, scientists have resorted to creating
their own “organisms” (i.e., agents) in computer
programs. Agent-based modeling is an ap-
proach used to study how evolutionary dynam-
ics can select for certain behavioral strategies in
a population of agents. This method has become
incredibly popular over the last few decades and
has yielded several valuable insights about how
evolution could have shaped human social be-
havior (Nowak, 2006).
The models always begin with a population
of agents that have preprogrammed behavioral
strategies (e.g., always cooperate, always de-
fect, tit for tat, and winstay, loseshift), and
then these agents interact with each other over
a lifespan in a situation that contains specified
outcomes. The outcome is the number of off-
spring an agent produces in a lifetime, and off-
spring always have a higher chance to inherit
the behavioral strategy of their parents. In the
context of the study of cooperation, agents are
most often specified to interact in a prisoner’s
dilemma (PD; or some variant of the PD, see
Figure 14.1). In the PD, each person can decide
to deliver a benefit (b) to the other at some cost
(c) to him- or herself. When the benefit to the
other is greater than the cost to oneself (b > c),
then both can obtain better outcomes if each
person decides to extend a benefit to the other.
However, in this type of situation, the best out-
VanLange_Book.indb 266VanLange_Book.indb 266 6/30/2020 11:17:37 AM6/30/2020 11:17:37 AM
14. Indirect Reciprocity, Gossip, and Reputation-Based Cooperation 267
come for each person can be obtained by not
paying the cost to deliver a benefit to the other,
and nonetheless receive a benefit delivered by
the partner. Thus, cooperation in the PD is mu-
tually beneficial, but it is always vulnerable to
exploitation and free riding by noncooperators.
A corpus of literature has formed around un-
derstanding the behavioral strategies that can
successfully maintain cooperation in a species
and are robust to invasion by noncooperators
(for reviews, see Nowak, 2006; Rand & Nowak,
2013; West, Griffin, & Gardner, 2007).
These models have generated support and
insights about behavioral strategies of direct
reciprocity in a population characterized by
repeated encounters. Early modeling work
demonstrated that the simple rule of tit for tat
(i.e., cooperate first, then follow ones part-
ner’s previous behavior) outperformed many
other more complex strategies (Axelrod, 1984).
Subsequent modeling work discovered another
strategy that outcompeted tit for tat—winstay,
loseshift (i.e., cooperate only if both players
had the same behavior on the previous round;
Nowak & Sigmund, 1993). Yet these strategies
can make costly errors in environments where
people sometimes intend to cooperate but end
up defecting. In these environments, a more for-
giving tit-for-tat strategy (i.e., cooperates once
again after a partner defects, but then defects
after a partner’s second defection; tit for two
tats; Wu & Axelrod, 1995) is more successful.
Also, adding some generosity to the tit-for-tat
strategy can be effective in “noisy” environ-
ments in which it is not always certain that an
intended choice results in actual choice (Kol-
lock, 1993). Indeed, changing parameters of the
environment itself (e.g., the situation is noisy or
not) or the social environment (i.e., the strate-
gies followed by others) can affect which strat-
egy is most successful. Thus, modeling work
can benefit from attempting to make plausible
assumptions about the ancestral conditions in
which humans evolved to cooperate (Tooby &
Cosmides, 1996).
The modeling work reported here provides us
insights about how evolution may have shaped
certain strategies of cooperation that could ac-
quire direct benefits, and still prevent a popu-
lation from being invaded and exploited by
defectors. The models can be used to generate
hypotheses about different adaptions humans
could have developed to regulate their coop-
eration to acquire direct benefits (see Delton,
Krasnow, Cosmides, & Tooby, 2011), such as
cheater detection (Cosmides, Barrett, & Tooby,
Cooperate
Not Cooperate
Player B
Cooperate
Not Cooperate
Player A
bc
bc
b
– c
b
0
0
FIGURE 14.1. The interdependence structure of a prisoner’s dilemma. Cooperation means delivering
a benefit (b) to one’s partner at a cost (c) to oneself (b > c).
VanLange_Book.indb 267VanLange_Book.indb 267 6/30/2020 11:17:38 AM6/30/2020 11:17:38 AM
268 I. PRINCIPLES IN THEORY
2010), revenge and forgiveness (McCullough,
Kurzban, & Tabak, 2013), gratitude (Ma, Tun-
ney, & Ferguson, 2017), generosity (Van Lange,
Ouwerkerk, & Tazelaar, 2002), and inferences
about future interactions (Delton et al., 2011).
Similarly, agent-based models have also pro-
vided insights about how evolution may have
shaped the way humans engage in indirect reci-
procity and its role in the maintenance of large-
scale cooperation. Nowak and Sigmund (1998a,
1998b) found that indirect reciprocity can evolve
if agents have knowledge about how their part-
ners have behaved toward others in previous
interactions (i.e., image score), then condition
their behavior on their partners’ past behavior.
In this modeling work, in each round of inter-
actions between agents, agents were randomly
assigned to be a donor or a receiver. The donor
could decide to pay a small cost to provide the
receiver with a larger benefit. Each donor would
receive a positive point for each helping behav-
ior and a negative point for each failure to help.
Cooperation evolved when agents assigned as
donors conditioned their decisions to help based
on the recipients’ image score (i.e., only help if
the recipient has a positive image score). Since
this initial work, a number of models have fur-
ther examined how different environments and
decision rules can affect the evolution of coop-
eration via indirect reciprocity (e.g., Ohtsuki &
Iwasa, 2006).
The modeling research described here serves
two complementary goals. First, modeling be-
havioral strategies of indirect reciprocity can
help us understand how humans evolved to
cooperate. Second, the modeling work can be
used to develop and test hypotheses about how
evolution could have modified the design of an
organism to cooperate to acquire direct and in-
direct benefits. Modeling evolutionary dynam-
ics can be viewed as a way to develop theories
and generate new predictions that can be test-
ed using behavioral experimentsand this is
where the modeling becomes most relevant for
psychologists.
An initial step in testing predictions from an
agent-based model is conducting behavioral ex-
periments to observe whether human behavior
varies according to how the models predict (for
a list of predictions generated by specific agent-
based models of indirect reciprocity, see Table
14.1). For example, empirical researchers could
design lab experiments to examine whether the
possibility of punishing defectors, with the de-
cision to punish affecting one’s reputation, is
especially effective at promoting cooperation in
larger groups (e.g., groups of eight vs. groups of
four; dos Santos & Wedekind, 2015).
A further step would be unpacking the abili-
ties that could have evolved to promote these
types of behaviorand this is often an entirely
different enterprise in applying evolution to
understanding human behavior, often referred
to as an adaptationist approach or evolution-
ary psychology (Tooby & Cosmides, 1992).
The agent-based models provide insights about
the evolutionary success of certain behavioral
strategies, but the models are agnostic about
the actual psychological mechanisms that could
have evolved through the process of evolution
to promote such behaviors. Importantly, evolu-
tion does not select for organisms to engage in
a specific behavior. Instead, the outputs of the
evolutionary process are psychological mecha-
nisms that process input from the environment
and produce behavior. Interestingly, there has
been much more agent-based modeling work on
the role of indirect reciprocity on cooperation
compared to an adaptationist approach. Much
of what comes next is a discussion of the pos-
sible psychological mechanisms that could be
operating to enable indirect reciprocity to pro-
mote large-scale cooperation. Yet prior to dis-
cussing the proximate psychology of indirect
reciprocity, we take a moment to consider re-
cent work that has documented the phenomenon
that people actually engage in indirect reciproc-
ity in their daily lives and in controlled lab en-
vironments.
Indirect Reciprocity in the Field
Agent-based modeling of the evolution of in-
direct reciprocity suggests that humans could
have adaptations that regulate their cooperative
behavior in a way that is structured according
to indirect reciprocity. One of the first steps in a
program of research on this topic is to document
that humans in fact do behave in ways that look
like indirect reciprocity, and a number of recent
field studies give us insights in this matter.
VanLange_Book.indb 268VanLange_Book.indb 268 6/30/2020 11:17:38 AM6/30/2020 11:17:38 AM
14. Indirect Reciprocity, Gossip, and Reputation-Based Cooperation 269
TABLE 14.1. Examples of Testable Hypotheses about Human Behavior Derived
from Agent-Based Modeling on Indirect Reciprocity
Study Model description Hypotheses
dos Santos &
Wedekind (2015)
Computer simulations tested two
reputation systems (reputation
based on cooperative and
noncooperative actions and
reputation based on punitive and
nonpunitive actions) in a public
goods game involving groups of
unrelated individuals.
Compared to reputation systems based on
cooperation, reputation systems based on
punishment (1) are more likely to lead to the
evolution of cooperation in larger groups, (2)
more effectively sustains cooperation within
larger groups, and (3) are more robust to errors
in reputation assessment.
Leimar &
Hammerstein (2001)
Simulations tested how
cooperation evolves through two
indirect reciprocity strategies
(i.e., image scoring and standing
strategy).
(1) Image scoring strategies enhance
cooperation only when the cost of
cooperation is small.
(2) Standing strategy outperforms image
scoring even when there are errors in
perception.
Roberts (2008) Evolutionary simulations
compared indirect reciprocity
strategies (i.e., image scoring
and simple standing) with
direct reciprocity strategies in
large groups with less repeated
interactions and in small groups
with more repeated interactions.
(1) As probability of repeated interactions
increases, indirect reciprocity through image
scoring becomes less stable in promoting
cooperation than direct reciprocity by
experience scoring.
(2) Indirect reciprocity through standing
strategy is as stable as direct reciprocity in
promoting cooperation when individuals
have repeated interactions with few partners.
Sasaki, Okada, &
Nakai (2017)
An evolutionary analysis
compared a simple “staying” norm
with other prevailing social norms
that discriminate the good and the
bad.
Staying is most effective in establishing
cooperation than other social norms that rely
on constant monitoring and unconditional
assessment (i.e., scoring, simple-standing,
stern-judging, and shunning).
a
Giardini, Paolucci,
Villatoro, & Conte
(2014)
An agent-based simulation
assessed how cooperation rates
change when agents can punish
others or know others’ reputation
and then defect with free riders or
refuse to interact with them.
(1) Both punishment and reputation-based
partner selection are effective in maintaining
cooperation.
(2) Cooperation decreases when people defect
after learning about free riders’ reputations.
(3) A combination of punishment and
reputation-based partner selection leads to
higher cooperation rates.
Giardini & Vilone
(2016)
An agent-based model tested the
conditions under which gossip
and ostracism might enhance
cooperation in groups of different
sizes by addressing the effects
of quantity and quality of gossip,
network structure, and errors in
gossip transmission.
(1) Cooperation is more likely to thrive in
larger groups when the amount of gossip
exchanged is abundant.
