\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 1 19-OCT-18 12:58
Exclusionary Taxation
Shayak Sarkar & Josh Rosenthal*
Property tax assessments appear to be technocratic calculations. But they
may be calculated to discriminate, even unintentionally. California’s constitu-
tional limitations on property taxes, as first enacted by Proposition 13 in 1978,
remain the poster child for the so-called “property tax revolt” of the late twenti-
eth century. Such laws privilege preexisting homeowners by capping assess-
ments at historic levels far below contemporary value. As property prices rise,
beneficiary homeowners may even bequeath this taxpayer windfall to their de-
scendants and immortalize these underassessments. Newer, increasingly diverse
residents end up paying higher taxes because the law treats them with less re-
gard than their more pedigreed neighbors. These tax policies are rationalized as
providing “stability” to the existing residents. The aggrieved have found cold
comfort in the Constitution, with the Supreme Court upholding the core of Cali-
fornia’s system in the canonical Nordlinger v. Hahn.
In this Article, we argue that even if such exclusionary tax policies do not
violate the Constitution, they likely violate another facet of federal law: the Fair
Housing Act’s disparate impact liability. Our contributions are threefold. First,
as a procedural matter, we identify recent caselaw that offers a means for such
legal challenges to enter the courthouse door. Although state and federal courts
in the twentieth century erected barriers to judicial review of property tax poli-
cies, we argue that the landscape has changed.
Second, using California as a case study, we illuminate the contours of a
Fair Housing Act challenge to discriminatory, acquisition-value assessments. We
do so with reference to prior and ongoing tax litigation in diverse municipali-
ties, namely Long Island and metropolitan Detroit. We thus explore the federal
prohibition of what we call “exclusionary taxation.”
Third and most significantly, we train our sights on the justifications for
exclusionary taxes. We map, and begin to reconcile, the tensions between, on
one hand, recognized local government interests in “stability,” and, on the
other, property-based inclusion of a demographically-evolving America. We ar-
gue that, while property tax assessments can be used to protect existing home-
owners, they must be employed through narrowly tailored methods, such as
circuit breakers or deferred payment, rather than overly broad acquisition-value
assessment systems. While the latter might pass constitutional muster, they fail
to comply with the Fair Housing Act’s vision of property-based pluralism.
T
ABLE OF
C
ONTENTS
I
NTRODUCTION
.................................................. 620
R
I. A P
ROPERTY
T
AX
P
RIMER
................................ 626
R
A. The Role of the Property Tax & Assessment ........... 626
R
B. The Tax Revolt and Proposition 13 ................... 628
R
* Shayak Sarkar is Acting Professor of Law at the University of California-Davis. Josh
Rosenthal is currently a staff attorney at the National Immigration Law Center (NILC). This
article was written before Mr. Rosenthal joined NILC. We thank Ian Ayres, Yuvraj Joshi,
Jacqueline Hand, Daniel Hemel, Jacob Goldin, Michael Knoll, Isaac William Martin, Erin
Scharff, Gabe Scheffler, Darien Shanske, and Stewart Sterk for helpful comments on earlier
drafts.
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 2 19-OCT-18 12:58
620 Harvard Civil Rights-Civil Liberties Law Review [Vol. 53
C. Fairness and the Law and Economics of Property
Taxes ............................................... 632
R
II. T
WENTIETH
C
ENTURY
W
ITHDRAWAL FROM
P
ROPERTY
T
AX
R
EVIEW
................................................. 634
R
A. Federal Disengagement .............................. 635
R
1. Expansion of Comity ............................. 637
R
2. “Plain, Speedy and Efficient Remedy” ............ 640
R
3. Deferential Constitutional Review Article XIIIA,
Allegheny, and Nordlinger ....................... 643
R
B. State Restrictions on Review ......................... 646
R
III. R
EVIVING
M
EANINGFUL
S
TATE
-C
OURT
R
EVIEW
............ 650
R
A. Inclusive Communities: Reaffirmed Disparate Impact . . . 650
R
B. HUD’s Disparate Impact Framework.................. 656
R
C. Diminished Deference ............................... 657
R
IV. Nordlinger Revisited: Addressing Exclusionary Taxation
with the Fair Housing Act ................................ 661
R
A. Prior Disparate Impact Challenges to Property Tax
Assessment .......................................... 662
R
1. Coleman v. Seldin ............................... 662
R
2. MorningSide v. Sabree ........................... 665
R
B. Litigating Challenges to California’s Article XIIIA ..... 670
R
1. The Prima Facie FHA Case and Relevant Empirical
Evidence ........................................ 670
R
2. “Preservation, Continuity, and Stability”:
Legitimate? Nondiscriminatory? .................. 674
R
3. Less Discriminatory Alternatives .................. 677
R
C
ONCLUSION
.................................................... 680
R
I
NTRODUCTION
Property taxes fuel communities. They play a significant fiscal role for
state and local governments,
1
and taxpayers are acutely aware of their prop-
erty tax liability, thanks in part to large annual or semi-annual tax payments.
2
Nonetheless, property value assessment, an underpinning of property taxes,
1
Erin Adele Scharff, Powerful Cities?: Limits on Municipal Taxing Authority and What to
Do About Them, 91 N.Y.U. L. R
EV
. 292, 296 (2016) (referring to “the most important local
tax, the property tax”); see also Darien Shanske, Revitalizing Local Political Economy
Through Modernizing the Property Tax, 68 T
AX
L. R
EV
. 143, 144-45 (2014) (explaining how
the local property tax may be more efficient given that it operates at closer proximity to voters,
as compared to state or federal taxes, and may thus better influence, and respond to, voter
preferences).
2
David Gamage & Darien Shanske, Three Essays on Tax Salience: Market Salience and
Political Salience, 65 T
AX
L. R
EV
. 19, 39 (2011) (describing how “[p]roperty taxes are also
far more salient than smaller taxes on personal property and consumption”).
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 3 19-OCT-18 12:58
2018] Exclusionary Taxation 621
receives only sporadic scholarly attention.
3
Assessment may seem at first
blush to be a purely technical or ministerial matter. Under this perception, a
taxing jurisdiction mechanically assesses the property value, and then ap-
plies a mandated rate to determine the property tax.
However, property taxes, through their underlying assessments, may
fuel exclusion.
4
At their worst, property tax assessments have been used as
an explicit tool of racial subordination.
5
In response to African-American
activists’ boycotting of white-owned businesses during the 1960s civil rights
movement, one Mississippi county’s tax assessor raised the assessed value,
and therefore property taxes, for those activists.
6
Historian Andrew Kahrl
has chronicled how, in post-Civil Rights Act Mississippi, “[d]iscriminatory
assessment practices quietly but undeniably facilitated white wealth accumu-
lation through land[ownership] and homeownership while helping ensure
those same opportunities remained unavailable to black Americans.”
7
Even when discernable animus is absent, assessments reflect both over-
arching policy choices and discretionary administrative decisions that can
have significant impacts on property owners’ taxes.
8
Moreover, patterns of
relatively higher or lower assessment values, as related to market value, can
work to the disadvantage of particular racial or ethnic groups. This phenom-
3
Property tax litigation, and related press, is in fact often focused on the mechanics of
assessment practices. See, e.g., Allan Dodds Frank, Trump Organization seeks hefty tax break
for Westchester golf club, ABC N
EWS
, (June 21, 2017), http://abcnews.go.com/Politics/trump-
organization-seeks-hefty-tax-break-westchester-golf/story?id=48179222 [https://permacc/
JW94-7ZYY]; Eric Schmitt, L.I. Rebels Over Property Tax Rises, N.Y. T
IMES
, (Feb. 26,
1989), http://www.nytimes.com/1989/02/26/nyregion/li-rebels-over-property-tax-rises.html
[https://permacc/FM8M-K9FC] (documenting rancor in Long Island over property tax assess-
ments disputes and remedies).
4
Our description of tax assessments parallels Sarah Schindler’s unearthing of architec-
ture’s mischaracterization as “functional, innocuous, and prepolitical.” Sarah Schindler, Archi-
tectural Exclusion: Discrimination and Segregation Through Physical Design of the Built
Environment, 124 Y
ALE
L. J. 1934, 1934 (2013).
5
Williams v. City of Dothan, Ala., 745 F.2d 1406, 1408, 141415 (11th Cir. 1984) (re-
versing a grant of summary judgment against minority residents challenging “tax assessments
imposed by the city of Dothan, Alabama to pay for a street paving and sewer improvement
project in their neighborhood . . . [and] contend[ing] that the city has violated their equal
protection rights by contributing a lower percentage of municipal funds to this project than it
has contributed to comparable projects in the past which were located in predominantly white
areas”); see also Bland v. McHann, 463 F.2d 21, 23 (5th Cir. 1972) (holding that TIA and the
availability of plain, speedy, and efficient remedy precluded availability of § 1983 relief to
“Negro property owners (taxpayers) in Edwards charging that the 1966 increases in property
tax assessments of Negroes were solely the result of racial discrimination and were in retalia-
tion for the prior demonstrations”).
