e University of San Francisco
USF Scholarship: a digital repository @ Gleeson Library |
Geschke Center
Sport Management College of Arts and Sciences
3-30-2018
Reputation and the League Standing Eect: e
Case of a Split Season in Minor League Baseball
Nola Agha
University of San Francisco, nagha@usfca.edu
omas Rhoads
Follow this and additional works at: h7ps://repository.usfca.edu/sm
Part of the Sports Management Commons
6is Article is brought to you for free and open access by the College of Arts and Sciences at USF Scholarship: a digital repository @ Gleeson Library |
Geschke Center. It has been accepted for inclusion in Sport Management by an authorized administrator of USF Scholarship: a digital repository @
Gleeson Library | Geschke Center. For more information, please contact repository@usfca.edu.
Recommended Citation
Agha, Nola and Rhoads, 6omas, "Reputation and the League Standing E5ect: 6e Case of a Split Season in Minor League Baseball"
(2018). Sport Management. 23.
h7ps://repository.usfca.edu/sm/23
1
REPUTATION AND THE LEAGUE STANDING EFFECT: THE CASE OF A SPLIT
SEASON IN MINOR LEAGUE BASEBALL
Abstract
Split season league design resets standings at the midpoint of the season, thus allowing for two
periods in which a team can potentially achieve success in a single season. This context allows us
to test both the reputation of the first half winner and the league standing effect on demand.
Examination of game-level data from the 2010 Southern League reveals fans are unaffected by
measures of both team quality and league standing in the second half of the season. On the other
hand, the first half winners saw an 11% increase in attendance as a percent of stadium capacity,
suggesting that in the second half of the season winners matter more than winning. (JEL L22 and
L83)
Keywords: demand, minor league baseball, league standing effect, reputation, split season
Agha, N. & Rhoads, T. A. (2018). Reputation and the league standing effect: The case of a split
season in Minor League Baseball, Applied Economics, (50)41, 4447-4455.
https://doi.org/10.1080/00036846.2018.1456646
2
1. Introduction
Consistently attracting fans to the ballpark is, of course, a primary goal of any
professional baseball team. This strategy provides at least a few steady revenue streams, the most
obvious being ticket, concession, and merchandise sales in addition to crowds that positively
contribute to home field advantage and player development. For minor league baseball teams in
particular, a business model that is more reliant on fans coming to the stadium is critical for
success. Because other major sources of revenue that Major League Baseball teams can rely
on—television revenue and revenue sharing, for instance—are mostly nonexistent for the minor
leagues, there are sometimes alternative ways to create, enhance, and maintain fan demand for
the ballpark experience. Additional entertainment such as postgame fireworks, concerts, and
bobblehead giveaways are just a few of the more typical methods used to bring additional fans to
the minor league ballpark that may not be drawn by the quality of the baseball competition alone.
Much work has already focused on this aspect of minor league baseball attendance.
The literature shows that fans generally respond positively to team quality at all levels of
professional sports. However, the response is somewhat muted for minor league sports—Gitter
and Rhoads (2010) and Winfree and Fort (2008) found that average attendance increases only
about 2% for minor league baseball and hockey teams when teams see a 10% increase in
winning percentage. Focusing exclusively on minor league baseball, this result can be somewhat
troubling from a revenue generation perspective for at least a few reasons. First, team quality is
entirely a function of the Major League parent team. Minor league affiliates are meant to serve as
the player development grounds for the Major League team while also providing opportunities to
play in more distracting conditions in order to learn to focus and block out noise and heckling
from fans. This suggests that winning games is not as important as developing player talent for
3
the Major League team. Second, the minimal impact from the additional fans from winning
suggests a team at the AA level of minor league baseball would see attendance increase by about
90 fans per game, or by about 6,250 fans annually. Using the minor league baseball average cost
of about $65 for a family of four to attend a game, this points to additional revenue of a little
more than $1,400 per game, or approximately $100,000 per season that would be attributed to a
higher quality team.
1
While this figure is not insignificant, we must keep in mind that this
additional revenue stream is purely a function of the quality of the minor league team, which is
completely out of the control of the owners of that minor league team.