(2) Inclusion errors (i.e., one’s negative
reputation is understood as positive) in
gossip transmission are more detrimental
to cooperation than exclusion errors (i.e.,
one’s positive reputation is understood as
negative).
a
Staying = the reputation of a person who gives help stays the same as in the last assessment if the recipient has a bad reputation;
scoring (or image scoring) = people lose reputations anytime they fail to help someone in need; simple standing (or standing strat-
egy) = reputation declines when one fails to help someone with a good reputation; stern judging = people lose reputations when they
help someone with a bad reputation or fail to help a person with a good reputation; shunning = people gain a good reputation only
when they help someone with a good reputation; otherwise they lose a good reputation.
VanLange_Book.indb 269VanLange_Book.indb 269 6/30/2020 11:17:38 AM6/30/2020 11:17:38 AM
270 I. PRINCIPLES IN THEORY
In a field study with 2,413 residents, re-
searchers collaborated with a utility company
to examine participation in a program to pre-
vent blackouts during high electricity demand
(Yoeli, Hoffman, Rand, & Nowak, 2013). They
found that participation rate was tripled when
residents’ identities were observable (vs. con-
cealed) on the sign-up sheet, and this positive
effect of observability was four times larger
than that of monetary reward. More important-
ly, observability had a larger effect for home-
owners (vs. temporary renters) and people liv-
ing in apartments (vs. houses), as they tend to
have longer-term relationships with neighbors.
In this study, we clearly see that people are more
cooperative when their behavior is observable,
and so can affect their reputation within their
social network.
Similarly, van Apeldoorn and Schram (2016)
examined indirect reciprocity in a field ex-
periment utilizing an online platform in which
people can ask and offer services to each other
for free. They created new member profiles that
vary in serving history (i.e., “serving” or “neu-
tral” profile), then sent out service requests to
worldwide members. People were more likely to
reward a service request from someone who had
previously offered services to others. Another
natural field experiment conducted in a hair
salon revealed that customers tended to offer
more tips to hairdressers who were collecting
donations to a charity, compared to doing noth-
ing (Khadjavi, 2016). These studies support the
idea that people are more cooperative with oth-
ers who have a cooperative reputation.
In fact, people are strongly influenced by in-
formation about others’ reputations, even more
so than information about their similarity with
others. Abrahao, Parigi, Gupta, and Cook (2017)
conducted a large-scale online experiment with
8,906 users of Airbnb playing an interpersonal
investment game. In this game, the users had
to make trust decisions toward potential receiv-
ers whose profiles varied in distance (i.e., the
extent to which the receiver matched the demo-
graphic attributes of participants across four
categories) and two reputation features (i.e.,
the average ratings and the number of reviews
on Airbnb). The users had 100 credits that they
could keep or invest in the receivers they chose.
Any amount invested was tripled and the re-
ceiver could then decide to return some amount
to users. The authors found that people tend
to trust receivers with a better reputation even
though they are dissimilar, and this was further
confirmed when analyzing real-world data of 1
million actual hospitality interactions among
users of Airbnb.
Taken together, these field studies show that
indirect reciprocity promotes cooperation in
contexts outside of the laboratory. Specifically,
this work documents that people are willing to
(1) behave in ways that maintain a positive and
cooperative reputation and (2) condition their
cooperation on their partners’ reputations.
Indirect Reciprocity in the Lab
Several experiments using economic games
as a paradigm to study cooperation have dem-
onstrated that people do engage in indirect
reciprocity. Wedekind and Milinski (2000)
conducted a behavioral experiment with a de-
sign similar to previous modeling work (i.e.,
Nowak & Sigmund, 1998b). In this study, par-
ticipants interacted with each other in several
rounds, and in each round they were selected to
interact with a different person as a donor or a
receiver. The donor decided whether to give 2
Swiss Francs to a receiver who would then earn
four Swiss Francs. In each round, participants
(assigned a pseudonym) could see the previous
decisions made by their partners. The study
revealed that people were more likely to give
money to another person who had given money
to others in the past.
Similar experiments have revealed that peo-
ple are more likely to help others who have a
positive reputation (Engelmann & Fischbacher,
2009; Seinen & Schram, 2006; Stanca, 2009).
When people can build a reputation in a group
based on their helping behavior, then groups
display higher levels of cooperation (Milinski,
Semmann, & Krambeck, 2002). Furthermore,
when people can gossip about each other during
interactions in a repeated public goods game
(i.e., a multiperson PD), then people become
more cooperative, compared to when gossip is
not allowed (Feinberg, Willer, & Schultz, 2014;
Wu, Balliet, & Van Lange, 2015).
Of course, people may strategically build
reputations to achieve higher earnings (e.g.,
VanLange_Book.indb 270VanLange_Book.indb 270 6/30/2020 11:17:38 AM6/30/2020 11:17:38 AM
14. Indirect Reciprocity, Gossip, and Reputation-Based Cooperation 271
only help others when being observed), and
economists have been interested in empirically
distinguishing such strategic behaviors aimed
at maximizing self-interest from a motivation
to extend benefits to others who have a coop-
erative reputation. To accomplish this, Engel-
mann and Fischbacher (2009) had participants
interact in an 80-trial helping game involving
a donor and a receiver. Participants were ran-
domly assigned to be a donor or a receiver in
each trial, and had a public or private score for
the first or last 40 trials (i.e., public scores dis-
played past behaviors to current partners, and
this information was not provided to current
partners in the private score condition). This
design allowed participants to interact with oth-
ers who had private or public scores. Important-
ly, they found that people with a private score
were still willing to help others with a higher
positive public score. Thus, participants with
a private score had no strategic incentives to
condition their cooperation toward people with
a cooperative reputation, so it is unlikely that
a motivation to maximize own outcomes was
directing these behaviors. The authors take this
as evidence that people have a social preference
to help others who have a helpful and coopera-
tive reputation.
Lab studies have also examined how effec-
tive and efficient indirect reciprocity can be at
promoting cooperation. This question becomes
especially relevant when one compares gossip
(i.e., reputation sharing) with another mecha-
nism that can support cooperation: the possi-
bility to punish others’ past behavior. A prior
study revealed that gossip is more effective and
efficient than punishment (Wu, Balliet, & Van
Lange, 2016a). Although punishment can be an
effective means to promoting cooperation, pun-
ishment is costly to enact and can result in re-
taliation. Gossip, on the other hand, may be less
costly to enact and involves less exposure to the
costs of retaliation. There can be reputational
costs in gossip, but this is not always true (Fein-
berg, Cheng, & Willer, 2012).
The agent-based models suggest that indirect
reciprocity is a possible route through which
evolutionary processes shape human coopera-
tion, and now we see that both lab and field
experiments have documented that people do
engage in indirect reciprocity. However, docu-
menting the existence, effectiveness, and effi-
ciency of indirect reciprocity does not provide
an explanation for this behavioral phenomenon.
Moreover, agent-based models and economic
models do not specify the cognitive and moti-
vational processes that produce behaviors in a
system of indirect reciprocity. Currently, there
is a need to develop theories about the proxi-
mate psychological mechanisms that could be
operating to produce these forms of behavior.
An Evolutionary
Psychology Approach
Agent-based models suggest that humans could
have evolved to cooperate in a system of indi-
rect reciprocity, so an evolutionary psychology
approach can be applied to hypothesize about
the proximate psychological mechanisms that
could have evolved to produce these behav-
iors. Evolutionary psychology aims to under-
stand how different cognitive and motivational
mechanisms of the human mind have evolved
to function and produce behavior. Prior to ap-
plying this perspective, we need to understand
a few key concepts (for several reviews, see
Confer et al., 2010; Cosmides & Tooby, 2013;
for comparisons of this perspective to other ap-
proaches in the social sciences, see Tooby &
Cosmides, 1992, 2015).
An evolutionary psychology approach is
an adaptationist research program, in that re-
searchers test hypotheses about some adaptive
designs of an organism that promote a function-
al output. An adaptation has four properties: (1)
It is a system of reliably developing properties
of a species, (2) it is incorporated into the design
of an organism, (3) it is coordinated with the
structure of the environment, and (4) it causes a
functional outcome (at least increases the prob-
ability of a functional outcome within the envi-
ronment that it evolved; see Tooby & Cosmides,
2015). Adaptations must solve a problem neces-
sary for the reproduction of an organism and can
be understood as the output of the evolutionary
process. Thus, an evolutionary psychology re-
search program is largely about understanding
the adaptations that underlie and explain vari-
ability in human behavior.
To understand any single adaptation, re-
searchers need to generate hypotheses about
VanLange_Book.indb 271VanLange_Book.indb 271 6/30/2020 11:17:38 AM6/30/2020 11:17:38 AM
272 I. PRINCIPLES IN THEORY
the environment of evolutionary adaptedness
(EEA). The EEA “for a given adaptation is the
statistical composite of the enduring selection
pressures or cause-and-effect relationships that
pushed the alleles underlying an adaptation
systematically upward in frequency until they
became species-typical or reached a frequency-
dependent equilibrium” (Tooby & Cosmides,
2015, p. 25). Each adaptation would have a cor-
responding specialized EEA with which the ad-
aptation is coordinated to promote a behavior
that enhanced survival and reproductive suc-
cess within those environmental conditions.
The EEA is not a specific time or place, but it
contains the reliably recurring environmental
challenges and opportunities that gave rise to
the adaptation. Thus, an evolutionary psychol-
ogy program of research generally tests hypoth-
eses about an adaptive psychological mecha-
nism that enables a specific behavior, and uses
knowledge and assumptions about the EEA
to generate hypotheses about how the adapta-
tion (i.e., proximate psychological mechanism)
might work to produce the behavior. Further-
more, this approach can be used to forward hy-
potheses about how an adaptation that evolved
to function for one purpose can be exapted and
applied to a different purpose (Andrews, Gan-
gestad, & Matthews, 2002; Buss, Haselton,
Shackelford, Bleske, & Wakefield, 1998). The
distinction between adaptations and exaptations
may be especially important in understanding
the emergence of indirect reciprocity, and how
the phylogenetically older psychological mech-
anisms that evolved for direct reciprocity could
be exapted to enable indirect reciprocity.
In the following sections, we break down a
system of indirect reciprocity into its most sim-
ple elementsthree persons in a social network.
We discuss specific potential adaptive challeng-
es and opportunities in the EEA for each person
in this network and hypothesize about possible
adaptations that motivate fitness-enhancing be-
haviors to resolve those adaptive problems.
Emergence of Indirect Reciprocity
in the EEA
Humans lived in small hunter–gatherer groups
prior to the advent of agriculture, and it is
thought that many human adaptations for co-
operation have arisen from reliably recurring
opportunities and challenges before and dur-
ing this period. Research comparing humans
to chimps and bonobos suggests that a common
ancestor may have already possessed some key
adaptations for cooperation, such as for direct
reciprocity—to help others who are helpful to
you, and not help those who did not help you
(De Waal, 2008; Jaeggi, Stevens, & Van Schaik,
2010; Warneken & Tomasello, 2006). Adapta-
tions for direct reciprocity could have provided
the foundation for indirect reciprocity to emerge
in human societies.