6
Andrew Kahrl, The Power to Destroy: Discriminatory Property Assessments and the
Struggle for Tax Justice in Mississippi, 82 J.
OF
S
O
. H
IST
. 579, 599602 (2016); see also
Bland, 463 F.2d at 23.
7
Kahrl, supra note 6, at 615.
R
8
We use the terms “property value assessment” and “property assessments” interchange-
ably. Although the statutory terminology varies by state, in this article, we refer to the determi-
nation of value of a property as its “assessment,” which is multiplied by the tax “rate” to
obtain the property tax amount.
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 4 19-OCT-18 12:58
622 Harvard Civil Rights-Civil Liberties Law Review [Vol. 53
enon has led to litigation from Chicago
9
to Long Island
10
to Berks County,
Pennsylvania,
11
to metropolitan Detroit.
12
Communities disadvantaged by tax
assessment practices may lack the political power to address policy choices,
and the available remedies for unfair assessment may be inaccessible or in-
adequate to address systemic inequities. As a result, these inequities may be
magnified and insulated by the very systems meant to ensure fairness.
13
In many states, the tax revolts of the 1970s and 80s
14
led to the adoption
of explicit caps on property assessment increases, most notably the acqui-
sition-value system created by California’s Proposition 13. The Proposition
became Article XIIIA of the state constitution.
15
Thanks to such caps, a
9
Rosewell v. LaSalle Nat. Bank, 450 U.S. 503 (1981) (invoking the TIA and deciding that
Illinois’s statutory remedy precluded federal jurisdiction over plaintiff’s claim for taxpayer re-
lief under 42 U.S.C. § 1983).
10
Coleman v. Seldin, 181 Misc. 2d 219 (N.Y. Sup. Ct. 1999).
11
Garrett v. Bamford, 582 F.2d 810, 812 (3d Cir. 1978).
12
MorningSide Cmty. Org. v. Wayne Cty. Treasurer, No. 336430, 2017 WL 4182985
(Mich. Ct. App. Sept. 21, 2017). Observers have further noted the race-contingent effects of
property tax regimes in Oregon, New York City, and New Haven, with empirical strategies of
varying rigor. Elliot Njus, Tax Breaks for Gentrifiers, T
HE
O
REGONIAN
(Sept. 11, 2015), http://
www.oregonlive.com/business/index.ssf/2015/09/measure_50_winners_and_losers.html
[https://permacc/MK3W-J9EN]; Andrew T. Hayashi, Property Taxes and Their Limits, 25
S
TAN
. L. & P
OL
Y
R
EV
. 33, 46 (2014); Lee Harris, ‘Assessing Discrimination’: The Influence of
Race in Residential Property Tax Assessments, 20 J. L
AND
U
SE
& E
NVTL
. L. 1, 1317 (2004).
13
For example, we discuss below the successful litigation to remedy unfair tax assess-
ments in Nassau County, New York. See, infra Section IV.A.1. However, a subsequent county
government has adopted a policy to significantly reduce assessments for property owners who
appeal their assessments, without corresponding reductions for other properties. This policy
has allegedly re-created stark racial disparities among Nassau County homeowners’ property
tax bills. See Matt Clark, Mangano’s overhaul created $1.7B property tax shift, N
EWSDAY
(Feb. 2, 2017), https://www.newsday.com/long-island/nassau/mangano-s-overhaul-created-1-
7b-property-tax-shift-1.13056134 [https://permacc/4LUM-HAPH].
14
I
SAAC
W
ILLIAM
M
ARTIN
, T
HE
P
ERMANENT
T
AX
R
EVOLT
: H
OW THE
P
ROPERTY
T
AX
T
RANSFORMED
A
MERICAN
P
OLITICS
47 (2008). Martin describes the tax revolts of the 1970s
as a rebellion against the local property tax; see also Marika Cabral & Caroline Hoxby, The
Hated Property Tax: Salience, Tax Rates, and Tax Revolts 24 (Nat’l Bureau of Econ. Research
Working Paper No. 18514, 2012), https://www.nber.org/papers/w18514 [https://permacc/
ST9H-397J] (defining property tax revolts as “generat[ing] property tax limits that success-
fully bind for many years” and noting that between 1970 and 2000, property taxes declined
from 3.3% to 2.5% of GDP).
15
See Cal. C
ONST
. art. XIIIA, § 2(a). For a discussion of tax revolts, see generally
Schmitt, supra note 3; Darien Shanske, How Less Can Be More: Using the Federal Income
Tax to Stabilize State and Local Finance, 31 V
A
. T
AX
R
EV
. 413, 44445 (2012) (describing
Proposition 13 as the “first shot of the modern property tax revolt”); W
ILLIAM
F
ISCHEL
, T
HE
H
OMEVOTER
H
YPOTHESIS
11119 (2001) (arguing that Proposition 13 was a response to the
California courts’ decision to equalize school finance); M
ARTIN
, supra note 14 (arguing, in
contrast to Fischel, that property owners were systematically, if informally, under-assessed
prior to Proposition 13, which simply formalized that privilege in response to the looming
modernization of the property tax). For further information on state property tax freeze and
assessment freeze programs in 14 states, see N
AT
L
C
ONF
.
OF
S
TATE
L
EGISLATURES
, S
TATE
P
ROPERTY
T
AX
F
REEZE AND
A
SSESSMENT
F
REEZE
P
ROGRAMS
(2012), http://www.ncsl.org/re-
search/fiscal-policy/state-property-tax-freezes-and-assessment-freezes.aspx [https://permacc/
TNT9-D33B].
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 5 19-OCT-18 12:58
2018] Exclusionary Taxation 623
house can have a vastly larger tax assessment than the identical house next
door.
16
These property tax systems, including the oft-challenged but so-far im-
pervious California system, likely violate federal civil rights law. The Fair
Housing Act places limits on policies, including tax policies, that dispropor-
tionately disadvantage and exclude racial minorities and other members of
protected classes without proper justification.
17
Thus, borrowing from chal-
lenges to “exclusionary zoning” and other “barrier” practices that form the
historic core of FHA disparate impact claims,
18
we label such discriminatory
tax policies as “exclusionary taxation.”
19
Such taxation can exclude in two
main ways. First, it can have the effect of disproportionately taxing or expro-
priating housing from members of a particular racial or ethnic group. Or it
can exclude by entrenching segregated housing patterns (such as by encour-
16
In the California context, the disparity is potentially based on when the owners took
possession of the property. California’s ceilings apply to most ad valorem property taxes. See
C
AL
. C
ONST
. art. XIIIA, § 1(b)(2)-(3) (permitting a narrow class of additional ad valorem taxes
to finance bond indebtedness for particular municipal improvements). But, they have permit-
ted, and arguably encouraged, the introduction of parcel taxes. In 1982, California passed the
Mello-Roos Community Facilities Act of 1982, C
AL
. G
OV
T
C
ODE
§53311-53368.3 (West
2018). See generally C
ALIFORNIA
T
AXPAYERS
A
SSOCIATION
, T
HE
O
THER
P
ROPERTY
T
AX
1
(2013), http://www.caltax.org/ParcelTaxPolicyBrief.pdf [https://permacc/3SDT-AKRV]
(describing how a parcel tax is different than an ad valorem tax in that it is imposed on a per-
parcel, rather than value, basis); C
ALIFORNIA
T
AXPAYERS
A
SSOCIATION
, P
IECING
T
OGETHER
C
ALIFORNIA
S
P
ROPERTY
T
AXES
1, 2 (2014) (“Of the parcel taxes identified, 64 percent were
imposed under the Mello-Roos Act. Generally, Mello-Roos parcel taxes are approved by land-
owners to fund new development, and, once debt payments on development are repaid, the
taxes expire. However, approximately 12.7 percent of Mello-Roos parcel taxes are levied in-
definitely to fund police services, fire services, public transit, education, or other services,
without ever being approved by the general electorate
and almost all include an annual in-
crease to adjust for inflation.”).
In Oregon, which does not even reassess on resale, similarly valued houses are taxed radi-
cally differently, based on the value they held years ago. Northwest Economic Research
Center, O
REGON
P
ROPERTY
T
AX
C
APITALIZATION
3, 56 (2014), http://media.oregonlive.com/
portland_impact/other/locreport.pdf [https://permacc/DVN4-GZLD] (estimating how differ-
ences in assessed values and “real market values” are capitalized into sale prices).
17
See infra Sections III.A and III.B.
18
See Tex. Dep’t of Hous. & Cmty. Affairs v. Inclusive Cmtys. Project, Inc., 135 S. Ct.