Given the above discussion, it should not be surprising that minor leagues cannot rely on
winning alone to maintain or increase attendance. Promotions and special events are standard for
minor league baseball—fireworks nights and bobblehead giveaways are typically the games with
the highest attendance during the season. But another way some minor leagues appear to have
tried to increase attendance is through a split season structure of regular season competition. In
those minor leagues with a split season, the teams making the playoffs are determined by
splitting the season into two halves to determine a first half and second half winner. The first half
winner is determined as the team with the best record at the midpoint of the season. Then, at the
midpoint of the season, the first half records are wiped clean and new second half standings are
generated. The team with the best record in the second half of the season is the second half
winner, and plays the first half winner in the playoffs. Usually, there are two divisions in a minor
league with a split season and the winners of each half of these divisions meet in a playoff. All
five leagues in the A level of minor league baseball use a split season format to determine
playoff teams while neither of the two AAA level leagues do. The AA level of minor league
1
See http://www.milb.com/news/article.jsp?ymd=20150615&content_id=130739074&fext=.jsp&vkey=pr_milb.
Accessed April 12, 2016.
4
baseball is unique in that two of the three leagues—the Southern League and the Texas
League—both have a split season format, while the Eastern League does not. This unique nature
of split season format at the AA level suggests leagues can attempt to optimize attendance
through the playoff and season structure.
This paper examines the impact of a split season on game-level attendance in the
Southern League for the 2010 season. We specifically focus on two possible reasons a split
season approach to league and playoff design could affect attendance. First, the somewhat
arbitrary resetting of the standings at the midpoint of the season means all teams are put in an
equal position for playoff consideration at the start of the second half of the season, regardless of
their performance in the first half of the season. Of course, the quality of the team is not likely to
change much, if at all, at the midpoint of the season. So while the relative success, or lack of it,
in the first half of the season is likely to carry over to the second half of the season, the reset
standings may give the fan a new sense of how their team compares to the rest of the league. We
test these ideas using Neale’s (1964) league standing effect. Second, because the split season
produces a first half winner in each of the two divisions in the Southern League, two teams are
assured of making the end-of-the season playoffs. For these teams, this designation as a playoff-
quality team can therefore send a signal to their fans of team quality for the entire second half of
the season. In other words, gaining a reputation as a playoff-caliber team may provide useful
information to the fan of absolute team quality that may not be easily revealed or readily
determined from the daily standings.
We get two primary results from our model. First, our results suggest Southern League
fans are not responsive to the games behind metric used to test the league standing effect.
Specifically, these fans are not sensitive to a daily indicator of team performance, relative team
5
quality, and end-of-season championship possibilities. Further, this suggests more broadly that
minor league baseball fans, unlike Major League Baseball fans, are mostly not concerned with
the uncertainty of outcome. However, our model does provide a second result showing an 11-
point increase in per game attendance as a percent of capacity in the second half of the season for
the first half winner that secured a spot in the postseason playoffs. These results together suggest
that while minor league baseball fans do not appear to be sensitive to relative team performance,
they do respond to a reputation signal of overall team quality.
The rest of this paper proceeds as follows. In the next section, we examine how the split
season league and playoff design fits into the literature. In section three, we introduce the data
and our model. Section four presents the results and in section five we discuss our results before
concluding in the final section.
2. Literature Review
Developing a more complete understanding of how baseball fans respond to certain
features of game, league and playoff design is perhaps the primary motivating factor for much of
the research concerning minor league baseball. Baseball demand estimation began with
Rottenberg (1956) and Noll (1974) and focused first on Major League Baseball before efforts
were made to estimate minor league baseball demand. In moving to estimate demand for minor
league baseball, Siegfried and Eisenberg (1980) opened opportunities for others to study things
such as the impact of promotions (Gifis and Sommers 2006), winning (Gitter and Rhoads 2010),
top prospects (Gitter and Rhoads 2011), stadium construction (Gitter and Rhoads 2014), parent
club quality, distance, and affiliation changes (Agha and Cobbs 2015), proximity to other
6
professional baseball teams (Rhoads 2015), team name changes (Agha, Goldman, and Dixon
2016), and a host of other factors (Anthony et al 2014).
The body of evidence documenting the impact on attendance at the minor league level is
getting deeper and broader, and provides a further check on the robustness of the research
examining demand at the major league level across sports. Minor league and major league live
sporting events are typically viewed as substitutes by fans in baseball (Agha et al. 2016; Gitter
and Rhoads 2010), hockey (Winfree and Fort 2008) and football (Fort and Quirk 1999),
suggesting that minor league and major league sports fans can behave in a somewhat similar and
predictable fashion. But there are some notable distinctions between minor league and major
league sports. Agha (2013) identifies a positive impact on local income levels from minor league
baseball teams not typically seen from Major League Baseball teams and Gitter and Rhoads
(2010) and Agha and Cobbs (2015) find that fans respond minimally to winning minor league
baseball teams in comparison to winning Major League Baseball teams. This suggests all
professional sports leagues can potentially provide a reasonable arena within which to test
economic theories, with some leagues possibly being better suited for testing than others.