Direct reciprocity can be an effective strat-
egy to maintain cooperation in small groups
in which people will interact with each other
in the future, can observe everyones behav-
ior, and share a history with each interaction
partner. However, direct reciprocity may face
difficulties in sustaining cooperation in larger
groups, or at least indirect reciprocity would
enable people to more effectively avoid costly
interactions with noncooperators (even during
the first encounter), and to capture even greater
benefits from cooperation by netting not only
direct but also indirect benefits in larger groups.
Furthermore, language was likely a key ability
that amplified the benefits of indirect reciproc-
ity. Language enabled people to communicate
their own social interaction experiences with
many others, and this information could be used
as an input to learn about others’ past behavior,
to update reputations, and to condition coop-
eration (Dunbar, 2004). Thus, as human groups
expanded in size, this increased the frequency
of people having valuable first-encounter in-
teractions and decreased the ability to directly
observe all possible interaction partners. These
changes in the social ecology, along with an
enhanced ability for language, were key con-
ditions that amplified the indirect benefits of
cooperation and paved the way for indirect reci-
procity, thereby enabling natural selection to
shape psychological mechanisms functionally
specialized for this structure of social interac-
tions.
How did indirect reciprocity become a major
force shaping human social behavior? One
critical action in a system of indirect reciproc-
ity involves one person cooperating or not with
another person, and this would have been oc-
VanLange_Book.indb 272VanLange_Book.indb 272 6/30/2020 11:17:38 AM6/30/2020 11:17:38 AM
14. Indirect Reciprocity, Gossip, and Reputation-Based Cooperation 273
curring deep into our ancestral past, and beyond
a common ancestor we share with the other
great apes. Therefore, it is possible that indirect
reciprocity takes hold when people learn about
others’ reputation and condition their behavior
toward others based on that reputation (as op-
posed to previous direct experience or benefits).
As mentioned earlier, humans likely had adap-
tations for direct reciprocity, and these preexist-
ing psychological mechanisms could have been
exapted to acquire input from others’ experi-
ences shared via language. Language enabled
people to communicate their experiences with
many others, and if people conditioned their co-
operation toward the actor based on this input,
then this enabled opportunities for people to
behave in ways to affect their reputations and
receive indirect benefits. This perspective pre-
dicts that at least some adaptations for direct
reciprocity, such as abilities for cheater detec-
tion and welfare tradeoffs (Cosmides, 1989;
Cosmides & Tooby, 1992; Sznycer, Delton,
Robertson, Cosmides, & Tooby, 2019), could
use language as input to condition cooperation
and partner selection.
Once humans were able to share informa-
tion with each other, then use that informa-
tion to condition their cooperation, this form
of structured interactions would have enabled
natural selection to operate on functionally
specialized abilities to (1) condition behavior
to acquire indirect benefits, (2) share informa-
tion to acquire direct benefits (since gossip has
value to interaction partners), and (3) evaluate
gossip and use it to select cooperative partners
and condition cooperation. An important line
of future research may consider understand-
ing what adaptations for direct reciprocity
have been exapted for indirect reciprocity and
which, if any, adaptations are unique to indi-
rect reciprocity. This line of research will need
to clearly delineate the different adaptive chal-
lenges of a system of indirect reciprocity. Fig-
ure 14.2 displays the essential components of
a system of indirect reciprocity and identifies
distinct adaptive challenges that can occur for
different persons within the network. Next, we
discuss the different adaptive problems, some
hypothesized solutions, and relevant research
on these topics.
FIGURE 14.2. Indirect reciprocity and adaptive problems faced by the actor, recipient, and third party.
Recipient
How to capture indirect benefits
How to impose indirect costs/benefits,
receive direct benefits via gossip
Update reputations of actors
Evaluate gossip veracity
Select cooperative partners
Condition cooperation on partner reputation
Cooperate
(or not)
Actor
Third
party
VanLange_Book.indb 273VanLange_Book.indb 273 6/30/2020 11:17:38 AM6/30/2020 11:17:38 AM
274 I. PRINCIPLES IN THEORY
Managing a Cooperative Reputation
(the Actor)
In a system of indirect reciprocity, cooperative
people can capture indirect benefits from others
and avoid ostracism in social interactions, and
this can offset the cost of cooperation. Thus,
conditioning cooperation in ways to acquire
these benefits and avoid these costs could be a
reliably recurring adaptive challenge. A gener-
alized learning system would have difficulty in
solving this problem because indirect benefits
can be incredibly challenging to anticipate, and
the rewards of ones cooperative behavior can
occur a long distance in time from the actual co-
operative behaviors. In fact, to anticipate these
indirect benefits, people would need to under-
stand that the recipient would evaluate their
behavior positively, remember their behavior,
share that information with othersand espe-
cially others with whom the actor would meet
and interact in the future, that the recipients of
the gossip would use that information to form
an evaluation of the actor, that the recipients
of gossip would meet them in the future and
condition their behavior on that information,
and that the benefit received from that future
interaction would be larger than the cost of the
present cooperation. Previous research suggests
that people find this difficult to do, even when
they obtain very explicit information about how
their actions affect the recipient, that the recipi-
ent will communicate with a third person, and
that the third person has a chance to select them
as a partner (and to possibly reward them with
a larger benefit). For example, Wu, Balliet, and
Van Lange (2015b) conducted three studies in
which participants knew (or not) that a recipient
of their generous behavior could gossip about
their behavior to a third person, and that this
third person could use that information to con-
dition his or her own behavior toward them in a
future interaction. Although participants were
more cooperative when they knew their behav-
ior would be gossiped about, this increase in co-
operation was not explained by the participants
expectation that the third person would be kind
to them in a future interaction. Perhaps the
problem of identifying opportunities to cooper-
ate to acquire indirect benefits is better solved
by a functionally specialized ability to use cues
in social interactions that would identify situa-
tions in which people could often acquire great-
er indirect benefits for their cooperation.
Social network structures can provide some
insights about situations that may result in
greater indirect benefits. Recent work has re-
vealed that several characteristics are reliably
recurring in social networks in large-scale
modern societies, as well in small-scale hunter
gatherer societies (Apicella, Marlowe, Fowler,
& Christakis, 2012; Hamilton, Milne, Walker,
Burger, & Brown, 2007; Hill et al., 2011; Mc-
Glohon, Akoglu, & Faloutsos, 2011; Porter,
Mucha, Newman, & Warmbrand, 2005). Two
of these social network properties are that (1)
social networks are “small” and (2) some people
are better connected than others. Specifically,
in most social networks, it takes very few con-
nections to travel from one node to another, so
gossip and reputational information can easily
spread widely throughout a social network. Fur-
thermore, the number of network connections
any single individual has in a social network is
unevenly distributed, with some people having
more network connections than others. If these
properties of social networks did indeed covary
with the probability of actions translating into
indirect benefits, then it might be possible that
natural selection would favor an ability to con-
dition cooperation on the social network prop-
erties of an interaction partner (or any observer
of ones behavior).
In order for this to be possible, there would
need to be cues that reliably covary across social
interactions that could be used to indicate which
situations are more likely to translate into indi-
rect benefits. Cues that a person is either con-
nected to ones social network or that the person
is well connected within one’s social network
could both indicate opportunities for indirect
benefits (Wu et al., 2016c). Previous research
indicates that people extended greater coopera-
tion and generosity to a person who could com-
municate to a future interaction partner (Wu et
al., 2015), and that people were more generous
toward others who could communicate with a
greater number of their possible future interac-
tion partners (Wu et al., 2016c). Thus, initial
evidence provides support for the idea that cues
that covary with network properties may be
used to condition cooperation to acquire indi-
rect benefits. Similarly, Yamagishi, Jin, and Ki-
VanLange_Book.indb 274VanLange_Book.indb 274 6/30/2020 11:17:38 AM6/30/2020 11:17:38 AM
14. Indirect Reciprocity, Gossip, and Reputation-Based Cooperation 275
yonari (1999) suggested that people use group
membership as a cue of a shared social network,
and that cooperation with ingroup members is a
strategy to acquire indirect benefits.
Another possible cue for indirect benefits is
observability. Observers may select or avoid an
actor based on the observed behavior, and ob-
servers may also gossip about what they have
witnessed. Prior research indicates that reduc-
ing anonymity tends to increase cooperation
(Andreoni & Petrie, 2004; Wang et al., 2017),
and researchers have argued that this effect may
be due to reputational concerns (e.g., Sparks &
Barclay, 2013). Watching eyes, such as a pair
of eyes on a computer screen when people are
making decisions, have been found to enhance
generosity and cooperation (Haley & Fessler,
2005). Recent meta-analyses, however, have ei-
ther found no effect of eye cues (Northover, Ped-
ersen, Cohen, & Andrews, 2017) or discovered
only a few situations in which the effect may
be found. For example, eye cues only increase
the probability of giving but not the overall level
of generosity (Nettle et al., 2013), only increase
cooperation after brief exposure (Sparks & Bar-
clay, 2013), and the eyes need to be open and
attentive (Manesi, Van Lange, & Pollet, 2016).
Furthermore, it may be that observability af-
fects cooperation via a different process than
reputation. For example, the presence of others
may serve as a cue of being mutually dependent
on another person (Balliet, Tybur, & Van Lange,
2017). Observability is certainly a central issue
in indirect reciprocity that may have enabled a
simple form of indirect reciprocity prior to the
existence of language and sharing gossip about
others. Future research can attempt to better
understand how anonymity and observability
influence behaviors that are aimed at reputation
management, while controlling and accounting
for alternative explanations.
Two interrelated issues for future research on
reputation management are (1) how to manage
several dimensions of reputation and (2) how
the social ecology shapes the strategies people
use to manage their reputation. Modeling and
experimental research on cooperation has tend-
ed to focus on how people can form cooperative
reputations, but reputations can be multifaceted
and track many other traits and characteristics
of people (e.g., dominance, competence, and
mate value). Recent work in our lab had people
describe their daily-life events about which they
either shared or received gossip (Dores Cruz et
al., 2018). We found that the gossip people re-
ported in their daily lives covers a broad range
of personal characteristics that fall into the six
broad dimensions of personality (i.e., Honesty–
Humility, Emotionality, Extroversion, Agree-
ableness, Conscientiousness, Openness to Ex-
perience) and the major dimensions of social
perception (i.e., warmth, competence, domi-
nance, and morality). One adaptive challenge in
managing ones reputation is to understand how
a behavior would be evaluated along each of
these dimensions, as well as what characteris-
tics would be of value to future interaction part-
ners. Moreover, little is understood about how
reputation management strategies vary across
social ecologies. One possibility is that varia-
tion across societies in the opportunity costs
of forming new relationships (Thomson et al.,
2018) relates to how much people will invest in
a cooperative reputation and which traits people
attempt to communicate to others.