2507, 2511 (2015) (“Suits targeting unlawful zoning laws and other housing restrictions that
unfairly exclude minorities from certain neighborhoods without sufficient justification are at
the heartland of disparate-impact liability.”); Stacy Seicshnaydre, Is Disparate Impact Having
Any Impact? An Appellate Analysis of Forty Years of Disparate Impact Claims Under the Fair
Housing Act, 63 A
M
. U. L. R
EV
. 357, 36063 (2013) (describing how the earliest FHA dispa-
rate impact cases challenged “housing barrier” regulation, which may operate in several ways,
including “to prevent the construction of housing that will likely be used by minority groups in
places that currently lack minority residents; to confine housing that will be used by minority
group members to neighborhoods where minority households already predominate; or to other-
wise deny minority households freedom of movement in a wider housing marketplace.”).
19
We also label these practices “exclusionary taxation” to avoid confusion with the con-
cept of “tax discrimination,” which often refers to the relative overtaxation of “foreign” enti-
ties in federal or confederal systems. See Ruth Mason & Michael S. Knoll, What is Tax
Discrimination?, 121 Y
ALE
L.J. 1014, 101722 (2012). While tax scholars might nonetheless
point out the overlapping terminology of inclusion and exclusion in American income tax, we
think such shared semantics will lead to negligible confusion.
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 6 19-OCT-18 12:58
624 Harvard Civil Rights-Civil Liberties Law Review [Vol. 53
aging a lack of mobility), which limit the ability of members of that group to
move into certain areas.
This Article focuses on one form of exclusionary taxation involving
property tax assessment policies. As reflected in the examples discussed be-
low, artificially inflated or deflated property assessments lead to higher (or
lower) tax bills, potentially leading to foreclosure and entrenching existing
housing patterns. Future research into other forms of exclusionary taxation
may be fruitful. For example, there is a long history of FHA litigation chal-
lenging zoning regulations that disadvantage multifamily housing, as com-
pared to single-family housing, under the theory that multifamily housing is
more commonly occupied by non-white racial groups. A pending FHA law-
suit in New York City challenges, in part, similar preferential treatment for
single-family properties in the New York City property tax scheme.
20
Surprisingly, despite sporadic litigation to challenge tax assessments
under constitutional and state-law theories, scholars have been slow to ac-
knowledge potential exclusionary taxation claims.
21
We look beyond the bet-
ter-known and generally unsuccessful litany of constitutional claims to
explore such federal statutory challenges. Though some property tax litiga-
tion has raised claims under the FHA, there has yet to be a substantive merits
decision illuminating the meaning of “fair housing” in the context of prop-
erty taxes.
22
This Article is thus among the first to systematically describe how
property tax assessment policies could have an unjustified disparate impact
along racial or ethnic lines in violation of federal civil rights law.
23
We ex-
amine the trends that procedurally limited remedies for such discriminatory
taxation and the recent countertrends facilitating property tax challenges
20
Compare Complaint, Tax Equity Now NY LLC v. City of New York, No. 153759/2017
(Sup. Ct. N.Y. Cnty. Apr. 25, 2017) [hereinafter Tax Equity Complaint] (alleging unequal tax
treatment of multifamily rental properties) with Warth v. Seldin, 422 U.S. 490, 49596 (1975)
(describing as “exclusionary zoning” a zoning scheme that sharply limits multifamily
housing).
21
See, e.g., Eduardo Mois´es Pe˜nalver, Regulatory Taxings, 104 C
OLUM
. L. R
EV
. 2182,
2201 (2004) (“Consistent with the extremely deferential standard of review of the state’s exer-
cise of its tax power, highly unequal property taxes will be upheld as long as the basis for the
unequal treatment is not wholly arbitrary.”). Pe˜nalver neglects the legal scrutiny potentially
placed on such tax systems if the inequality relates to categories protected under the Fair
Housing Act. Bernadette Atuahene stands as a prominent exception, having begun a detailed
analysis of housing discrimination in the context of Detroit’s tax foreclosures, which is dis-
cussed in further detail below. See Bernadette Atuahene & Timothy Hodge, Stategraft, 91 S
O
.
C
AL
. L. R
EV
. 2 (2018); Bernadette Atuahene, “Our Taxes Are Too Damn High”: Institutional
Racism, Property Tax Assessment, and the Fair Housing Act, 112 N
W
. L. R
EV
1501 (2018).
22
The pending New York City case may provide the first such decision, though, like the
challenges to Nassau County’s system decades ago, the parties might simply settle first. See
Tax Equity Complaint, supra note 20.
R
23
We use federal fair housing law as synonymous with the Fair Housing Act because of
its disparate impact theory. However, federal fair housing law includes 42 U.S.C. §§ 1981 and
1982, which, like the Equal Protection clause, have been interpreted to require proof of intent.
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 7 19-OCT-18 12:58
2018] Exclusionary Taxation 625
under the FHA.
24
Litigation under the FHA can resuscitate fair taxation from
the constitutional graveyard.
25
With an eye toward California’s acquisition-value approach to property
assessment, we use the seemingly narrow issue of property tax assessments
to examine the country’s changing demographics and attendant challenges
facing American communities.
26
We unpack the “stability” rationale that
courts have embraced to justify property tax systems, noting its inconsisten-
cies with the evolution envisioned by the FHA.
In Part I, we offer a primer on the facets of the property tax most rele-
vant to our argument, including a summary of California’s system. We also
examine briefly the need to look beyond “efficiency” considerations that
have historically dominated law and economics literature to fully understand
the nature of fair property taxation and the origins of the “tax revolt.”
In Part II, we scrutinize the doctrinal efforts that both federal and state
courts have taken to disengage with challenges to property tax assessments,
including those that are allegedly discriminatory. This jurisdictional and pro-
cedural disengagement is grounded in the Tax Injunction Act (TIA); the doc-
trine of comity, a particularly deferential standard of constitutional review;
and inconsistent and insufficient procedures and fora at the state level.
In Part III, we argue that a triplet of Supreme Court decisions in recent
years has demanded a more meaningful vindication of federal, property tax-
payer rights. The Court confirmed the availability of disparate impact claims
under the FHA in Texas Department of Housing & Community Affairs v.
Inclusive Communities Project, Inc.
27
empowering homeowners who could
not prove that their unfair taxes resulted from explicit animus. Further, Hay-
wood v. Drown
28
reasserted federal supremacy in the face of subversive state
jurisdiction rules, and Direct Marketing Association v. Brohl
29
cabined the
reach of jurisdictional challenges to tax litigation.
24
Infra Section II.A and Part III.
25
Early litigation challenging Proposition 13 relied on claims under California’s state con-
stitution. See, e.g., Amador Valley Joint Union High Sch. Dist. v. State Bd. of Equalization,
583 P.2d 1281, 1284 (Cal. 1978) (rejecting constitutional challenges to four distinct elements
of Proposition 13). Despite that litigation’s failure, state law may continue to play a role, but
we focus on the surprisingly robust floor of fair property taxation inscribed in federal law.
26
Douglas Massey & Jonathan Tannen, A Research Note on Trends in Black Hypersegre-
gation, 52 D
EMOGRAPHY
1024, 1033 (“Although hypersegregation may have become less
common in recent years, it hasn’t disappeared, but has instead become centered in a subset of
metropolitan areas containing some of the nation’s largest black communities. . . [W]e can
continue to expect a disproportionate share of the nation’s racial conflicts and disturbances to
occur within these intensely segregated landscapes.”); see also Anderson, infra note 281
(describing challenges facing cities in twenty-first century America); Cristina M. Rodr´ıguez,
The Significance of the Local in Immigration Regulation, 106 M
ICH
. L. R
EV
. 567, 58190
(2008) (describing ways in which states and localities can integrate, and have integrated, re-
cent immigrants despite the doctrine of federal exclusivity in immigration law).
27
135 S. Ct. 2507 (2015).
28
556 U.S. 729 (2009).
29
135 S. Ct. 1124 (2015).
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 8 19-OCT-18 12:58
626 Harvard Civil Rights-Civil Liberties Law Review [Vol. 53
In Part IV, we use litigation case studies to show how the FHA can
address property tax assessment policies that discriminate without adequate
justification. After examining lessons from two existing FHA lawsuits
against exclusionary taxation, we explore a prospective FHA challenge to
California’s system. We note particularly strong concerns about the ability of
children and grandchildren to receive the tax benefits accorded to their par-
ents and grandparents. We further examine the meaning and legitimacy of
“stability” as a substantial interest under the FHA, particularly amidst com-
peting and evolving visions of local communities. Any defensible concep-
tion of stability must accommodate the federal mandate to make figurative
and literal room for an increasingly diverse America. And while interven-
tions can be targeted to stabilize those who might otherwise be displaced
from their communities, they must not stabilize exclusive conceptions of the
communities themselves.
I. A P
ROPERTY
T
AX
P
RIMER
We begin by explaining the role of the property tax and how property
value assessments are determined. We then provide a summary of Califor-
nia’s Article XIIIA, which was unsuccessfully challenged on constitutional
grounds. We conclude by explaining why existing efficiency considerations
guiding property tax scholarship are legally and theoretically insufficient.