We turn our focus now to Neale’s (1964) league standing effect, which posits that “the
closer the standings, and within any range of standings the more frequently the standings change,
the larger will be the gate receipts” (p. 3). Importantly, it must be noted that it should be possible
to apply and test the league standing effect in any professional sports league—including any
minor league baseball league like the Southern League—that maintains and reports league
standings and where there exists the potential for league standings or rank to change at any point
before, during or after any game throughout the season (Andreff and Scelles 2015). In fact, a
literature that emerged in the late 1980s and early 1990s began to focus more on the importance
7
of the dynamics of championship league standings and the possible effects of daily changes on
attendance instead of simply examining how end-of-season competitive balance was related to
attendance. Cairns (1987) highlighted championship and relegation contention, especially in the
second half of the season, in the Scottish Football League. Likewise, Borland (1987) controlled
for those teams within two games of the league leader in the championship race in determining
attendance in the Victorian Football League—an Australia Rules football league. While
championship significance and league position were tested separately by Jennett (1984) for the
Scottish Football League and by Dobson and Goddard (1992) for the English Football League,
their metrics were ultimately found problematic by Baimbridge, Cameron and Dawson (1996)
who studied championship and relegation significance in the English Premier League.
The problem with some of the previous models in controlling for championship
significance is that fans were assumed to use information only available at the end of the season
in order to make ex ante attendance decisions. Baimbridge, Cameron and Dawson (1996) work
around this by including a dummy variable for a top four position in the standings, suggesting
the team is in contention for the championship. Additionally, they included controls for whether
or not the team already secured a championship or relegation for the following season. While
none of these highlighted variables were found to be significant in describing match attendance,
they nevertheless point to the types of variables that should be included when modeling the
league standing effect in professional baseball. Specifically, baseball fans pay attention to the
standings and the closeness of those standings through the games behind metric. This metric is
reported on a daily basis and shows how many wins (games) behind the current first place team
any given baseball team in the league is. The games behind metric is reported in the standings
8
and is updated in the newspaper and on league websites after every game is completed and is
readily available for any fan to access.
We note that some previous studies used the games behind metric to test the uncertainty
of outcome hypothesis. The games behind metric provides information to baseball fans about the
relative quality of the baseball teams playing, making it possible to form an ex ante prediction
about the uncertainty of outcome. Knowles, Sherony and Haupert (1992) include the sum of the
games behind for both the home and visiting teams playing the game while Soebbing (2008)
includes just the games behind for the home team. While these two previous studies were
certainly not the first to examine the impact of games behind on attendance (see, for example,
Demmert 1973, Noll 1974, and Whitney 1988) they do highlight a very common technique used
to test the uncertainty of outcome hypothesis. And while even more complex measures of game
and league championship uncertainty and game importance exist, (see Tainsky and Winfree,
2010 and Lei and Humphreys 2013) they are not expected to be easily accessible or used readily
by fans to make a decision about attending a baseball game.
We suggest here that the games behind metric is perhaps a better test of the league
standing effect as it is likely the metric most commonly used by fans to assess both relative team
quality and the likely significance of each game in the end-of-season championship race. Two
recent papers explicitly test the league standing effect. In looking at Major League Baseball,
Humphreys and Zhou (2015) use a measure that is probably less intuitive or accessible to fans
than a games behind metric, while Andreff and Scelles (2015) use a metric for the French
football league that is not as comprehensive in describing the championship possibilities as a
standard games behind metric. These two papers provide mixed results of the presence of the
league standing effect.
9
We must emphasize that the Southern League’s split season—and other leagues similarly
structured—where league standings are reset at the midpoint of the season, appears to be
designed in order to benefit from a fan’s expected preference to attend a baseball game with a
more direct and immediate impact on the end-of-season championship race. To our knowledge,
split season minor league baseball has not been used as a test bed to examine the extent to which
the league standing effect exists. In fact, Medcalfe (2009) seems to be the only one to have used
split season minor league data in any work, but he examined team effort and not fan demand
resulting from the league standing effect. Thus, our research is expected to fill a gap in the
literature by testing the league standing effect by using split season data from the Southern
League of AA minor league baseball. Finally, we will additionally test the reputational effects
afforded to the first half winner in attracting fans to the ballpark. This feature of league design
has attracted little attention as it relates to fan demand, but reputation due to winning the
season’s first half is expected to provide critical information to the fan regarding relative team
quality and end-of-season championship possibilities (see Czarnitzki and Stadtmann 2002 and
Ertug and Castellucci 2013).