Gossip and Reputation Sharing
(the Recipient)
People engage in actions that directly affect
others’ outcomes, and these actions can spark
recipient evaluations and behaviors in response
to these actions and outcomesa topic that
has been widely studied as moral evaluations,
judgment, and behavior (e.g., Skowronski &
Carlston, 1987). From an evolutionary perspec-
tive, humans may have evolved strategies in
social interactions to increase the chance of fu-
ture benefits and reduce potential future costs.
These strategies would function to shape others’
behavior that can affect one’s outcomes. One
strategy is to directly reciprocate benefits and
costs. For example, when an individual is mis-
treated, he or she may experience anger, which
mobilizes direct confrontation that can function
to adjust the transgressors’ actions in future en-
counters (e.g., become more cooperative; Sell,
Tooby, & Cosmides, 2009). An alternative strat-
egy is to share information with others who will
confer benefits and impose costs on the actor.
For example, a person who is exploited in an in-
teraction can share this experience with a third
party, who then may decide against selecting
VanLange_Book.indb 275VanLange_Book.indb 275 6/30/2020 11:17:38 AM6/30/2020 11:17:38 AM
276 I. PRINCIPLES IN THEORY
the actor as a future cooperative partner. Here
we focus on the adaptive challenges of when
and how to share information about others’ be-
havior (e.g., gossip).
Human communication via language greatly
expands the human capacity to obtain knowl-
edge about others in their social networks.
People often talk about other people, and this
is pervasive across small- and large-scale soci-
eties (see Dunbar, 2004). Previous theory has
suggested that humans may use language stra-
tegically to communicate information about
others, and especially absent third parties. For
example, people who have been treated poorly
by another could directly aggress against that
person or impose harm on him or her, but this is
a strategy that is exposed to the costs of retali-
ation. Instead, people could share information
about that person’s past behavior with others
in the absence of the actor, and the recipients
of that information could then impose costs
on the actor (i.e., indirect aggression; Archer
& Coyne, 2005) or avoid the person in the fu-
ture. Humans may have a functionally special-
ized ability to share information about others in
ways that increase the likelihood that benefits
and costs occur to others because the behavior
could indirectly enhance an individuals repro-
ductive fitness by further enhancing the fitness
of a cooperative ally or reducing the fitness of
a previously uncooperative exchange partner
(Molho, Tybur, Van Lange, & Balliet, 2020).
Talking about others, especially in their ab-
sence, is known as gossip. Unfortunately, gos-
sip has not received extensive research atten-
tion, perhaps because it has been widely viewed
as a trivial social behavior of little consequence.
Thus, when and how people gossip about others
is an understudied topic of research, and this is
unfortunate given that theory of indirect reci-
procity provides a functional account of gossip
in regulating social relationships and that peo-
ple around the world engage in this behavior.
Research over the past few decades has ap-
proached and defined gossip in many different
ways (for an overview of definitions, see Table
14.2). Common themes across these definitions
are that gossip involves communicating infor-
mation about an absent third party (or at least
the third party is not knowledgeable of the in-
formation exchanged). Other approaches have
emphasized that the communicated information
must contain some evaluative content (e.g., Fos-
ter, 2004) and that the communication must be
TABLE 14.2. Def initions of Gossip
Reference Definition of gossip
Dunbar (2004) “conversation about social and personal topics” (p. 109)
Feinberg, Cheng, & Willer (2012) “sharing of evaluative information about an absent third party” (p. 25)
Fine & Rosnow (1978) “a topical assertion about personal qualities or behavior, usually but not
necessarily formulated on the basis of hearsay, that is deemed trivial or
nonessential within the immediate social context” (p. 161)
Fonseca & Peters (2017) the class of speech that transmits information about the behaviors and
attributes of third parties” (p. 254)
Foster (2004) the exchange of personal information (positive or negative) in an
evaluative way (positive or negative) about absent third parties” (p. 83)
Hess & Hagen (2006) “personal conversations about reputation-relevant behavior” (p. 339)
Noon & Delbridge (1993) the process of informally communicating value-laden information
about members of a social setting” (p. 25)
Piazza & Bering (2008) the mechanism by which social information (derived from direct
experience) gets transmitted to absent third parties” (p. 172)
Wittek & Wielers (1998) the provision of information by one person (ego) to another person
(alter) about an absent third person (tertius)” (p. 189)
VanLange_Book.indb 276VanLange_Book.indb 276 6/30/2020 11:17:38 AM6/30/2020 11:17:38 AM
14. Indirect Reciprocity, Gossip, and Reputation-Based Cooperation 277
informal (Noon & Delbridge, 1993). Yet previ-
ous theory of indirect reciprocity does not spec-
ify that the information communicated needs
to be evaluative; it could simply be factual, and
neither should it have to be informal. In fact,
formal evaluations, such as an employer giving
an evaluation of an employee, is an institution-
alization of gossiporganizations understand
the functional benefits of gossip in terms of
selecting and retaining cooperative allies. We
take the perspective that gossip is the sharing
of information about a third party who is not
knowledgeable about the information exchange.
Such gossip does not need to be evaluative; it
can be simply factual and can be either formal
or informal.
There are several adaptive problems of gos-
sip, such as when, how, and with whom to
gossip to impose costs or benefits on an actor.
First, people may gossip in ways that amplify
the benefits and costs to the actor. People may
strategically share gossip with others who will
have future interactions with the target of gos-
sip, and thus may be especially likely to share
gossip with ingroup members or people who are
connected to their social network. People may
share gossip in a way that communicates attri-
butes (e.g., competence, trustworthiness) of the
target that would make him or her especially
(un)desirable as a cooperation partner to others.
People could have an ability to understand when
to share facts versus evaluations, and when to
exaggerate certain evaluations of the target.
Second, people may use gossip as a resource
in exchange for other direct benefits from the
recipients of gossip. From the perspective of
indirect reciprocity, gossip can be a valuable
resource that enables others to select mutually
beneficial, cooperative allies and avoid costly
encounters with noncooperators. Thus, people
should be willing to reciprocate the benefits re-
ceived from gossip. Indeed, previous work has
indicated that exchanging gossip can enhance
trust, reciprocity, and social bonding (Peters,
Jetten, Radova, & Austin, 2017). Furthermore,
sharing highly negative gossip about others could
make the gossiper even more vulnerable and, in-
deed, people tend to share negative gossip only
when they trust the recipient (Ellwardt, Wittek,
& Wielers, 2012; Grosser, Lopez-Kidwell, & La-
bianca, 2010). An interesting possibility is that
sharing negative gossip could especially help to
further build trust and bonding between indi-
viduals.
Third, people may gossip in ways that reduce
the likelihood of exposure and retaliation from
the target of gossip. How would people avoid the
cost of retaliation for being exposed for gossip-
ing? People should be sensitive to the qualities
of the relationship between the recipient and the
target of gossip. In particular, people may be
less likely to share negative gossip about targets
who are genetically related to the recipient or
close to the recipient. Moreover, certain quali-
ties of the recipient may increase the chance of
detection, such as the person being well con-
nected within a social network, untrustworthy,
or highly dominant. In addition, certain quali-
ties of the target, such as how well connected
the target is in his or her social network, and his
or her prestige and standing within the group,
may also increase the chance of detection.
Reputation Updating, Partner Selection,
and Conditional Cooperation
(Third Party)
Previous modeling work has clearly displayed
that sharing information about others’ behavior
in a social network can promote the evolution
of cooperation, and we recognize at least three
adaptive problems for the recipients of gossip
(i.e., third parties): (1) how to update an actor’s
reputation based on new information, (2) how to
use reputation to select and avoid partners, and
(3) how to use others’ reputations to condition
their own cooperation.
Reputation has been discussed and defined in
many ways across different literatures (for some
prominent definitions, see Table 14.3). Across
these definitions, there are some key similari-
ties and differences. Reputation can be thought
to involve information that is shared about a
person among multiple people. The information
is usually about some attribute of the person,
and possibly a corresponding evaluation of that
attribute. Many scholars theorize that reputa-
tion exists at a collective level of analysis and
refers to a shared belief and evaluation of a per-
son (Anderson & Shirako, 2008; Emler, 1990).
However, most research also acknowledges that
an individual’s evaluation of another’s actions
can contribute to shaping that persons reputa-
VanLange_Book.indb 277VanLange_Book.indb 277 6/30/2020 11:17:39 AM6/30/2020 11:17:39 AM
278 I. PRINCIPLES IN THEORY
tion in the mind of the individual, and if shared
with others, then the individuals evaluation
contributes to the collectively shared evalua-
tion of that person. Reputation is meaningfully
tied to social status, prestige, and one’s standing
in a social group (Tedeschi & Melburg, 1984).
Indeed, future research can more clearly delin-
eate the uniqueness of reputation beyond these
existing constructs and situate reputation in the
nomological net of existing constructs in psy-
chology.
One adaptive problem is how to form a repu-
tation of the actor based on his or her actions
toward the recipient. The actor’s reputation
would ideally enable the third party to avoid
being exploited by a noncooperator and facili-
tate selecting cooperative partners for mutually
beneficial exchange. Initial models of indirect
reciprocity tested a simple rule of assessing
reputation called image scoring (Nowak & Sig-
mund, 1998b). To assess an image score, people
just kept track of whether someone was coop-
erative (+1) or noncooperative (1) with others
in prior interactions, then cooperate with others
having a positive image score. However, this
reputation-updating strategy may be too simple
and actually punishes a person who defects (i.e.,
refuses to cooperate) with another person hav-
ing a negative image score. An additional strat-
egy that has been modeled in previous work is
called standing strategy (i.e., assigning a nega-
tive reputation only to someone who fails to
cooperate with a cooperator; see Yamamoto,
Okada, Uchida, & Sasaki, 2017). Although this
strategy places greater demands on memory to
update reputational scores, the standing strat-
egy does not impose punishment on people who
do not cooperate with others who have been un-
cooperative in the past, and thus can distinguish
between justified and unjustified noncoopera-
tors.