A. The Role of the Property Tax & Assessment
Local tax policy reflects policy makers’ divergent visions for their com-
munities. Different jurisdictions adopt different levels of revenue and public
services. They make varying decisions about how progressive the tax system
should be, what matters should be incentivized by the tax code, and the
blend of revenue sources upon which to rely.
30
Such variation in tax administration has deep historical roots. Origi-
nally, local property taxes primarily fell on agricultural land, but in the nine-
teenth century, they shifted to cover other property classes and to serve as
“commitment devices” to fund public projects across localities.
31
During the
twentieth century, states increasingly transferred the authority to tax real
30
Eric M. Zolt, Inequality, Collective Action, and Taxing and Spending Patterns of State
and Local Governments, 62 T
AX
L. R
EV
. 445, 447 (2009); cf. Bridget Crawford & Carla Spiv-
ack, Tampon Taxes, Discrimination, and Human Rights, W
IS
. L. R
EV
. 491, 496-97 (2017)
(discussing varying tax policy choices in adopting the sales tax and exempting certain products
from taxation).
31
John Joseph Wallis, The Property Tax as a Coordinating Device: Financing Indiana’s
Mammoth Internal Improvement System, 1835 to 1842, at 2 (Nat’l Bureau of Econ. Research
Working Paper, Historical Paper No. 136, 2001), http://www.nber.org/papers/h0136.pdf
[https://permacc/G7E4-VCLD].
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 9 19-OCT-18 12:58
2018] Exclusionary Taxation 627
property to local governments.
32
Local property tax revenue now reflects
approximately half a trillion dollars of revenue, and has, in recent history,
exceeded federal corporate income tax.
33
Property taxes are generally “ad valorem” taxes
taxes based on some
measure of value, as opposed to, for example, number of parcels or acre-
age.
34
To administer an ad valorem tax, jurisdictions must conduct assess-
ments by identifying taxable properties, their values, and the corresponding
taxes due.
35
Property “value” thus serves as the foundation of property tax,
36
but value assessments occur with heterogeneous frequency depending on ju-
risdiction.
37
In most states, a local government serves as the property value
and tax “assessing unit” under the monitoring of a statewide agency that
sets standards.
38
Assessing jurisdictions generally use a current market value
approach to assess residential real estate.
39
32
Zolt, supra note 30, at 472. For a much broader and compelling discussion of tax policy
R
changes during this period, see generally A
JAY
M
EHROTRA
, M
AKING THE
M
ODERN
A
MERICAN
F
ISCAL
S
TATE
: L
AW
, P
OLITICS
,
AND THE
R
ISE OF
P
ROGRESSIVE
T
AXATION
, 1877-1929 134
(2013) (describing the transition from a more obscure and piecemeal 19th century tax system
to a professionalized, progressive one reflecting distinct values).
33
J
OAN
Y
OUNGMAN
, A G
OOD
T
AX
ix (2016). According to the Lincoln Institute of Land
Policy, the average effective owner-occupant tax rate for the 50 largest US cities in about
1.5%, with a range from .44% in Colorado Springs to 3.82% in Detroit. The average of the
estimated tax bills for each city’s median home is $3,343. L
INCOLN
C
ENTER FOR
L
AND
P
OLICY
& M
INNESOTA
C
ENTER FOR
F
ISCAL
E
XCELLENCE
, 50-S
TATE
P
ROPERTY
T
AX
C
OMPARISON
S
TUDY
64 (2016), http://www.lincolninst.edu/sites/default/files/pubfiles/50-state-property-tax-
comparison-for-2016-full.pdf [https://permacc/44W9-NDWL].
34
Stewart E. Sterk & Mitchell L. Engler, Property Tax Reassessment: Who Needs It?, 81
N
OTRE
D
AME
L. R
EV
. 1037, 1041 (2006).
35
Timothy Schiller, What’s It Worth? Property Taxes and Assessment Practices, Q3
P
HILA
. R
ES
. B
ANK
B
US
. R
EV
. 21, 23 (2011) (defining property tax assessment broadly as “the
process by which a taxing authority [i] identifies taxable properties, [ii] determines who is
responsible for paying taxes on them, [iii] assigns values to them for taxation, and [iv] calcu-
lates the tax liability of the property.”).
36
Property values are assessed in different manners and with different frequencies. Sterk
& Engler, supra note 34, at 1042-44. The property tax is generally calculated off the assessed
R
value, in conjunction with the property class-specific tax rate, net any exemptions.
37
This heterogeneity reflects various concerns, only some of which are technical. Reas-
sessments do not typically focus on all property in a given revaluation year. Richard Henry
Carlson, A Brief History of Property Tax, F
AIR
& E
QUITABLE
3 (Feb. 2005), http://www.iaao
.org/uploads/A_Brief_History_of_Property_Tax.pdf [https://permacc/KSC9-FQNE]. Some
states impose no duty for reassessment but may provide incentives for assessing jurisdictions
to do so, while others require frequent reassessment. Sterk & Engler, supra note 34, at 1042.
R
Some commentators have proposed an intermediate proposal, whereby “taxes for each owner-
ship year would be recalculated at sale by averaging the homeowner’s purchase and sales
prices.” Id. at 1040.
38
Schiller, supra note 35, at 23. Generally, a property is assessed by only one jurisdiction.
R
But see N.Y. S
TATE
D
EP
TOF
T
AXATION AND
F
INANCE
, A
SSESSORS
, https://www.tax.ny.gov/pit/
property/learn/assessors.htm [https://permacc/YTG6-LPDD] (“New York is only state in the
nation where property owners can receive two separate assessments for the same property.”).
39
Laura Bucher Murphy, Cafo Grief: Using Tax Grieving Procedures to Protest Indus-
trial Animal Factories, 23 J. E
NVTL
. L. & L
ITIG
. 357, 364 (2008). Methods commonly used for
commercial, industrial, or agricultural property, may value property according to the income-
generating capacity (the income method) or the cost to replace the structures on the property
(the cost method). To identify market value, jurisdictions often use a sales comparison ap-
proach for residential real estate (the actual sale prices of similar properties). Schiller, supra
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 10 19-OCT-18 12:58
628 Harvard Civil Rights-Civil Liberties Law Review [Vol. 53
Many tax assessors are elected, and regardless of the method of selec-
tion, they may face political pressures concerning the mechanics of property
tax administration.
40
These political pressures can lead assessors to privilege
more politically powerful groups, including racial and ethnic majorities.
41
Formalized processes notwithstanding, property tax assessments may reflect
“gut feeling”
42
or methods poorly understood by the public.
43
When the val-
uation procedures leave taxpayers aggrieved, either in accordance with the
law or in spite of it, those taxpayers may appeal through the particular chan-
nels available in their state, which we will detail in Section II.B.
B. The Tax Revolt and Proposition 13
California provides a paradigmatic example of how state law shapes
property tax assessment. In 1978, California voters passed Proposition 13,
enacting an amendment to the state constitution capping the property tax rate
and limiting the growth of property tax assessments.
44
Proposition 13
adopted an acquisition-value assessment system
45
that placed a state consti-
note 35, at 25. Residential appraisals occur through “mass,” rather than individual, appraisal.
R
Mass appraisals reflect large data sets of other property with adjustments for particular attrib-
utes of property under appraisal, of which computer-assisted mass appraisal (CAMA) is a
popular subgenre. Id. at 24. In mass appraisals, the actual sales price of a property is not the
direct basis of its valuation for the purposes of tax assessment.
40
For example, the California Constitution requires that county assessors be elected. C
AL
.
C
ONST
. art. XI, § 4(c). As of 1994, assessment officials in 30 states were elected, rather than
appointed. Robert P. Strauss & Sean R Sullivan, The Political Economy of The Property Tax:
Assessor Authority And Assessment Uniformity, 91 P
ROCEEDINGS
. A
NN
. C
ONF
.
ON
T
AXATION
AND
M
INUTES OF THE
A
NN
. M
EETING OF THE
N
AT
L
T
AX
A
SS
N
254, 255 (1998). However,
some local governments within a state vary in their method of selection for assessors. See, e.g.,
V
A
. C
ODE
A
NN
. § 58.1-3270 (allowing local governments to choose whether assessment is
performed by the elected commissioner of revenue or an appointed official).
41
See Justin M. Ross, Assessor Incentives & Property Assessment, 77 S. E
CON
. J. 776,
792 (2011) (finding a correlation between racial homogeneity
which decreases the political
power of racial minorities
and overassessment, as well as a trend toward underassessment by
elected rather than appointed assessors).
42
City of Biddeford v. Adams, 1999 ME 49, ¶ 3, 727 A.2d 346, 350 (Me. 1999) (“[The
assessor] stated that he granted the 12.5% decrease based on his ‘gut feeling.’”). That is not to
suggest that statistical methods do not rely on their own sets of potentially problematic and
non-transparent assumptions.