3. Data and Model
Demand for a professional sporting event is necessarily a function of the league standing
effect in addition to team and game quality. Neale’s (1964) observation that “progress towards a
championship or changes in the standings” can help determine demand for a sporting event and
suggests that in order to incorporate a split season league design, a demand model must allow for
the possibility of two halves in a season and the opportunity to identify the first half division
winners. Our demand model for split season minor league baseball below is unique in that it
10
includes split season flexibility in identifying the league standing effect for each half of the
season in addition to the standard inclusion of team and game quality measures that drive game
attendance:
Game Attendance = F (1
st
Half League Standing Effect, 2
nd
Half League Standing
Effect, 1
st
Half Division Winner, Team Quality, Game Quality)
To test the league standing effect and the reputational effect of a split season first half
winner, we used individual home game observations from all 10 teams in the 2010 Southern
League season (n=693). Specifically, we utilized ordinary least squares (OLS) to estimate
y
ij
= β
1
X
ij
+ β
2
Z
ij
+ υ
i
+ ε
ij
(1)
where y
i
is per game attendance as a percent of stadium capacity for team i in game j, similar to
Cebula, Toma, and Carmichael (2009). X
ij
captures team quality and game quality, Z
ij
contains
split season-related indicators, υ
i
are city fixed-effects, and ε
ij
is a random disturbance. If the split
season format successfully results in two separate “seasons” then each half should be analyzed
separately thus we also estimate this model by removing Z
i
from equation (1) and replacing it
with a single indicator for the first half winner. We relied on the plentiful research on individual
game demand in minor league baseball to formulate our empirical specification (Anthony et al.
2014; Cebula et al. 2009; Howell, Klenosky, and McEvoy 2015; Paul, Toma, and Weinbach
2009; Paul and Weinbach 2013a; Paul and Weinbach 2013b; Siegfried and Eisenberg 1980)
where individual game demand is a function of team quality, game quality, and city-specific
features.
Team quality is captured through win percent, cumulative homeruns, and the number of
top prospects defined as any player ranked in the top 20 by Baseball America at the start of the
2010 season. Both win percent and cumulative homeruns are calculated for each game and are
11
re-set at the beginning of the second half due to the split season. We expect the coefficients on
both the number of top prospects (Gitter and Rhoads 2011) and the number of homeruns (Gitter
and Rhoads 2010; Siegfried & Eisenberg 1980) to be positive. Both Agha and Cobbs (2015) and
Gitter and Rhoads (2010) found the coefficient on win percent to be positive and significant in
AA leagues as a whole, but analysis of only the Southern League (Anthony et al. 2014; Paul and
Weinbach 2013a) found the coefficient on win percent to be insignificant. Game quality is
captured by dummy variables for opening day, doubleheader, day of the week, month, weather,
fireworks, and non-fireworks promotions. City fixed effects are included to capture constants
such as population, per capita income, preference for minor league baseball, and other
unobservable city specific features.
Relying on Neale’s (1964) claim that gate receipts derive from, “excitement in the daily
changes in the standings or…possibilities of changes in standings” (p. 3) we operationalize the
league standing effect as games behind. This common measure is widely distributed, easily
understood by local fans, and can signal both potential excitement for a game, and “progress
towards a championship” (Neale, 1964, p. 4). In a split season this progress occurs twice—once
halfway through the season and once at the end. Thus, games behind is re-set halfway through
the season. To be thorough, we test both games behind for the home team (Soebbing 2008) and
the sum of games behind for both home and visiting teams (Knowles et al. 1992). Furthermore,
we test for a possible reputational effect of the first half winner on second half demand with a
dummy variable. Table 1 summarizes the descriptive statistics for each of the variables.
To date, all demand modeling on minor league baseball has omitted measurement of a
split season league and analyzed a single season as if it had one championship. Thus we begin
with a single equation that captures team quality, game quality, and city-specific features. To
12
capture the unique structure of the split season league we include an indicator for first half
games, an interaction of this first half dummy and games behind, and an indicator for the first
half winners, of which there are two (one for each division). The full season empirical
specification is
AttendanceAsPctOfCapacity = β
0
+ β
1
FirstHalfWinner + β
2
FirstHalfDummy +
β
3
FirstHalfWinnerxFirstHalfDummy + β
4
TopProspects + β
5
WinPct + β
6
Homeruns +
β
7
GamesBehind + β
8
OpeningDay + β
9
Doubleheader + β
10-15
DayOfWeek + β
16-20
Month +
β
21
Temperature + β
22
Windspeed + β
23
Clear + β
24
Sunny + β
25
Cloudy + β
26
Overcast + β
27
Drizzle
+ β
28
Rain + β
29
Fireworks + β
30
NonFireworksPromotion + city fixed-effects + ε (2)
The empirical specification for separate first and second halves removed the first half
dummy and the interaction term and months were adjusted accordingly.