Some prior research has tested whether hu-
mans use image scoring or standing strategy to
update reputations. Milinski, Semmann, Bak-
ker, and Krambeck (2001) conducted an ex-
periment to observe how people behave toward
others who cooperate, or not, with a noncoop-
erative person. They found that participants
who did not cooperate with a noncooperative
person were defected on in subsequent inter-
actions. This was taken as evidence that the
people did not take into account the interaction
partner’s reputation but used a simpler updating
rule based on an actors’ behavior (cooperate or
not). In contrast, Bolton, Katok, and Ockenfels
(2005) found that while providing information
about a partner’s past behavior (i.e., image scor-
ing) increased cooperation, there was an even
higher increase in cooperation when partici-
pants were provided with second-order infor-
mation (i.e., the partner’s previous partner’s past
action), which suggests that standing strategy
exists. Thus, it is still uncertain whether people
follow a more complicated reputation-updating
rule like a standing strategy. It has been ar-
gued that image scoring is a simpler heuristic
that avoids the problem of recursive reasoning,
for example, that a person should know his or
her partner’s (say, person A) previous behavior
toward person B, person Bs previous actions
toward person C, person Cs actions toward
person D, person Ds actions toward person E,
and so on. If any single interaction is missing,
then a person cannot adequately use a standing
strategy to update the reputation of a partner,
so this could result in an image scoring heuris-
tic as a useful, though imperfect, shortcut. That
said, an evolved ability to update reputational
information may circumvent these problems by
only searching and using input from first-order
and second-order information, and not attempt
to secure all the information about the history
of interactions (which is likely an insurmount-
able computational problem). Future research
is necessary to better understand how humans
update reputations.
People may also spread false information
about others. There can be possible benefits to
an individual to manipulate gossip to derogate
competitors and enhance ones relative stand-
ing in a social network (Barkow, 1992; Emler,
1990). Moreover, gossip can also contain er-
rors that occur during communication (Hess &
Hagen, 2006). In order for indirect reciprocity
to promote cooperation, people need to be able
to accurately assess others’ reputations. Thus,
one adaptive problem is assessing the verac-
ity of gossip. Hess and Hagen conducted sev-
eral experiments to test cues of gossip verac-
ity and found that people perceive gossip to be
more accurate (1) when they receive the same
information from multiple independent sources
VanLange_Book.indb 278VanLange_Book.indb 278 6/30/2020 11:17:39 AM6/30/2020 11:17:39 AM
14. Indirect Reciprocity, Gossip, and Reputation-Based Cooperation 279
and (2) when there is no detectable conflict or
competition between the gossiper and the target
of gossip. Thus, it seems that people use cues
that enable them to assess the accuracy of gos-
sip, and this could be an adaptation that enabled
more accurate updating of others’ reputations
and better selection of cooperative partners.
Innovative Directions for
Future Research
Social Learning, Reputation,
and Indirect Reciprocity
Societies and groups can have social norms of
cooperation, that is, a shared set of beliefs that
people should cooperate, and that noncoopera-
tion will result in negative evaluations, punish-
ment, and ostracism from group members (Fehr
& Fischbacher, 2004). Learning social norms
and the punishment of counternormative be-
havior may account for why people choose to
cooperate with others who are cooperative and
choose to defect with or ostracize noncoopera-
tors. From this perspective, people copy, mimic,
and learn the common (and successful) behav-
iors they observe from ingroup members (Hen-
rich & Boyd, 2001)and can be biased to es-
pecially learn from prestigious group members
(Chudek, Heller, Birch, & Henrich, 2012). This
approach offers hypotheses about when people
will choose to cooperate, and the motivations
they have for cooperating, that differ from rep-
utation-based indirect reciprocity.
For example, when people are part of a
group that contains a majority of noncoopera-
tive members, a social norm perspective would
predict that people would learn to defect. How-
ever, what would happen in this situation when
a group member interacts with a newcomer to
the group who has a cooperative reputation? To
examine this issue, Romano and Balliet (2017)
assigned participants to a group in which other
group members were always noncooperative
or cooperative with a newcomer to the group.
They also manipulated whether the newcomer
was always cooperative or not in previous in-
teractions. A social norm learning approach
predicts that people should follow the majority
group member behavior, but this research found
that people condition their behavior on their
partner’s past (and expected future) behavior
(i.e., their partner’s reputation). Moreover, when
people did conform to their group members’ be-
havior (i.e., behaving as though conforming to
a social norm), they reported doing so because
they were concerned about their reputation in
the group. Thus, people were conforming to
group member behavior in order to avoid being
negatively evaluated by ingroup members.
These findings suggest that the psychological
mechanisms of indirect reciprocity may have
greater influence on decisions to cooperate than
the psychological mechanisms underlying the
TABLE 14.3. Def initions of Reputation
Reference Definition of reputation
Anderson & Shirako (2008) the set of beliefs, perceptions, and evaluations a community forms about
one of its members” (p. 320)
Emler (1990) that set of judgments a community makes about the personal qualities of
one of its members” (p. 171)
Milinski (2016) the current standing the person has gained from previous investments or
refusal of investments in helping others” (p. 1)
Stiff & Van Vugt (2008) “socially shared information about a potential interaction partner” (p. 156)
Whitmeyer (2000) “an attribute attached to actors (or perhaps objects) that signals that they
are more or less likely to be desirable for some sort of interaction than those
without the attribute” (p. 189)
Wu, Balliet, & Van Lange
(2016b)
“a set of collective beliefs, perceptions, or evaluative judgments about
someone among members within a community” (p. 351)
VanLange_Book.indb 279VanLange_Book.indb 279 6/30/2020 11:17:39 AM6/30/2020 11:17:39 AM
280 I. PRINCIPLES IN THEORY
learning of social norms. Future research can
further test the contrasting predictions of theo-
ries about social norms and indirect reciprocity,
with a focus on distinguishing the psychologi-
cal mechanisms that are hypothesized to under-
lie each of these phenomena.
One line of inquiry can test to what extent
a general learning ability can account for how
people cooperate to acquire indirect benefits.
For example, humans could have a general
learning ability that identifies when their be-
havior can translate into good or bad reputa-
tional outcomes, and so indirect benefits and
costs. However, reputational consequences of
ones current actions often occur in the distant
future, and this presents a challenge for leaning
about how one can adjust his or her behavior to
maintain a cooperative reputation. Instead, hu-
mans may have decision rules or heuristics that
help them solve exactly this problem. People
may use cues that are reliably associated with
indirect costs and benefits, then condition their
behavior on these cues. Future research can
contrast a reinforcement learning account of
reputation management, with an alternative ac-
count of functionally specialized decision rules
that rely on cues that can be associated with in-
direct benefits.
Indirect Reciprocity from
a Developmental Perspective
As we discussed earlier, humans may have
evolved abilities that enable reputation-based
indirect reciprocity, and this proposition has
inspired several researchers to examine when
these abilities emerge through development.
Field research making observations at a school
playground has documented that 5- to 6-year-
old children are more likely to receive help after
having previously helped another child (Kato-
Shimizu, Onishi, Kanazawa, & Hinobayashi,
2013). Such notable field observations present
immense challenges in ruling out alternative
interpretations, such as direct reciprocity and
the effects of the history of the relationships be-
tween the children.
However, lab research has also documented
that young children display indirect reciprocity.
Olson and Spelk (2008) presented 3½-year-olds
a puppet story with a protagonist who had to
decide how to divide resources among other
puppets. The participants learned that one of
the other puppets had previously helped other
puppets, while another puppet decided against
helping someone in the past. They found that
the children recommended that the protago-
nist give more to the puppet that had previ-
ously been helpful, compared to the puppet that
did not help previously, suggesting that chil-
dren at this age engage in indirect reciprocity.
Similarly, Kenward and Dahl (2011) found that
4½-year-olds, but not 3-year-olds, would decide
to give more resources to a puppet that had pre-
viously helped another puppet, compared to a
puppet that was a hindrance to another puppet.
Importantly, across both studies, children only
distributed resources as would be expected ac-
cording to indirect reciprocity when they were
forced to decide how to distribute unequal re-
sources (e.g., three cookies between two per-
sons). However, when they could divide the re-
sources equally (e.g., two cookies between two
persons), they preferred dividing the resources
equally between helpers and nonhelpers. Such
field and lab studies suggest that children at a
young age, and potentially even 3 years old, are
motivated to give more benefits to others whom
they observed to be helpful to others in previous
occasions.
Interestingly, the cognitive and motivational
mechanisms of indirect reciprocity may emerge
even earlier in development. Previous research
has found that even 10-month-old infants seem
to expect third parties to behave positively to-
ward someone who has behaved in an egalitar-
ian way in a previous interaction, compared to
someone who behaved unfairly (Meristo & Su-
rian, 2013). There is a need for future research
along these lines on the development of specific
cognitive and motivational abilities that under-
lie indirect reciprocity.
Do Reputations Transcend
Group Boundaries?
Social networks often contain clusters of indi-
viduals who have strong ties to each other, and
these clusters can be considered groups. Yam-
agishi and colleagues (1999) have claimed that
reputational benefits of cooperation may be
contained within groups. According to a bound-
VanLange_Book.indb 280VanLange_Book.indb 280 6/30/2020 11:17:39 AM6/30/2020 11:17:39 AM
14. Indirect Reciprocity, Gossip, and Reputation-Based Cooperation 281
ed generalized reciprocity perspective, groups
contain a system of reputation-based indirect
reciprocity, and humans have evolved a decision
heuristic to be more cooperative with ingroup
members than with outgroup members, in order
to enhance their cooperative reputation and to
avoid being ostracized from the group. Previ-
ous research using minimal group paradigm
has supported this claim through the observa-
tion that ingroup favoritism in cooperation only
occurs when people have common knowledge
of each other’s group membership (Balliet, Wu,
& De Dreu, 2014; Yamagishi et al., 1999). When
participants have unilateral knowledge of group
membership (i.e., participants knew their part-
ners’ group membership, but also learned that
their partners did not know their own group
membership), they could not gain reputational
benefitscosts from their behavior, and so they
did not discriminate in cooperation between
ingroup and outgroup members. A recent me-
ta-analysis of the literature on ingroup favorit-
ism indeed found that people only cooperated
more with ingroup than with outgroup mem-
bers when there was common knowledge, but
this ingroup favoritism completely disappeared
in the unilateral knowledge condition (Balliet
et al., 2014). This work is complemented by re-
search showing that 5-year-old children invest
in a positive reputation with ingroup, but not
outgroup, members (Engelmann, Over, Her-
rmann, & Tomasello, 2013).
Theory and research suggest that reputation-
al benefits of cooperation are contained within
groups, or at least that people have a reputa-
tion management strategy that is conditional on
group membership. However, research support-
ing this view has mostly relied on the common
knowledge paradigm to manipulate whether
actions can have reputational consequences.