43
See, e.g., F
INAL
R
EPORT OF THE
S
ENATE
P
ROPERTY
T
AX
A
SSESSMENTS AND
A
PPEALS
S
TUDY
C
OMMITTEE
, G
EORGIA
S
ENATE
P
ROPERTY
T
AX
A
SSESSMENTS AND
A
PPEALS
S
TUDY
C
OMMITTEE
67 (2009), http://www.senate.ga.gov/sro/Documents/StudyCommRpts/09Proper
tyTaxAssessmentRpt.pdf [https://permacc/YU8X-A2QK] (noting that the public was inten-
tionally excluded from statutorily required trainings for tax office employees, assessors, and
boards of equalization).
44
C
AL
. C
ONST
. art. XIIIA (as adopted 1978). Various scholars have advanced causes for
the passage of Proposition 13. William Fischel argued that it was a response to the California
Supreme Court’s decision requiring the equalization of school district finances, severing the tie
between local taxes and that most prized of local goods, school quality. W
ILLIAM
F
ISCHEL
, T
HE
H
OMEVOTER
H
YPOTHESIS
11118 (2001).
45
C
AL
. S
TATE
B
OARD OF
E
QUALIZATION
, C
ALIFORNIA
P
ROPERTY
T
AX
: A
N
O
VERVIEW
, at 1
(Pub. 29, July 2015), http://www.boe.ca.gov/proptaxes/pdf/pub29.pdf [https://permacc/4CAC-
2NK4].
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 11 19-OCT-18 12:58
2018] Exclusionary Taxation 629
tutional ceiling on property tax assessment growth, administered by a de-
tailed statutory scheme.
46
Acquisition-value assessment systems anchor the assessed value of a
property to the value determined at acquisition.
47
Eighteen other states and
several localities have also adopted acquisition-value taxation systems or an-
other limitation on the growth of property assessments.
48
These systems
often have significant political support. Proposition 13 has been described as
an “impregnable institution” in the California political landscape.
49
California’s scheme, as further amended by later ballot propositions,
50
has five significant components for residential properties. First, the annual
property tax rate is assessed on the “full cash value,” which is constitution-
ally defined as the “valuation on the 1975-76 tax bill or, thereafter, the ap-
praised value of real property when purchased, newly constructed, or a
change in ownership has occurred.”
51
If the fair market value exceeds the
full cash value in any given year, the full cash value can be increased only
by the lesser of the rate of inflation
52
or 2% of the adjusted acquisition cost.
53
At the individual level, the property tax benefit is economically significant.
46
As Joan Youngman has aptly noted, “Proposition 13 in California does not call for
unchanging assessments, but it achieves near complete predictability through a fixed 1 percent
tax rate and an assessment generally based on the purchase price of the property (or the 1975-
1976 value, for property that has not changed hands since that time).” J
OAN
Y
OUNGMAN
, A
G
OOD
T
AX
40 (2016).
47
As Joan Youngman writes, “[a] property’s maximum assessment is rigidly constrained
under an acquisition value system, but a drop in market values below that limit will generally
cause assessed value to fall as well. The assessment cannot rise above the inflation-adjusted
acquisition value, but in most cases it can fall by any amount-and rise by any amount-so long
as it remains below that limit.” Id. at 196.
48
See, e.g., Melissa J. Morrow, Comment, Twenty-Five Years of Debate: Is Acquisition-
Value Property Taxation Constitutional? Is It Fair? Is It Good Policy?, 53 E
MORY
L.J. 587,
59495 (2004) (“States that have adopted such limitations include Arizona, California, Iowa,
New Mexico, New York, Michigan, and Florida. Varying from two to six percent, these assess-
ment limitations prevent the government from garnering increased revenues due to rising prop-
erty values.”); S
IGNIFICANT
F
EATURES OF THE
P
ROPERTY
T
AX
, L
INCOLN
I
NSTITUTE
, http://
datatoolkits.lincolninst.edu/subcenters/significant-features-property-tax/Re-
port_Tax_Limits.aspx [https://permacc/ARZ4-9PTM] (last visited Feb. 26, 2017) (relying in
part on D
ANIEL
M
ULLINS
& K
IMBERLY
C
OX
, T
AX AND
E
XPENDITURES
L
IMITS ON
L
OCAL
G
OV-
ERNMENTS
(1995)).
49
Kevin O’Leary, The Legacy of Proposition 13, T
IME
(June 27, 2009), http://content.time
.com/time/nation/article/0,8599,1904938,00.html [https://permacc/5FU8-YT4V].
50
For example, Proposition 13 did not actually deal with declines in fair market value
until six months after its 1978 passage when Proposition 8 specified assessment on the lower
of the existing taxable value or the current market value. Note however that “[i]ncreases to a
Prop 8 assessment are not subject to the 2% increase limitation as are Prop 13 values. A Prop 8
value may be increased or decreased, depending on market activity in your neighborhood.
Once the real estate market begins to recover, assessed values will be increased until they are
restored to their Prop 13 factored base year values. At no point can the value be increased
above your factored Prop 13 value.” Alameda Cty. Assessor, Why Assessed Value May In-
crease More Than 2%, https://www.acgov.org/assessor/about_property_assessment/may-in-
crease.htm [https://permacc/UNK4-PJYJ] (last visited May 22, 2018).
For the amendments on inheritability, see infra notes 5657.
R
51
C
AL
. C
ONST
. art. XIIIA, § 2(a).
52
The rate of inflation is currently defined by statute.
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 12 19-OCT-18 12:58
630 Harvard Civil Rights-Civil Liberties Law Review [Vol. 53
As our back-of-the-envelope calculations demonstrate, someone who
purchases or has recently purchased a small home in coastal Northern Cali-
fornia might pay the equivalent of an additional 20% of their (already signif-
icant) mortgage payment to cover the additional property taxes they owe as
compared to a neighbor who purchased her property in 1980.
54
The large
premium is partly a product of the particularly low annual assessment
growth ceiling in California (2%). Yet even in the absence of a ceiling, Cali-
fornia’s formula would still produce significant disparities by tying assess-
ment growth to inflation (which has trailed real estate appreciation).
55
Second, and of particular demographic import, post-Proposition 13 con-
stitutional amendments assure that children and grandchildren largely do not
incur a reassessment when they inherit or purchase property from parents
and grandparents.
56
Third, many homeowners over the age of 55 can carry
53
Today, the market value of a typical California home purchased in 1980 is more than
twice its assessed value. L
EGISLATIVE
A
NALYST
S
O
FFICE
, C
OMMON
C
LAIMS
A
BOUT
P
ROPOSI-
TION
13, 4 (2016).
54
Imagine two identical cottages purchased in Marin County, CA in 1980 for $100,000
(nominal). They are unrenovated and have 2016 market values of $1,000,000 (for a helpful
graphic displaying Bay Area valuation changes from 1980 based on the Case-Shiller index, see
Blanca Torres, Bay Area Home Values, S.F. Chron. (June 24, 2014), https://www.bizjournals
.com/sanfrancisco/blog/real-estate/2014/06/bay-area-home-prices-san-francisco-case-shiller
.html#i1 [https://permacc/XR2F-NMZV]). The first remains owner-occupied and the value
assessment increases by an annual inflation factor, capped at 2%. See C
AL
. S
TATE
B
OARD OF
E
QUALIZATION
, F
INAL
I
NFLATION
F
ACTORS FOR
P
RIOR
Y
EARS
(2015), https://www.boe.ca.gov/
proptaxes/pdf/lta15055.pdf [https://permacc/TG5H-2EY9]. Utilizing these year-specific fac-
tors beginning in 1980-81 and ending with 2015-16, the value assessment in 2016 is $188,474.
The homeowner pays 1% of that amount for a $1,885 annual, or $157 monthly, property tax
payment. In contrast, the prospective or recently arrived homeowner for the neighboring cot-
tage will pay 1% of $1,000,000, for a $10,000 annual, or $833 monthly, payment.
Thus, the capped tax assessment leads the new neighbor to pay $676 per month more in
property taxes. If the prospective homeowner purchased the $1,000,000 home with a 20%
down payment and 30-year-mortgage remaining for the $800,000, their monthly mortgage
payment, at a 3.5% interest rate, will be approximately $3,600 per month. The additional
property taxes, as compared to the neighbor’s, comprise an additional 19% monthly payment
($676 on top of the $3,600), and of course the premium would not disappear once the mort-
gage was paid off.
To be technically precise, this exercise abstracts away from a narrow class of additional ad
valorem taxes permitted in California to finance bond indebtedness for particular municipal
improvements, which exist in Marin County. See C
AL
. C
ONST
. art. XIIIA, § 1(b)(2)-(3).
55
Continuing the example from note 57, even with no growth ceiling, the value assess-
ment would become $363,198. (The annual California inflation rate peaked at 17% during the
relevant period, though it was usually closer to two percent.) The homeowner pays 1% of that
amount for a $3,632 annual, or about $303 monthly, property tax payment. Here, the capped
tax assessment leads the new neighbor to pay $530 per month more in property taxes (as
compared to the $833 monthly payment by new owners). The additional property taxes, as
compared to the neighbor’s under Proposition 13, equate to an additional 15% monthly mort-
gage payment ($530 on top of the $3,600).