4. Results
We used OLS to estimate both the full and half season models. A Breusch-Pagan / Cook-
Weisberg test for heteroskedasticity indicated the need for robust standard errors in the full
season (χ
2
= 36.39, p < 0.001), first half (χ
2
= 13.93, p < 0.001), and second half (χ
2
= 32.17, p =
0.08) regressions. Variance inflation factors under 10 indicate multicollinearity is not a problem
in the first half and second half regressions.
To determine whether the data should be pooled into full season or regressed by halves of
the season, we tested for the equality of coefficients with a Hausman test using seemingly
unrelated regressions. The results indicate we can reject the equality of the common coefficients
between the full season and first half (χ
2
= 87.25, p < 0.0001) and between the full season and the
second half (χ
2
= 104.34, p < 0.0001).
13
Overall, our results in Table 2 are consistent with previous research on per game
attendance. As expected, we find attendance as a percent of capacity increases with promotions,
good weather, opening day, and Thursday, Friday, and Saturday games. Additionally, rain tends
to decrease attendance as a percent of capacity. Coefficients on team quality, measured as top
prospects and homeruns, were insignificant and line up with other estimations of demand for
Southern League baseball (Anthony et al. 2014; Paul and Weinbach 2013a). On the other hand,
team quality measured as win percent was significant in the first half but not the second half or
full season models. Table 2 further indicates the coefficient on the home team games behind
metric is insignificant in all cases, and a separate analysis found the coefficient on the sum of
games behind for the home and away teams was similarly insignificant (p > 0.4) with no change
in any of the other variable estimates.
2
Finally, first half winners are associated with an 11-point
gain in attendance as a percent of stadium capacity in the second half of the season.
5. Discussion
Neale’s (1964) league standing effect proposes that close standings, actual changes in
standings, or the possibility of changes in standings generate excitement in fans who then
convert that excitement into gate revenues. In theory, the split season league design attempts to
maximize this benefit for minor league baseball teams by providing more than just the usual one
period for a team to achieve success in the regular season. By providing a chance for a team to
either be the first half or second half winner during two distinct periods of the regular season,
league standings have more opportunity to be close and potentially matter more. Our results
2
These results are available upon request.
14
indicate that fans of AA Southern League baseball are not motivated to attend games due to any
measure of league standing in either half of the season. In fact, team win percent is the only
measure of team quality that affects demand in the first half of the season. When the second half
of the season begins, winning ceases to matter altogether. Instead, the first half winner benefits
from its reputation as a winner—attendance as a percent of stadium capacity increases 11% in
the second half of the season for the first half winner. These results are consistent with
Czarnitzki and Stadtmann (2002) who similarly found significant reputational effects that
outweighed measures of league position and Rindova et al (2005) who found prominence can be
more powerful than the ability to produce quality output. In short, in the split season minor
league baseball context, gaining a reputation as a winner becomes more important than actually
winning.
If fans are generally uninterested in the sporting performance of a minor league team
focused on developing player talent, Neale’s Fourth Estate Benefit might explain why first half
winners see an 11 point increase in attendance in the second half of the season. He suggests the
“reporter-newspaper-printer-distributor complex” (Neale 1964, p. 3) is incentivized to tout the
success of the first half winner. A minor league baseball team that is the first half winner and has
an active marketing department thus appears to have a strong incentive to directly promote the
quality of their playoff-caliber team. This not only drives revenue to the firm, but can also
meaningfully signal to the fans that a team has a reputation as a winner.
Bounded rationality provides an alternate explanation to the notion that fans respond to first
half winners but not to winning. While fans could benefit from using the games behind metric in
making a decision of whether or not to attend a baseball game, the cost of making that decision
may simply be too high. The level of information about the quality of the team provided from
15
being credentialed as a first half winner is likely enough to offset any cost of acquiring that
information. Southern League baseball fans thus appear to exhibit bounded rationality in their
decisions to attend baseball games.