Other research using different methodologies
has resulted in the conclusion that people care
about their reputation when interacting with
both ingroup and outgroup members (Romano,
Balliet, & Wu, 2017; Semmann, Krambeck,
& Milinski, 2005). Romano, Balliet, and Wu
(2017) conducted five studies in which they
manipulated both partner group membership
(using minimal and natural groups) and cues of
reputation (e.g., anonymity, gossip) via several
methods, and found that reputation promoted
cooperation during interactions with both in-
group and outgroup members. Additionally, a
large-scale study across 17 societies attempted
to replicate the previous work by Yamagishi and
colleagues (1999) testing how common/unilat-
eral knowledge affected ingroup favoritism in
cooperation (Romano, Balliet, Yamagishi, &
Liu, 2017). This study manipulated partner na-
tionality (own country vs. one of 16 other coun-
tries) and common (vs. unilateral) knowledge
of partner group membership, and found that
these two factors did not interact to predict co-
operation as would be expected by the bounded
generalized reciprocity theory. However, com-
mon knowledge (and also reputational benefits)
promoted cooperation with both ingroup and
outgroup members.
It is unclear why these studies result in in-
consistent findings, and there is a need for fu-
ture work to closely examine how reputation
and reputational benefits can generalize across
groups. This issue can inform why people might
discriminate in favor of their ingroup, which
can not only result in benefits for the ingroup
but also provoke conflict between groups (De
Dreu, & Balliet, & Halevy, 2014). Furthermore,
if reputation transcends group boundaries, then
it may be wielded as a tool to reduce intergroup
discrimination.
Individual Differences
in Reputation Management
Although reputation-based indirect reciprocity
could result in universal human adaptations,
there may be individual differences in how
these mechanisms would operate to produce
behavior. For example, people may not display
similar levels of concern for their reputations,
and they may not invariably cooperate in re-
sponse to cues that their behavior can lead to
indirect benefits. Some personality traits (e.g.,
social value orientation, prevention focus, and
chronic public self-awareness) are likely to ac-
count for potential variation in reputation man-
agement.
There exist stable individual differences in
the weighting of own and others’ outcomes dur-
ing interdependent decision-making tasks, with
some people (e.g., proselfs) only valuing their
own welfare, and other people (e.g., prosocials)
VanLange_Book.indb 281VanLange_Book.indb 281 6/30/2020 11:17:39 AM6/30/2020 11:17:39 AM
282 I. PRINCIPLES IN THEORY
displaying a positive valuation of both self and
others’ outcomes (Van Lange, 1999; Van Lange,
Otten, De Bruin, & Joireman, 1997). While pro-
socials tend to be generally more cooperative
than proselfs in both economic games and real-
world situations (Balliet, Parks, & Joireman,
2009; Van Lange, Schippers, & Balliet, 2011),
proselfs have been found to be strategically
more cooperative in situations with cues that
their behavior can lead to potential future in-
direct benefits (e.g., the presence of third-party
observers or potential for gossip), compared to
an anonymous situation (Feinberg, Willer, Stel-
lar, & Kellner, 2012; Simpson & Willer, 2008;
Wu et al., 2015; Wu, Balliet, & Van Lange,
2016c). Thus, proself individuals can be more
strongly influenced to cooperate when their
reputations are at stake.
Individuals differences in prevention focus
ones general tendency to minimize negative
outcomes and prevent losses (Higgins, 1998)
can also shape strategies of reputation manage-
ment. Some initial evidence reveals that preven-
tion-focused individuals tend to generally show
greater concern for their reputations (Cavazza,
Guidetti, & Pagliaro, 2015) and also donate
more money when they are exposed to subtle
cues of watching eyes (Pfattheicher, 2015). In
addition, people with a strong chronic public
self-awareness also tend to be behave more pro-
socially in response to cues of being watched
(Pfattheicher & Keller, 2015). While some
previous research has been done on individual
differences in gossip (Nevo, Nevo, & Derech-
Zehavi, 1993), very little research has examined
individual differences in the context of indirect
reciprocity, and several candidate traits include
Honesty–Humility, Dark Triad, Forgivingness,
and Revengefulness (see Thielmann, Spadaro,
& Balliet, 2020).
Conclusions
Humans possess a remarkable ability to coor-
dinate and cooperate to produce public goods.
Biologists and psychologists believe that this
ability has its roots in the phylogeny of our
species. Indeed, natural selection can favor
cooperative strategies that result in direct and
indirect benefits of cooperation. Thus, indirect
reciprocity may have shaped human abilities to
evaluate others’ behavior (e.g., person percep-
tion, moral judgment) and to engage in certain
social behaviors (e.g., reputation and impression
management, partner selection, and conditional
cooperation) to acquire these benefits. In this
chapter, we have discussed several fitness-rel-
evant adaptive problems (e.g., capturing indi-
rect benefits, strategically sharing gossip, and
selecting cooperative partners and avoiding ex-
ploitation by free riders) that can occur when
social interactions are structured according to
indirect reciprocity. Specifying these adaptive
problems can be useful in generating hypoth-
eses about how the mind might work to solve
these problems, and we proposed several pos-
sibilities, many of which require future research
and empirical scrutiny.
Several agent-based models discussed in
this chapter support the idea that indirect reci-
procity could have influenced the evolution of
human cooperation. And here we reported an
abundance of evidence, from both the field and
lab, that people engage in behaviors that can
be recognized as indirect reciprocity. We be-
lieve the most exciting next steps on this topic
involve identifying the proximate psychologi-
cal processes underlying these behaviors. In
this regard, bridging evolutionary models of
indirect reciprocity and social psychology
should be exceptionally useful in generating
hypotheses to test in behavioral experiments.
Specifically, psychologists can use these evo-
lutionary models of ultimate mechanisms as
inspiration to develop and test hypotheses
about the proximal cognitive and motivational
processes that underlie the human ability for
indirect reciprocity. Another topic may focus
on the broader circumstances that may limit
or facilitate the workings of indirect reciproc-
ity. For example, it is unclear whether people
cooperate to secure a good reputation among
outgroup members. Such issues could illumi-
nate and extend classic topics in social psy-
chology, such as stereotyping, discrimination,
and impression formation. We predict that the
next decade will witness a cascade of work on
gossip, reputation, and reputation-based coop-
eration, thereby increasing our understanding
about how humans evolved to become such a
cooperative species.
VanLange_Book.indb 282VanLange_Book.indb 282 6/30/2020 11:17:39 AM6/30/2020 11:17:39 AM
14. Indirect Reciprocity, Gossip, and Reputation-Based Cooperation 283
REFERENCES
Abrahao, B., Parigi, P., Gupta, A., & Cook, K. S.
(2017). Reputation offsets trust judgments based
on social biases among Airbnb users. Proceedings
of the National Academy of Sciences of the USA,
114, 98489853.
Akçay, Ç., Reed, V. A., Campbell, S. E., Templeton,
C. N., & Beecher, M. D. (2010). Indirect reciproc-
ity: Song sparrows distrust aggressive neighbours
based on eavesdropping. Animal Behaviour, 80,
1041–1047.
Alexander, R. (2017). The biology of moral systems.
New York: Routledge. (Original work published
1987)
Anderson, C., & Shirako, A. (2008). Are individuals’
reputations related to their history of behavior?
Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 94,
320–333.
Andreoni, J., & Petrie, R. (2004). Public goods ex-
periments without confidentiality: A glimpse into
fund-raising. Journal of Public Economics, 88,
16051623.
Andrews, P. W., Gangestad, S. W., & Matthews,
D. (2002). Adaptationismhow to carry out an
exaptationist program. Behavioral and Brain Sci-
ences, 25, 489–504.
Apicella, C. L., Marlowe, F. W., Fowler, J. H., &
Christakis, N. A. (2012). Social networks and
cooperation in hunter–gatherers. Nature, 481,
497–501.
Archer, J., & Coyne, S. M. (2005). An integrated
review of indirect, relational, and social aggres-
sion. Personality and Social Psychology Review,
9, 212230.
Axelrod, R. (1984). The evolution of cooperation.
New York: Basic Books.
Balliet, D., Parks, C., & Joireman, J. (2009). Social
value orientation and cooperation in social dilem-
mas: A meta-analysis. Group Processes and In-
tergroup Relations, 12, 533547.
Balliet, D., Tybur, J. M., & Van Lange, P. A. M.
(2017). Functional interdependence theory: An
evolutionary account of social situations. Person-
ality and Social Psychology Review, 21, 361–388.
Balliet, D., Wu, J., & De Dreu, C. K. W. (2014). In-
group favoritism in cooperation: A meta-analysis.
Psychological Bulletin, 140, 1556–1581.
Barkow, J. H. (1992). Beneath new culture is old
psychology: Gossip and social stratification. In J.
H. Barkow, L. Cosmides, & J. Tooby (Eds.), The
adapted mind: Evolutionary psychology and the
generation of culture (pp. 627637). New York:
Oxford University Press.
Bolton, G. E., Katok, E., & Ockenfels, A. (2005). Co-
operation among strangers with limited informa-
tion about reputation. Journal of Public Econom-
ics, 89, 14571468.
Boyd, R., & Richerson, P. J. (1989). The evolution of
indirect reciprocity. Social Networks, 11, 213–236.
Bshary, R., & Grutter, A. S. (2006). Image scoring
and cooperation in a cleaner fish mutualism. Na-
ture, 441, 975–978.
Buss, D. M., Haselton, M. G., Shackelford, T. K.,
Bleske, A. L., & Wakefield, J. C. (1998). Adapta-
tions, exaptations, and spandrels. American Psy-
chologist, 53, 533–548.
Cavazza, N., Guidetti, M., & Pagliaro, S. (2015).
Who cares for reputation?: Individual differences
and concern for reputation. Current Psychology,
34, 164 176.
Chudek, M., Heller, S., Birch, S., & Henrich, J.
(2012). Prestige-biased cultural learning: By-
stander’s differential attention to potential mod-
els influences childrens learning. Evolution and
Human Behavior, 33, 46–56.
Confer, J. C., Easton, J. A., Fleischman, D. S., Goetz,
C. D., Lewis, D. M., Perilloux, C., et al. (2010).
Evolutionary psychology: Controversies, ques-
tions, prospects, and limitations. American Psy-
chologist, 65, 110126.
Cosmides, L. (1989). The logic of social exchange:
Has natural selection shaped how humans rea-
son?: Studies with the Wason selection task. Cog-
nition, 31, 187276.
Cosmides, L., Barrett, H. C., & Tooby, J. (2010).
Adaptive specializations, social exchange, and the
evolution of human intelligence. Proceedings of
the National Academy of Sciences of the USA, 107,
9007–9014.
Cosmides, L., & Tooby, J. (1992). Cognitive adap-
tations for social exchange. In J. H. Barkow, L.
Cosmides, & J. Tooby (Eds.), The adapted mind:
Evolutionary psychology and the generation of
culture (pp. 163–228). Oxford, UK: Oxford Uni-
versity Press.
Cosmides, L., & Tooby, J. (2013). Evolutionary
psychology: New perspectives on cognition and
motivation. Annual Review of Psychology, 64,
201229.
Dawes, R. M. (1980). Social dilemmas. Annual Re-
view of Psychology, 31, 169–193.