56
Proposition 58 (Nov. 1986) created the safe harbor for transactions between parents and
children, and Proposition 193 (March 1996) expanded it to cover grandparent-grandchild
transactions. These protections are limited to the recipient’s primary residence and an addi-
tional $1 million of property transfer. The resulting propositions are codified at C
AL
. C
ONST
.
art. XIIIA § 2(h). See also Exclusions from Re-appraisal (Propositions 58 and 193), C
AL
.
S
TATE
B
OARD OF
E
QUALIZATION
(2017), https://www.boe.ca.gov/proptaxes/faqs/proposi-
tions58.htm#1 [https://permacc/JQ7N-BRE8].
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 13 19-OCT-18 12:58
2018] Exclusionary Taxation 631
their property assessment to a new home
further extending disparities as
homeowners are able to preserve tax privileges.
57
Fourth, the annual property
tax rate cannot exceed 1%, with only narrow exceptions.
58
Finally, the prop-
erty tax rate and assessment limitation apply broadly across all categories of
property, both residential and commercial.
59
In particular, the property tax
relief accorded residential property occurs regardless of owner-occupancy
and number of properties owned.
These tax limitations often have distortionary effects with different con-
sequences for different racial and ethnic communities.
60
Housing patterns
and values change over time in ways that sometimes correlate with race and
ethnicity. Tax systems that fail to account for value changes or disincentivize
moving can reinforce unequal and segregated housing patterns. Shortly after
Proposition 13 passed, the California Taxpayers’ Association noted a sharp
rise in other fees and non-ad valorem taxes, which are administered on a
basis other than in proportion to fair market value, such as per parcel.
61
Be-
cause the fees are restricted to new developments or service districts, these
fees hit newer residents harder. The parcel taxes thus further exacerbate Pro-
position 13’s effect of increasingly unequal tax burdens between old and
newer, increasingly diverse residents.
62
Additionally, scholars have
57
Proposition 60 (Nov. 1986) allowed for the transfer of the property assessment by a
person over the age of 55 from one primary residence to another within the same county.
Proposition 90 (Nov. 1988) allowed counties to accept intercounty assessment transfers, but
did not require counties to do so. As of 2015, eleven counties accept intercounty transfers
under Prop 90. See Exclusions from Re-appraisal (Propositions 60 and 90), C
AL
. S
TATE
B
OARD OF
E
QUALIZATION
(2017), http://www.boe.ca.gov/proptaxes/faqs/propositions60_90
.htm [https://permacc/ELZ2-LVCP].
58
C
AL
. L
EG
. A
NALYST
S
O
FFICE
, A L
OOK AT
V
OTER
-A
PPROVAL
R
EQUIREMENTS FOR
L
O-
CAL
T
AXES
, 2 http://www.lao.ca.gov/reports/2014/finance/local-taxes/voter-approval-032014
.aspx [https://permacc/F4NY-JMAG] (“The State Constitution limits, with narrow exceptions,
the property tax rate to 1 percent. Local governments may raise the property tax rate only for
two purposes: (1) to pay debt approved by voters prior to July 1, 1978 and (2) to finance bonds
for infrastructure projects.”).
59
At the end of 2017, multiple organizations sought a ballot initiative to secure a “split
roll,” that would reduce the benefits of Proposition 13 to commercial property. See Kevin
Modesti, Prop. 13 targeted by proposed California ballot initiative, O
RANGE
C
OUNTY
R
EGIS-
TER
(Dec. 19, 2017), https://www.ocregister.com/2017/12/19/prop-13-is-targeted-by-proposed-
california-ballot-initiative/ [https://permacc/AN7W-3AMC]. This proposal was previously
contained in a proposed constitutional amendment, Senate Constitutional Amendment No. 5
(Cal. 2015-2016), http://leginfo.legislature.ca.gov/faces/billTextClient.xhtml?bill_id=201520
160SCA5 [https://permacc/4NGF-ML8E].
60
See, e.g., infra Section IV.A.1 (discussing disparate consequences in the context of
Nassau County, New York).
61
Bill Stall, Levies, Fees Used to Offset Prop. 13: Finances: Cities, Counties and Special
Districts have Added a Variety of Assessments to Compensate for Losses in Property Tax Reve-
nues, L.A. T
IMES
(Oct. 11, 1993), http://articles.latimes.com/1993-10-11/news/mn-44713_1_
property-taxes [https://permacc/9U33-ZPCV]. See generally C
ALIFORNIA
T
AXPAYERS
A
SSOCI-
ATION
, T
HE
O
THER
P
ROPERTY
T
AX
(March 2013), http://www.caltax.org/ParcelTaxPolicyBrief
.pdf [https://permacc/F9BN-JFTY].
62
See Darien Shanske, Note, Public Tax Dollars for Private Suburban Development: A
First Report on a National Phenomenon, 26 V
A
. T
AX
R
EV
. 709, 763 (2007) (“Mello-Roos
taxes, along with impact fees, represent a further tax burden generally imposed on newer
homeowners or, put more precisely, on homeowners in newer neighborhoods.”); see also
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 14 19-OCT-18 12:58
632 Harvard Civil Rights-Civil Liberties Law Review [Vol. 53
bemoaned the resulting “fiscalization of land use law,” by which municipal
governments in California might, for example, prioritize retail over residen-
tial development because sales tax revenue is potentially more lucrative than
the peril of capped property taxes.
63
C. Fairness and the Law and Economics of Property Taxes
Law and economics scholarship provides thoughtful insights into the
efficient administration of the property tax, but efficiency considerations are
somewhat orthogonal to, or at least constrained by, the law’s equality- and
fairness-oriented mandates. Whatever the economic virtues, shortcomings,
or particular form of the property tax, the Fair Housing Act (FHA) requires
some equality in its application.
64
We propose below that the FHA includes a
precept of equitable taxation of housing that prohibits tax policies producing
inadequately justified disparate impacts on housing opportunity for different
groups. This concept of equitable taxation is distinct from optimal
65
or effi-
cient taxation. A deeply inefficient property system can create equal bur-
dens, just as a more efficient property system can create unequal burdens.
More concretely, a high tax jurisdiction may suffer from relatively low-qual-
ity schools and amenities due to poor planning and inefficient expenditures,
and yet each frustrated resident pays their fair share. In contrast, a low tax
jurisdiction might innovatively make use of its limited funds to provide for
high quality schools, but might have arcane and unjustified tax policies that
Building Industry Ass’n of the Bay Area v. City of San Ramon, 4 Cal. App. 5th 62, 67 (2016)
(holding that tax imposed upon developer to cover the cost to the city of providing services to
the new development was a qualifying “special” tax under Mello-Roos and therefore did not
violate California’s constitutional restriction, via Proposition 13, of such special taxes).
63
David J. Barron, Reclaiming Home Rule, 116 H
ARV
. L. R
EV
. 2255, 2346 (2003) (“In-
deed, some have faulted Proposition 13’s restrictions on local property taxation for having
induced a destructive interlocal scramble for commercial property, and the resulting sales tax
revenue that promotes the kind of sprawling, zero-sum development pattern that many critics
of home rule find problematic.”). See generally Scharff, supra note 1, at 312; Shanske, supra
R
note 62, at 764.
R
64
To that end, even prior to reassessment, ratio study audits can address concerns with the
assessment process, namely horizontal and vertical equity. See Daniel P. McMillen & Rachel
N. Weber, Thin Markets and Property Tax Inequities: A Multinomial Logit Approach, 61
N
AT
L
T
AX
J. 653, 654 (2008) (“Property tax assessment ratios
a property’s assessed value
divided by its market value
determine the effective tax rates paid by owners and . . . [w]hen
ratios in the same assessment district vary, the property tax will not be applied uniformly.”).
Horizontal and vertical equity refer, respectively, to the claims “that persons with equal life-
time resources should face equal lifetime tax burdens, and that those with higher lifetime
resources should face higher lifetime tax burdens than those with lower lifetime resources.”
Lawrence Zelenak, Tax Policy and Personal Identity over Time, 62 T
AX
L. R
EV
. 333, 346
(2009).
65
Optimal taxation theories generally consider consumer behavior and elasticities in max-
imizing social surplus. The concept of optimal taxation has recently attracted considerable
attention in the context of commodity taxes, a literature pioneered by Frank Ramsey. F.P.
Ramsey, A Contribution to the Theory of Taxation, 37 E
CON
. J. 47 (1927); see also Raj Chetty,
Adam Looney, & Kory Kroft, Salience and Taxation: Theory and Evidence, 99 A
M
. E
CON
.
Rev. 1145 (2009) (measuring, and incorporating, salience and behavioral responses to augment
the canonical model).
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 15 19-OCT-18 12:58
2018] Exclusionary Taxation 633
disproportionately burden minorities. The Fair Housing Act’s legal mandate
empowers those aggrieved by tax inequity (if that inequity falls on the axis
of a protected classification) while providing little relief to those aggrieved
by tax inefficiency.