Reputation as a playoff-caliber team thus seems to matter for fans in this setting where
information acquisition is costly and can lead directly to an additional revenue stream for the
first half winner. An increase in attendance of 11.4% of stadium capacity leads to an additional
884 fans per game for the average Southern League team. With the average AA baseball ticket
price around $7.00, this suggests the first half winner in the Southern League can increase ticket
revenue in the second half of the season by more than $200,000. Concessions and ancillary
purchases at the stadium can be expected to add to the bump in revenue the first half winner
could receive.
These results have interesting implications for demand modeling. First, they indicate that
leagues utilizing a split season design have unique demand characteristics by half and should be
estimated as such. This will be a challenge to future researchers when analyzing classifications
like AA that have both a split and non-split season format among the different leagues. Second,
while full season analysis finds significant effects of win percent in AA leagues (Agha and
Cobbs 2015; Gitter and Rhoads 2010) game-level analysis does not. This difference could stem
from the split season first half winner driving some of the results or from the differences between
split season and non-split season leagues.
The results of our research also have implications beyond baseball in some settings where
reputation as a winner matters and information acquisition is not costless. An Academy Award
nomination, for example, provides a strong reputational signal about a film’s quality to a
potential consumer. Box-office revenues increase with nominations (Nelson et al 2001),
16
suggesting that movie release dates can be a function of award schedules. But our results further
suggest that more awards in the entertainment industry may provide more opportunities for films
and television shows to gain a reputation for high quality. This allows consumers to gain
information about the quality of a movie or television show with relatively low acquisition costs
and can lead to higher revenues for production studios as more consumers watch films and
television shows considered the best. Also, consider the U.S. political landscape and the state-
level presidential primary contests that occur every four years. Primary candidates place a lot of
emphasis on winning the early races—New Hampshire, Iowa, and South Carolina, for instance—
with the expectation that an early win can provide momentum for future primary contests in
other states. An early win can send a signal to a future voter in another state about quality of the
candidate in a way that suggests reputation as a winner matters to voters much like reputation as
a playoff-caliber team matters to Southern League baseball fans.
Although a split season design allows standings to reset at the midpoint of the season, the
reality is that team quality changes little, if at all, at this point. That observation, coupled with
our results, nevertheless raises important questions about league design. For example, what
would happen to Southern League attendance if there was no split season or what would happen
to the Eastern League (currently no split season) if a split season was implemented? Similarly,
would MLB benefit from a split season? We encourage future researchers to examine more years
and more leagues to determine the robustness of our results. Finally, future research should also
attempt to more accurately determine those quality metrics that matter to minor league baseball
fans.
6. Conclusion
17
The minor league baseball business model centers on drawing fans to the ballpark
primarily with savvy marketing and promotions. In alignment with many minor league baseball
executives who claim the business is about “family entertainment” (Johnson 1995; Pietschmann
2010), the results of this analysis indicate the quality of the team and the closeness of the
championship race—that is, the league standing effect—generally do not motivate fans of
Southern League baseball to attend games. This holds true despite a split season league design
that doubles the opportunities for fans to see their team achieve success. In contrast, winning the
first half is comparable to having a fireworks night every night for the second half of the
season—a truly meaningful result for minor league managers and marketers.
Acknowledgements
The authors wish to thank Jeff Gurney for sharing his Southern League data.
18
References
Agha, N. (2013). The economic impact of stadiums and teams: The case of Minor League
Baseball. Journal of Sports Economics, 14(3), 227-252.
Agha, N., & Cobbs, J. (2015). Is the grass greener? Switching costs and geographic proximity in
the high status affiliations of professional baseball. Managerial and Decision
Economics, DOI: 10.1002/mde.2741
Agha, N., Goldman, M., & Dixon, J. C. (2016). Rebranding: The value of team name changes,
European Sport Management Quarterly, 16(5), 673-693.
Andreff, W., & Scelles, N. (2015). Walter C. Neale 50 years after: Beyond competitive balance,
the league standing effect tested with French football data. Journal of Sports Economics,
16(8), 819-834.
Anthony, T., Kahn, T., Madison, B., Paul, R. J., & Weinbach, A. (2014). Similarities in fan
preferences for minor league baseball across the American southeast. Journal of
Economics and Finance, 38(1), 150-163.
Baimbridge, M., Cameron, S. & Dawson, P. (1996). Satellite television and the demand for
football: A whole new ball game? Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 43(3), 317.
Borland, J. (1987). The demand for Australian Rules Football. Economic Record, 63(182), 220.