De Dreu, C. K. W. (2010). Social conflict: The emer-
gence and consequences of struggle and negotia-
tion. In S. T. Fiske, D. T. Gilbert, & L. Gardner
(Eds.), Handbook of social psychology (pp. 983
1023). New York: Wiley.
De Dreu, C. K. W., Balliet, D. P., & Halevy, N.
(2014). Parochial cooperation in humans: Forms
and functions of self-sacrifice in intergroup con-
flict. In A. Elliot (Ed.), Advances in motivational
science (Vol. 1, pp. 148). New York: Elsevier.
VanLange_Book.indb 283VanLange_Book.indb 283 6/30/2020 11:17:39 AM6/30/2020 11:17:39 AM
284 I. PRINCIPLES IN THEORY
De Waal, F. B. (2008). Putting the altruism back into
altruism: The evolution of empathy. Annual Re-
view of Psychology, 59, 279–300.
Delton, A. W., Krasnow, M. M., Cosmides, L., &
Tooby, J. (2011). Evolution of direct reciprocity
under uncertainty can explain human generos-
ity in one-shot encounters. Proceedings of the
National Academy of Sciences of the USA, 108,
13335–13340.
Dores Cruz, T., Thielmann, I., Balliet, D., Righetti,
F., Beersma, B., Molho, C., et al. (2020). Gossip in
daily life [Raw data], VU Amsterdam.
dos Santos, M., & Wedekind, C. (2015). Reputation
based on punishment rather than generosity allows
for evolution of cooperation in sizable groups.
Evolution and Human Behavior, 36, 5964.
Dunbar, R. I. M. (2004). Gossip in evolutionary
perspective. Review of General Psychology, 8,
100110.
Ellwardt, L., Wittek, R., & Wielers, R. (2012). Talk-
ing about the boss effects of generalized and in-
terpersonal trust on workplace gossip. Group and
Organization Management, 37, 521549.
Emler, N. (1990). A social psychology of reputa-
tion. European Review of Social Psychology, 1,
171–193.
Engelmann, D., & Fischbacher, U. (2009). Indirect
reciprocity and strategic reputation building in an
experimental helping game. Games and Econom-
ic Behavior, 67, 399407.
Engelmann, J. M., Over, H., Herrmann, E., & Toma-
sello, M. (2013). Young children care more about
their reputation with ingroup members and po-
tential reciprocators. Developmental Science, 16,
952–958.
Fehr, E., & Fischbacher, U. (2004). Social norms and
human cooperation. Trends in Cognitive Sciences,
8, 185–190.
Fehr, E., Fischbacher, U., & Gächter, S. (2002).
Strong reciprocity, human cooperation, and the
enforcement of social norms. Human Nature, 13,
1–25.
Feinberg, M., Cheng, J. T., & Willer, R. (2012). Gos-
sip as an effective and low-cost form of punish-
ment. Behavioral and Brain Sciences, 35, 25.
Feinberg, M., Willer, R., & Schultz, M. (2014). Gos-
sip and ostracism promote cooperation in groups.
Psychological Science, 25, 656664.
Feinberg, M., Willer, R., Stellar, J., & Keltner, D.
(2012). The virtues of gossip: Reputational infor-
mation sharing as prosocial behavior. Journal of
Personality and Social Psychology, 102, 1015
1030.
Fine, G. A., & Rosnow, R. L. (1978). Gossip, gossip-
ers, gossiping. Personality and Social Psychology
Bulletin, 4, 161168.
Fonseca, M. A., & Peters, K. (2017). Will any gossip
do?: Gossip does not need to be perfectly accurate
to promote trust. Games and Economic Behavior,
107, 253281.
Foster, E. K. (2004). Research on gossip: Taxonomy,
methods, and future directions. Review of Gen-
eral Psychology, 8, 7899.
Giardini, F., Paolucci, M., Villatoro, D., & Conte, R.
(2014). Punishment and gossip: Sustaining coop-
eration in a public goods game. In B. Kamiński &
Grzegorz Koloch (Eds.), Advances in social simu-
lation (pp. 107–118). Berlin, Germany: Springer.
Giardini, F., & Vilone, D. (2016). Evolution of gos-
sip-based indirect reciprocity on a bipartite net-
work. Scientific Reports, 6, Article No. 37931.
Gintis, H., Smith, E. A., & Bowles, S. (2001). Costly
signaling and cooperation. Journal of Theoretical
Biology, 213, 103119.
Grosser, T. J., Lopez-Kidwell, V., & Labianca, G.
(2010). A social network analysis of positive and
negative gossip in organizational life. Group and
Organization Management, 35, 177212.
Haley, K. J., & Fessler, D. M. (2005). Nobody’s
watching?: Subtle cues affect generosity in an
anonymous economic game. Evolution and
Human Behavior, 26, 245–256.
Hamilton, M. J., Milne, B. T., Walker, R. S., Burger,
O., & Brown, J. H. (2007). The complex structure
of huntergatherer social networks. Proceedings
of the Royal Society of London B: Biological Sci-
ences, 274, 2195–2203.
Hamilton, W. D. (1964). The genetical evolution of
social behaviour II. Journal of Theoretical Biol-
og y, 7, 1752.
Henrich, J., & Boyd, R. (2001). Why people punish
defectors: Weak conformist transmission can sta-
bilize costly enforcement of norms in cooperative
dilemmas. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 208,
7989.
Hess, N. H., & Hagen, E. H. (2006). Psychological
adaptations for assessing gossip veracity. Human
Nature, 17, 337–354.
Higgins, E. T. (1998). Promotion and prevention:
Regulatory focus as a motivational principle. Ad-
vances in Experimental Social Psychology, 30,
1–46.
Hill, K. R., Walker, R. S., Božičević, M., Eder,
J., Headland, T., Hewlett, B., et al. (2011). Co-
residence patterns in hunter–gatherer societies
show unique human social structure. Science,
331, 1286–1289.
Jaeggi, A. V., Stevens, J. M., & Van Schaik, C. P.
(2010). Tolerant food sharing and reciprocity is
precluded by despotism among bonobos but not
chimpanzees. American Journal of Physical An-
thropology, 143, 41–51.
VanLange_Book.indb 284VanLange_Book.indb 284 6/30/2020 11:17:39 AM6/30/2020 11:17:39 AM
14. Indirect Reciprocity, Gossip, and Reputation-Based Cooperation 285
Kato-Shimizu, M., Onishi, K., Kanazawa, T., & Hi-
nobayashi, T. (2013). Preschool children’s behav-
ioral tendency toward social indirect reciprocity.
PLOS ONE, 8, e70915.
Kenward, B., & Dahl, M. (2011). Preschoolers dis-
tribute scarce resources according to the moral
valence of recipients’ previous actions. Develop-
mental Psychology, 47, 10541064.
Khadjavi, M. (2016). Indirect reciprocity and chari-
table giving—evidence from a field experiment.
Management Science, 63, 3708–3717.
Kollock, P. (1993). An eye for an eye leaves every-
one blind: Cooperation and accounting systems.
American Sociological Review, 58, 768–786.
Komorita, S. S., & Parks, C. D. (1995). Interpersonal
relations: Mixed-motive interaction. Annual Re-
view of Psychology, 46, 183–207.
Leimar, O., & Hammerstein, P. (2001). Evolution
of cooperation through indirect reciprocity. Pro-
ceedings of the Royal Society of London B: Bio-
logical Sciences, 268, 745753.
Ma, L. K., Tunney, R. J., & Ferguson, E. (2017). Does
gratitude enhance prosociality?: A meta-analytic
review. Psychological Bulletin, 143, 601635.
Manesi, Z., Van Lange, P. A. M., & Pollet, T. (2016).
Eyes wide open: Only eyes that pay attention pro-
mote prosocial behavior. Evolutionary Psychol-
ogy, 14, 1–15.
McCullough, M. E., Kurzban, R., & Tabak, B. A.
(2013). Putting revenge and forgiveness in an evo-
lutionary context. Behavioral and Brain Sciences,
36, 4158.
McGlohon, M., Akoglu, L., & Faloutsos, C. (2011).
Statistical properties of social networks. In C. C.
Aggarwal (Ed.), Social network data analytics
(pp. 17–42). New York: Springer.
Meristo, M., & Surian, L. (2013). Do infants detect
indirect reciprocity? Cognition, 129, 102–113.
Milinski, M. (2016). Reputation, a universal cur-
rency for human social interactions. Philosophi-
cal Transactions of the Royal Society of London
B: Biological Sciences, 371, 20150100.
Milinski, M., Semmann, D., Bakker, T. C., & Kram-
beck, H. J. (2001). Cooperation through indirect
reciprocity: Image scoring or standing strategy?
Proceedings of the Royal Society of London B:
Biological Sciences, 268, 24952501.
Milinski, M., Semmann, D., & Krambeck, H. J.
(2002). Reputation helps solve the “tragedy of the
commons.” Nature, 415, 424426.
Molho, C., Tybur, J. M., Van Lange, P. A. M., & Bal-
liet, D. (2020). Direct and indirect punishment in
daily life. Manuscript under review.
Nettle, D., Harper, Z., Kidson, A., Stone, R., Penton-
Voak, I. S., & Bateson, M. (2013). The watching
eyes effect in the Dictator Game: It’s not how
much you give, it’s being seen to give something.
Evolution and Human Behavior, 34, 3540.
Nevo, O., Nevo, B., & Derech-Zehavi, A. (1993). The
development of the tendency to gossip question-
naire: Construct and concurrent validation for a
sample of Israeli college students. Educational
and Psychological Measurement, 53, 973981.
Noon, M., & Delbridge, R. (1993). News from behind
my hand: Gossip in organizations. Organization
Studies, 14, 23–36.
Northover, S. B., Pedersen, W. C., Cohen, A. B., &
Andrews, P. W. (2017). Artificial surveillance
cues do not increase generosity: Two meta-analy-
ses. Evolution and Human Behavior, 38, 144–153.
Nowak, M. A. (2006). Five rules for the evolution of
cooperation. Science, 314, 15601563.
Nowak, M., & Sigmund, K. (1993). A strategy of
winstay, loseshift that outperforms tit-for-tat
in the Prisoner’s Dilemma Game. Nature, 364,
56–58.
Nowak, M. A., & Sigmund, K. (1998a). The dynam-
ics of indirect reciprocity. Journal of Theoretical
Biology, 194, 561574.
Nowak, M. A., & Sigmund, K. (1998b). Evolution
of indirect reciprocity by image scoring. Nature,
393, 573577.
Ohtsuki, H., & Iwasa, Y. (2006). The leading eight:
Social norms that can maintain cooperation by in-
direct reciprocity. Journal of Theoretical Biology,
239, 435–444.
Olson, K. R., & Spelke, E. S. (2008). Foundations
of cooperation in young children. Cognition, 108,
222–231.