66
Federal law thus limits tax policies discriminating on
characteristics of the (prospective) property owner, though tax policies regu-
larly and permissibly discriminate on characteristics of the property itself.
67
While the questions of efficiency might be somewhat orthogonal, they
do play a role in the competing narratives surrounding Proposition 13. Some
have praised the economic virtues of property taxes as exemplifying the Tie-
bout hypothesis,
68
whereby local goods are purchased with local taxes and
allow for residential segregation based on preferences and willingness-to-
pay for amenities. The economist William Fischel has characterized Proposi-
tion 13 in Tiebout terms by arguing that it was a reaction to the California
Supreme Court’s decisions in Serrano v. Priest,
69
which struck down the
inequities produced by California’s earlier school financing system. Accord-
ing to Fischel, these decisions “crippled the Tiebout system by divorcing
local property wealth from school spending.”
70
Under this theory, Proposi-
tion 13, which passed on Serrano’s tails, can be construed as taxpayers refus-
66
Tax efficiency in this context relates to the community benefits acquired through a
given amount of tax collection while tax inequity refers to differences in burdens between
diverse property owners with nonetheless similar properties. Our distinction between tax effi-
ciency and tax equality should not be confused with the large literature on the role of tax in
furthering equality. See, e.g., Louis Kaplow & Steven Shavell, Why the Legal System Is Less
Efficient Than the Income Tax in Redistributing Income, 23 J. L
EGAL
S
TUD
. 667, 667 (1994)
(arguing that “redistribution through legal rules offers no advantage over redistribution
through the income tax system and typically is less efficient.”); see also Chris William
Sanchirico, Deconstructing the New Efficiency Rationale, 86 C
ORNELL
L. R
EV
. 1003, 100710
(2001) (arguing against Kaplow and Shavell’s double-distortion argument and against using
efficiency as the sole guiding principle of legal rule design).
67
We are generally focused on property owners. Nonetheless, economists have pointed
out that the progressivity of property taxes depends, in part, on the incidence of the tax be-
tween property owners and renters. Thomas Piketty & Emmanuel Saez, How Progressive is
the U.S. Federal Tax System? A Historical and International Perspective, 21 J.
OF
E
CON
. P
ER-
SPECTIVES
3, 10 (2007) (“Overall, state and local taxes are believed to be somewhat regressive
but this depends on the assumed incidence of the property tax.”). There may still be analytic
room, outside the scope of this Article, to argue that in a renter-dominated society (or munici-
pality or town), if the incidence of the property tax falls upon the renters rather than the
property owners, the Fair Housing Act challenge might need to contemplate both the impact
on, and demographics of, renters and property owners.
68
Charles M. Tiebout, A Pure Theory of Local Expenditures, 64 J. P
OL
. E
CON
. 416 (1956);
see also Kirk Stark & Jonathan Zasloff, Tiebout and Tax Revolts: Did Serrano Really Cause
Proposition 13?, 50 UCLA L. Rev. 801, 81112 (2003) (noting that “[i]n the local setting,
individuals can shop among multiple jurisdictions, selecting membership in the community
that most closely matches their preferences for the appropriate mix of taxes and services.”);
Nestor M. Davidson & Sheila R. Foster, The Mobility Case for Regionalism, 47 U.C. D
AVIS
L.
R
EV
. 63, 76 (2013) (“Legal scholars have drawn on this [Tiebout] framework to argue for
devolution and decentralization in governmental authority and structure.”).
69
The three Serrano cases are Serrano v. Priest, 96 Cal. Rptr. 601 (1971) (Serrano I);
Serrano v. Priest, 135 Cal. Rptr. 345 (1976) (Serrano II); Serrano v. Priest, 141 Cal. Rptr. 315
(1977) (Serrano III). Proposition 13 passed in 1978.
70
William A. Fischel, Did “Serrano” Cause Proposition 13?, 42 N
AT
L
T
AX
J. 465,
46566 (1989).
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 16 19-OCT-18 12:58
634 Harvard Civil Rights-Civil Liberties Law Review [Vol. 53
ing to shoulder further local tax increases when those increases could no
longer fund locally consumed amenities.
71
In some sense, Fischel’s hypothe-
sis ties together efficiency and equity concerns by arguing that Proposition
13’s resulting inequities were catalyzed by conservative voters’ fears of post-
Serrano inefficiency.
Other analysts have disputed this account and advanced alternative ex-
planations.
72
For instance, Isaac William Martin suggested that the roots of
Proposition 13 may lie in the administrative modernization of the property
tax, which undermined previously hidden tax advantages for homeowners.
73
From this perspective, Proposition 13 formalized preexisting benefits for
homeowners. Martin also draws on individual voter survey data, as opposed
to only aggregated community-level data, to argue that there is little empiri-
cal evidence supporting the idea that Serrano catalyzed support for Proposi-
tion 13.
74
II. T
WENTIETH
C
ENTURY
W
ITHDRAWAL FROM
P
ROPERTY
T
AX
R
EVIEW
Notwithstanding recent Supreme Court decisions that subtly yet mean-
ingfully shift the procedural landscape,
75
American courts have been histori-
cally reluctant to adjudicate challenges to state and local tax systems. Over
the course of the twentieth century, both federal and state actors erected
strong barriers to meaningful judicial review of local tax policies.
Although the federal courts generally became more aggressive enforc-
ers of federally protected civil rights during the mid-twentieth century, the
Burger and Rehnquist Courts insulated state taxation from this trend through
procedural barriers and weakened constitutional standards for tax fairness.
As federal remedies were closed off, many states likewise restricted taxpay-
ers’ ability to challenge assessment regimes under state law.
The trends discussed below present challenges for homeowners who
seek to challenge systemically unfair property tax assessments, including
where that unfairness falls along racial lines.
71
Id. at 465.
72
Kirk Stark & Jonathan Zasloff, Tiebout and Tax Revolts, 50 U.C.L.A. L. R
EV
. 801, 850-
53 (2002) (finding no connection between Serrano and Proposition 13 and suggesting that it
was spurred by high property price inflation in California in the 1970s). But see William A.
Fischel, Did John Serrano Vote for Proposition 13?, 51 U.C.L.A. L. R
EV
. 887 (2004).
73
See, e.g., I
SAAC
W
ILLIAM
M
ARTIN
, T
HE
P
ERMANENT
T
AX
R
EVOLT
: H
OW THE
P
ROPERTY
T
AX
T
RANSFORMED
A
MERICAN
P
OLITICS
4-5 (2008) (“By modernizing and standardizing tax
assessment, the reformers did away with traditional and informal tax breaks that dated from
the late nineteenth century. Local tax assessors had dispensed these informal tax privileges
unevenly and often arbitrarily. But most homeowners received substantial benefit from them.
When they were swept away, homeowners fought to restore them in a new and permanent
form.” (emphasis added)).
74
Isaac W. Martin, Does School Finance Litigation Cause Taxpayer Revolt? Serrano and
Proposition 13, 40 L. & S
OCIETY
R
EV
. 525, 545 (2006).
75
See discussion infra Part III.
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 17 19-OCT-18 12:58
2018] Exclusionary Taxation 635
A. Federal Disengagement
At first, federal intervention in allegedly unlawful state taxation was
primarily constrained by general restrictions on federal-court injunctions.
Early cases from the nineteenth century grounded the hesitance to enjoin
taxes in the general limitations on equity jurisdiction
that an injunction
will not lie where there is a “plain, adequate, and complete remedy at law”
available in federal court.
76
In the 1930s, the Supreme Court and Congress
further restricted the power of federal courts to enjoin state taxes, culminat-
ing in the Tax Injunction Act.
77
First, in Matthews v. Rodgers, plaintiffs sought a federal injunction
against Mississippi’s allegedly unconstitutional taxes on those engaged in
buying or selling cotton.
78
The Court denied the injunction after describing
state-court refund procedures.
79
The “remedy at law in state court was
[ ]sufficient to defeat federal equitable jurisdiction,” effectively reversing
prior state tax injunction cases that had held that the remedy must have been
available in federal courts.
80
The Matthews Court characterized this rule as
“a proper reluctance to interfere by injunction with [states’] fiscal
operations.”
81
Lower federal courts nonetheless continued to enjoin state and local
taxes.
82
Possibly because of the relatively high amount-in-controversy re-
quirement for both federal question and diversity lawsuits, out-of-state cor-
porations were the predominant plaintiffs in these lawsuits, arousing
Congressional sympathy for state and local fiscs.
83
76
Dows v. City of Chicago, 78 U.S. 108, 10910, (1870); see also Allen v. Pullman’s
Palace Car Co., 139 U.S. 658, 661 (1891); Shelton v. Platt, 139 U.S. 591, 59899 (1891);
Pacific Exp. Co. v. Seibert, 142 U.S. 339, 348 (1892). The Supreme Court sometimes dis-
cussed the importance of taxation to the public fisc, but the holdings did not rely principally on
financial federalism concerns. See, e.g., Dows, 78 U.S. at 110.