Cairns, J. A. (1987). Evaluating changes in league structure. The reorganization of the Scottish
Football League. Applied Economics, 19(2), 259-275.
Cebula, R. J., Toma, M., & Carmichael, J. (2009). Attendance and promotions in minor league
baseball: The Carolina League. Applied Economics, 41(25), 3209-3214.
Czarnitzki, D., & Stadtmann, G. (2002). Uncertainty of outcome versus reputation: Empirical
evidence for the First German Football Division. Empirical Economics, 27(1), 101-112.
Demmert, H. G. (1973). The economics of professional team sports: Lexington, Mass.,
Lexington Books [1973].
Dobson, S. M., & Goddard, J. A. (1992). The demand for standing and seated viewing
accommodation in the English Football League. Applied Economics, 24(10), 1155.
Ertug, G., & Castellucci, F. (2013). Getting what you need: How reputation and status affect
team performance, hiring, and salaries in the NBA. Academy of Management Journal,
56(2), 407-431.
19
Fort, R & Quirk, J. (1999). The college football industry. In Fizel, J., Gustafson, E., & Hadley,
L. (Eds.). Sports economics: Current research: Westport, CT: Praeger.
Gifis, L. S., & Sommers, P. M. (2006). Promotions and attendance in Minor League
Baseball. Atlantic Economic Journal, 34(4), 513-514.
Gitter, S. R., & Rhoads, T. A. (2010). Determinants of Minor League Baseball
attendance. Journal of Sports Economics, 11(6), 614-628.
Gitter, S. R., & Rhoads, T. A. (2011). Top prospects and Minor League Baseball
attendance. Journal of Sports Economics, 12(3), 341-351.
Gitter, S. R., & Rhoads, T. A. (2014). Stadium construction and Minor League Baseball
attendance. Contemporary Economic Policy, 32(1), 144-154.
Howell, S. M., Klenosky, D. B., & McEvoy, C. D. (2015). Weather, timing, and promotions in
Minor League Baseball: An examination of attendance in the International
League. Journal of Applied Sport Management, 7(2).
Humphreys, B. R., & Zhou, L. (2015). The Louis-Schmelling Paradox and the league standing
effect reconsidered. Journal of Sports Economics, 16(8), 835-852.
Jennett, N. I. (1984). Attendances, uncertainty of outcome and policy in Scottish League
Football. Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 31(2), 176-198.
Johnson, A. T. (1995). Minor league baseball and local economic development. Urbana and
Chicago: University of Illinois Press.
Knowles, G., Sherony, K., & Haupert, M. (1992). The demand for Major League Baseball: A
test of the uncertainty of outcome hypothesis. American Economist, 36(2), 72-80.
Lei, X. & Humphreys, B. (2013). Game importance as a dimension of uncertainty of outcome.
Journal of Quantitative Analysis in Sports, 9(1), 25-36.
Medcalfe, S. (2009). Incentives and league structure in Minor League Baseball. Journal of Sport
Management, 23, 119-141.
Neale, W. C. (1964). The peculiar economics of professional sports: a contribution to the theory
of the firm in sporting competition and in market competition. Quarterly Journal of
Economics, 78, 1-14.
Nelson, R., Donihue, M., Waldman, D., & Wheaton, C. (2001). What’s an Oscar Worth?
Economic Inquiry, 39, 1–16.
Noll, R. G. (1974). Attendance and price setting. In R. G. Noll (Ed.), Government and the sports
business (pp. 115-157). Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.
20
Paul, R. J., Toma, M., & Weinbach, A. P. (2008). The minor league experience: What drives
attendance at South Atlantic League baseball games? Coastal Business Journal, 8(1),
70-84.
Paul, R. J., & Weinbach, A. P. (2013a). Fireworks saturation and attendance in minor league
baseball. International Journal of Sport Finance, 8(4), 312.
Paul, R. J., & Weinbach, A. P. (2013b). The Yankee effect in Minor League Baseball. New York
Economic Review, 44(1), 32-42.
Pietschmann, R. J. (2010, March 30). Diamond Mines. Departures, Retrieved from
http://www.departures.com/lifestyle/consuming-passions/diamond-mines
Rhoads, T. (2015). The call up to the majors: A proximity-based approach to the economics of
Minor League Baseball. New York, NY: Springer.
Rindova, V. P., Williamson, I. O., Petkova, A. P., & Sever, J. M. (2005). Being good or being
known: An empirical examination of the dimensions, antecedents, and consequences of
organizational reputation. Academy of Management Journal, 48(6), 1033-1049.