Peters, K., Jetten, J., Radova, D., & Austin, K. (2017).
Gossiping about deviance: Evidence that deviance
spurs the gossip that builds bonds. Psychological
Science, 28, 16101619.
Pfattheicher, S. (2015). A regulatory focus perspec-
tive on reputational concerns: The impact of pre-
vention-focused self-regulation. Motivation and
Emotion, 39, 932942.
Pfattheicher, S., & Keller, J. (2015). The watching
eyes phenomenon: The role of a sense of being
seen and public self-awareness. European Jour-
nal of Social Psychology, 45, 560–566.
Pfeiffer, T., Rutte, C., Killingback, T., Taborsky, M.,
& Bonhoeffer, S. (2005). Evolution of cooperation
by generalized reciprocity. Proceedings of the
Royal Society of London B: Biological Sciences,
272, 11151120.
Piazza, J., & Bering, J. M. (2008). Concerns about
reputation via gossip promote generous alloca-
tions in an economic game. Evolution and Human
Behavior, 29, 172178.
Porter, M. A., Mucha, P. J., Newman, M. E., &
Warmbrand, C. M. (2005). A network analysis of
VanLange_Book.indb 285VanLange_Book.indb 285 6/30/2020 11:17:39 AM6/30/2020 11:17:39 AM
286 I. PRINCIPLES IN THEORY
committees in the US House of Representatives.
Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences
of the USA, 102, 7057–7062.
Pruitt, D. G., & Kimmel, M. J. (1977). Twenty years
of experimental gaming: Critique, synthesis, and
suggestions for the future. Annual Review of Psy-
chology, 28, 363–392.
Rand, D. G., & Nowak, M. A. (2013). Human cooper-
ation. Trends in Cognitive Sciences, 17, 413425.
Richerson, P., Baldini, R., Bell, A., Demps, K., Frost,
K., Hillis, V., et al. (2016). Cultural group selec-
tion plays an essential role in explaining human
cooperation: A sketch of the evidence. Behavioral
and Brain Sciences, 39, e30.
Roberts, G. (2008). Evolution of direct and indirect
reciprocity. Proceedings of the Royal Society of
London B: Biological Sciences, 275, 173179.
Romano, A., & Balliet, D. (2017). Reciprocity out-
performs conformity to promote cooperation.
Psychological Science, 28, 14901502.
Romano, A., Balliet, D., & Wu, J. (2017). Unbounded
indirect reciprocity: Is reputation-based coopera-
tion bounded by group membership? Journal of
Experimental Social Psychology, 71, 59 67.
Romano, A., Balliet, D., Yamagishi, T., & Liu, J. H.
(2017). Parochial trust and cooperation across 17
societies. Proceedings of the National Academy of
Sciences of the USA, 114, 12702–12707.
Sasaki, T., Okada, I., & Nakai, Y. (2017). The evolu-
tion of conditional moral assessment in indirect
reciprocity. Scientific Reports, 7, Article No. 41870.
Seinen, I., & Schram, A. (2006). Social status and
group norms: Indirect reciprocity in a repeated
helping experiment. European Economic Review,
50, 581602.
Sell, A., Tooby, J., & Cosmides, L. (2009). Formida-
bility and the logic of human anger. Proceedings
of the National Academy of Sciences of the USA,
106, 1507315078.
Semmann, D., Krambeck, H. J., & Milinski, M.
(2005). Reputation is valuable within and outside
one’s own social group. Behavioral Ecology and
Sociobiology, 57, 611616.
Simpson, B., & Willer, R. (2008). Altruism and in-
direct reciprocity: The interaction of person and
situation in prosocial behavior. Social Psychology
Quarterly, 71, 37–52.
Skowronski, J. J., & Carlston, D. E. (1987). Social
judgment and social memory: The role of cue di-
agnosticity in negativity, positivity, and extremity
biases. Journal of Personality and Social Psy-
chology, 52, 689699.
Sparks, A., & Barclay, P. (2013). Eye images increase
generosity, but not for long: The limited effect of
a false cue. Evolution and Human Behavior, 34,
317322.
Stanca, L. (2009). Measuring indirect reciprocity:
Whose back do we scratch? Journal of Economic
Psychology, 30, 190202.
Stiff, C., & Van Vugt, M. (2008). The power of repu-
tations: The role of third party information in the
admission of new group members. Group Dynam-
ics: Theory, Research, and Practice, 12, 155166.
Sznycer, D., Delton, A. W., Robertson, T. E., Cos-
mides, L., & Tooby, J. (2019). The ecological ra-
tionality of helping others: Potential helpers in-
tegrate cues of recipients’ need and willingness
to sacrifice. Evolution and Human Behavior, 40,
3445.
Tedeschi, J. T., & Melburg, V. (1984). Impression
management and influence in the organization. In
S. B. Bacharach & E. J. Lawler (Eds.), Research in
the sociology of organizations (Vol. 3, pp. 31–58).
Greenwich, CT: JAI.
Thielmann, I., Spadaro, G., & Balliet, D. (2020).
Personality and prosocial behavior: A theoretical
framework and meta-analysis. Psychological Bul-
letin, 146(1), 30 90.
Thomson, R., Yuki, M., Talhelm, T., Schug, J., Kito,
M., Ayanian, A. H., et al. (2018). Relational mobil-
ity predicts social behaviors in 39 countries and is
tied to historical farming and threat. Proceedings
of the National Academy of Sciences of the USA,
115, 7521–7526.
Tooby, J., & Cosmides, L. (1992). The psychologi-
cal foundations of culture. In J. H. Barkow, L.
Cosmides, & J. Tooby (Eds.), The adapted mind:
Evolutionary psychology and the generation of
culture (pp. 19–136). New York: Oxford Univer-
sity Press.
Tooby, J., & Cosmides, L. (1996). Friendship and the
banker’s paradox: Other pathways to the evolution
of adaptations for altruism. In W. G. Runciman,
J. M. Smith, & R. I. M. Dunbar (Eds.), Proceed-
ings of the British Academy: Vol. 88. Evolution
of social behaviour patterns in primates and
man (pp. 119–143). New York: Oxford University
Press.
Tooby, J., & Cosmides, L. (2015). The theoretical
foundations of evolutionary psychology. In D. M.
Buss (Ed.), The handbook of evolutionary psy-
chology: Vol. 1. Foundations (2nd ed., pp. 387).
Hoboken, NJ: Wiley.
Trivers, R. L. (1971). The evolution of reciprocal al-
truism. Quarterly Review of Biology, 46, 3557.
Van Apeldoorn, J., & Schram, A. (2016). Indirect
reciprocity: A field experiment. PLOS ONE, 11,
e0152076.
Van Lange, P. A. M. (1999). The pursuit of joint out-
comes and equality in outcomes: An integrative
model of social value orientation. Journal of Per-
sonality and Social Psychology, 77, 337349.
VanLange_Book.indb 286VanLange_Book.indb 286 6/30/2020 11:17:39 AM6/30/2020 11:17:39 AM
14. Indirect Reciprocity, Gossip, and Reputation-Based Cooperation 287
Van Lange, P. A. M., Balliet, D., Parks, C. D., & Van
Vugt, M. (2014). Social dilemmas: The psychol-
ogy of human cooperation. New York: Oxford
University Press.
Van Lange, P. A. M., Otten, W., De Bruin, E. M. N.,
& Joireman, J. A. (1997). Development of proso-
cial, individualistic, and competitive orientations:
Theory and preliminary evidence. Journal of Per-
sonality and Social Psychology, 73, 733–746.
Van Lange, P. A. M., Ouwerkerk, J. W., & Tazelaar,
M. J. A. (2002). How to overcome the detrimental
effects of noise in social interaction: The benefits
of generosity. Journal of Personality and Social
Psychology, 82, 768–780.
Van Lange, P. A. M., Rockenbach, B., & Yamagishi,
T. (2014). Reward and punishment in social dilem-
mas. New York: Oxford University Press.
Van Lange, P. A. M., Schippers, M., & Balliet, D.
(2011). Who volunteers in psychology experi-
ments?: An empirical review of prosocial motiva-
tion in volunteering. Personality and Individual
Differences, 51, 284297.
Wang, Z., Jusup, M., Wang, R. W., Shi, L., Iwasa, Y.,
Moreno, Y., et al. (2017). Onymity promotes co-
operation in social dilemma experiments. Science
Advances, 3, e1601444.
Warneken, F., & Tomasello, M. (2006). Altruistic
helping in human infants and young chimpanzees.
Science, 311, 1301–1303.
Wedekind, C., & Milinski, M. (2000). Cooperation
through image scoring in humans. Science, 288,
850852.
West, S. A., Griffin, A. S., & Gardner, A. (2007).
Evolutionary explanations for cooperation. Cur-
rent Biology, 17, R661–R672.
Whitmeyer, J. M. (2000). Effects of positive reputation
systems. Social Science Research, 29, 188–207.
Wittek, R., & Wielers, R. (1998). Gossip in organiza-
tions. Computational and Mathematical Organi-
zation Theory, 4, 189–204.
Wu, J., & Axelrod, R. (1995). How to cope with
noise in the iterated prisoner’s dilemma. Journal
of Conflict Resolution, 39, 183189.
Wu, J., Balliet, D., & Van Lange, P. A. M. (2015).
When does gossip promote generosity?: Indirect
reciprocity under the shadow of the future. So-
cial Psychological and Personality Science, 6,
923930.
Wu, J., Balliet, D., & Van Lange, P. A. M. (2016a).
Gossip versus punishment: The efficiency of
reputation to promote and maintain cooperation.
Scientific Reports, 6, Article No. 23919.
Wu, J., Balliet, D., & Van Lange, P. A. M. (2016b).
Reputation, gossip, and human cooperation. So-
cial and Personality Psychology Compass, 10,
350–364.
Wu, J., Balliet, D., & Van Lange, P. A. M. (2016c).
Reputation management: Why and how gossip en-
hances generosity. Evolution and Human Behav-
ior, 37, 193201.
Yamagishi, T., Jin, N., & Kiyonari, T. (1999). Bound-
ed generalized reciprocity: Ingroup boasting and
ingroup favoritism. Advances in Group Process-
es, 16, 161197.
Yamamoto, H., Okada, I., Uchida, S., & Sasaki, T.
(2017). A norm knockout method on indirect reci-
procity to reveal indispensable norms. Scientific
Reports, 7, Article No. 44146.
Yoeli, E., Hoffman, M., Rand, D. G., & Nowak, M.
A. (2013). Powering up with indirect reciprocity
in a large-scale field experiment. Proceedings of
the National Academy of Sciences of the USA, 110,
10424–10429.
VanLange_Book.indb 287VanLange_Book.indb 287 6/30/2020 11:17:40 AM6/30/2020 11:17:40 AM