Rottenberg, S. (1956). The baseball players' labor market. Journal of Political Economy, 64,
242-258.
Siegfried, J. J., & Eisenberg, J. D. (1980). The demand for Minor League Baseball. Atlantic
Economic Journal, 8(2), 59-69.
Soebbing, B. P. (2008). Competitive balance and attendance in Major League Baseball: An
empirical test of the uncertainty of outcome hypothesis. International Journal of Sport
Finance, 3(2), 119-126.
Tainsky, S., & Winfree, J. A. (2010). Short-run demand and uncertainty of outcome in Major
League Baseball. Review of Industrial Organization, 37(3), 197-214.
Whitney, J. D. (1988). Winning games versus winning championships: The economics of fan
interest and team performance. Economic Inquiry, 26(4), 703-724.
Winfree, J. A., & Fort, R. (2008). Fan substitution and the 2004-05 NHL lockout. Journal of
Sports Economics, 9(4), 425-434.
21
Table 1. Descriptive statistics of 2010 Southern League home games
Variable Mean Std. Dev. Min Max
Dependent variable
Attendance as a percent of capacity 0.445
0.252
.043
1.332
Split Season Measures
First half winner dummy 0.101
0.302
0
1
First half dummy 0.498
0.500
0
1
Games behind by half x First half dummy 2.081
3.484
0
16.5
Team Quality
Number of top prospects 0.127
0.333
0
1
Win percent by half 0.496
0.142
0
1
Cumulative homeruns by half 10.909
7.912
0
37.0
Game Quality
Games behind, home team, by half 3.958
3.904
0
16.5
Games behind, sum of both teams, by half 7.851
5.717
0
23.5
Opening day dummy 0.014
0.119
0
1
Doubleheader 0.091
0.288
0
1
Sunday 0.141
0.349
0
1
Tuesday 0.104
0.305
0
1
Wednesday 0.143
0.350
0
1
Thursday 0.162
0.368
0
1
Friday 0.154
0.362
0
1
Saturday 0.157
0.364
0
1
April 0.159
0.366
0
1
May 0.203
0.403
0
1
July 0.189
0.392
0
1
August 0.206
0.405
0
1
September 0.045
0.207
0
1
Temperature 84.156
8.567
54
104
Wind speed 6.929
4.303
1
26
Clear 0.253
0.435
0
1
Sunny 0.059
0.236
0
1
Cloudy 0.175
0.380
0
1
Overcast 0.066
0.249
0
1
Drizzle 0.009
0.093
0
1
Rain 0.017
0.131
0
1
Fireworks 0.182
0.386
0
1
Non-fireworks promotions 0.691
0.462
0
1
22
Table 2. Demand estimation on attendance as a percent of capacity in the Southern League,
2010
Full Season First Half Second Half
β β β
First half winner dummy 0.0552
0.1144*
First half dummy -0.0259
Games behind by half x First
half dummy -0.0018
Number of top prospects -0.0008 -0.0774 -0.0169
Win percent by half 0.0188 0.1708* -0.1237
Cumulative homeruns by
half 0.0026 0.0030 -0.0024
Games behind, home team,
by half 0.0011 -0.0013 -0.0001
Opening day dummy 0.1843 0.1312 0.0000
Doubleheader -0.0276 -0.0362 -0.0193
Sunday 0.0190 -0.0296 0.0561
Tuesday 0.0192 0.0556 -0.0153
Wednesday 0.0372 0.0902* -0.0186
Thursday 0.0665** 0.0763* 0.0551*
Friday 0.1898*** 0.2265*** 0.1642***
Saturday 0.2515*** 0.2932*** 0.2213***
April 0.0682 0.1084*
May 0.0479* 0.0647*
July 0.0297
0.0532
August -0.0554
0.0205
September -0.0606
0.0465
Temperature 0.0001 0.0011 0.0014
Wind speed -0.0009 -0.0018 0.0018
Clear 0.0157 -0.0176 0.0450*
Sunny 0.0719* 0.0979* 0.0514
Cloudy -.0392* -0.0420 -0.0184
Overcast -0.0228 -0.0322 0.0199
Drizzle -0.0468 -0.1660*** -0.0560
Rain -0.1344*** -0.2109*** -0.1126*
Fireworks 0.1447*** 0.1119*** 0.1629***
Non-fireworks promotions 0.0671*** 0.1244*** 0.0275
Observations 683
340
343
R
2
0.6288
0.6202
0.7230
Note: Fixed effects suppressed; *p < 0.05; **p < 0.01; ***p < 0.001