The Court did, however, rely on federalism principles to reject the suggestion to allow any
unconstitutional tax to be enjoined, regardless of whether the other general requirements for an
injunction are met. Boise Artesian Hot & Cold Water Co. v. Boise City, 213 U.S. 276, 282
(1909) (noting a “proper reluctance to interfere by prevention with the fiscal operations of the
state governments . . . where the Federal rights of the persons could otherwise be preserved
unimpaired.”); see also Henrietta Mills v. Rutherford Cty., 281 U.S. 121, 127 (1930).
77
28 U.S.C. § 1341 (2012).
78
284 U.S. 521, 523 (1932).
79
Id. at 526.
80
John F. Coverdale, Remedies for Unconstitutional State Taxes, 32 C
ONN
. L. R
EV
. 73,
109 (1999) (“In 1932, the Supreme Court unanimously held that federal courts could not
entertain the equitable challenges to state taxes if an adequate remedy at law was available in
state court.”); see also Matthews v. Rogers, 284 U.S. 521, 52526 (1932).
81
Matthews, 284 U.S. at 52526 (internal citations omitted).
82
Note, Federal Court Interference with the Assessment and Collection of State Taxes, 59
H
ARV
. L. R
EV
. 780, 78283 (1946); see, e.g., Consolidation Coal Co. v. Martin, 113 F.2d 813
(6th Cir. 1940).
83
Note, Clarifying Comity: State Court Jurisdiction and Section 1983 State Tax Chal-
lenges, 103 H
ARV
. L. R
EV
. 1888, 189293 (1990).
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 18 19-OCT-18 12:58
636 Harvard Civil Rights-Civil Liberties Law Review [Vol. 53
In 1937, Congress passed the TIA, which provides: “The district courts
shall not enjoin, suspend or restrain the assessment, levy or collection of any
tax under State law where a plain, speedy and efficient remedy may be had
in the courts of such State.”
84
This language resembles the general standard
for equity jurisdiction, with two significant expansions. First, mirroring the
Matthews ruling, the statute prohibits an injunction where a remedy is avail-
able in state courts. Second, the TIA expanded on the Matthews ruling by
precluding a federal-court injunction for any “plain, speedy, and efficient”
remedy, whether at law or at equity. Congress described the purpose of the
act as addressing “the unfairness of requiring ‘the citizen of the State . . . to
pay first and then litigate, while those privileged to sue in the Federal courts
need only pay what they choose and withhold the balance during the period
of litigation.’
85
The Act was one of a series of Depression-era laws, coinci-
dent with “[t]he sales tax movement . . . associated primarily with the fiscal
emergencies of the States.”
86
The TIA’s new exception
“plain, speedy, and efficient”
became the
subject of judicial interpretation, and by the end of the twentieth century, the
TIA and related doctrines operated as an effective bar on many federal reme-
dies in taxation, regardless of venue.
87
This doctrinal shift occurred on two
axes: (i) the Court interpreted TIA’s principles of comity to preclude federal
damages remedies, and even certain injunctions in state court, while (ii) nar-
rowing the main safety valve
the requirement of a “plain, speedy, and effi-
cient” state remedy. We turn to each of these axes in turn and conclude by
briefly addressing a third factor
the deferential substantive standards ap-
plied by courts in reviewing property tax policies. Each of these changes
84
28 U.S.C. § 1341 (2012). The original wording differed, but “[t]he courts have treated
the rewording of the Act, which was part of the 1948 recodification of Title 28, as not affecting
the Act’s substance.” Peter D. Enrich, Federal Courts and State Taxes: Some Jurisdictional
Issues, with Special Attention to the Tax Injunction Act, 65 T
AX
L
AW
. 731, 741 n.65 (2012)
(citing Levin v. Commerce Energy, Inc., 130 S. Ct. 2323, 2335 n.10 (2010)).
85
Note, supra note 87 at 1892 (quoting S. REP. NO. 1035, 75th Cong., 1st Sess. 2
(1937)). Drawing on this legislative history, some courts in the 1970s had suggested that the
TIA only applied to diversity jurisdiction cases. Id. at 1892 (citing Fulton Mkt. Cold Storage
Co. v. Cullerton, 582 F.2d 1071, 107475 (7th Cir. 1978), cert. denied, 439 U.S. 1121 (1979);
Garrett v. Bamford, 538 F.2d 63, 67 (3d Cir. 1976), cert. denied, 429 U.S. 977 (1976)).
86
C
HARLES
A. T
ROST
, F
EDERAL
L
IMITATIONS ON
S
TATE AND
L
OCAL
T
AX
§ 11:1 (2d ed.
2017); see also R
OBERT
M
URRAY
H
AIG
& C
ARL
S
HOUP
, T
HE
S
ALES
T
AX
I
N
T
HE
A
MERICAN
S
TATES
324 (1934) (chronicling the factors that led to the widespread adoption of state-level
sales taxes).
87
Contemporaneous commentary suggested that the Court’s early cases interpreting the
statute were inconsistent with “the strong congressional policy of noninterference with state
fiscal operations.” Note, Federal Court Interference with the Assessment and Collection of
State Taxes, 59 H
ARV
. L. R
EV
. 780, 781 (1946). However, the Harvard Law Review, more than
fifty years later, suggested that the later expansive interpretation of the TIA contravened legis-
lative intent. Leading Cases, The Supreme Court, 2003 Term, 118 H
ARV
. L. R
EV
. 486 (2004)
(“Gradually over the course of the Act’s almost eighty-year history, its scope has been inter-
preted more expansively, diverging from the congressional intent behind it, so that [at the turn
of the twenty-first century] the TIA had come to stand for the broad principle that federal
courts must not interfere with any aspect of state tax systems.”).
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 19 19-OCT-18 12:58
2018] Exclusionary Taxation 637
continue to inhibit litigation on behalf of homeowners who face unfair tax
assessments.
1. Expansion of Comity
Comity broadly refers to a deference, or at least sensitivity, to state
authority and institutions.
88
In the mid-twentieth century, a revitalized Sec-
tion 1983
89
the Reconstruction-era statute creating a cause of action for
state constitutional violations
opened federal courthouse doors to constitu-
tional claims.
90
Taxpayers, however, were left shortchanged as their efforts
to challenge perceived constitutional infirmities in state tax regimes were
undermined by the Supreme Court’s expansion of the comity doctrine, apart
from the TIA, to bar such lawsuits.
91
Specifically, the Supreme Court ex-
panded comity to deter tax challenges in Fair Assessment in Real Estate
Ass’n, Inc. v. McNary and National Private Truck Council, Inc. v. Oklahoma
Tax Commissioner.
92
These decisions recognized tax-specific comity princi-
ples that reach beyond the text of the TIA
and beyond historical equity
jurisdictional principles
to significantly limit federal constitutional dam-
ages claims and constitutional claims in state courts.
In Fair Assessment, the Supreme Court erected a comity-based barrier
to review of state and local taxes, despite having liberally offered judicial
88
The Supreme Court has defined comity as “a proper respect for state functions, a recog-
nition of the fact that the entire country is made up of a Union of separate state governments,
and a continuance of the belief that the National Government will fare best if the States and
their institutions are left free to perform their separate functions in their separate ways.”
Younger v. Harris, 401 U.S. 37, 44 (1971); see also James C. Rehnquist, Taking Comity Seri-
ously: How to Neutralize the Abstention Doctrine, 46 S
TAN
. L. R
EV
. 1049, 1052 (1994) (“I
propose to revise abstention doctrine on a view of federal and state courts as functional coe-
quals by focusing on the idea of ‘comity,’ a term unduly freighted with baggage from the
discourse of federalism and abstention. Properly unpacked and understood, however, the con-
cept of comity is useful; it nicely captures the reciprocal deference that different parts of
government
such as state and federal courts
ought to accord each other.”).
89
42 U.S.C. § 1983 (2016) (establishing a civil action for constitutional torts).
90
See Monroe v. Pape, 365 U.S. 167, 19398 (1961) (holding that individual officers, but
not municipalities, could be held liable for allegations that Chicago police officers illegally
searched plaintiff’s home and arrested him.). But see Monell v. Dep’t of Soc. Servs. of New
York, 436 U.S. 658, 663 (1978) (overruling Monroe and finding that municipalities can be
held liable under § 1983); see also John Valery White, Vindicating Rights in A Federal System:
Rediscovering 42 U.S.C. S 1985(3)’s Equality Right, 69 T
EMP
. L. R
EV
. 145, 14748 (1996)
(discussing how “Monroe revived the dormant Section 1 of the 1871 Civil Rights Act and
initiated the revival of other largely dormant sections of Reconstruction Era statutes.”).
91
Note, however, that the Supreme Court had earlier expanded the scope of the TIA to
preclude federal jurisdiction of a lawsuit seeking a declaratory judgment that a state law is
unconstitutional where an adequate state remedy exists in Great Lakes Dredge & Dock Co. v.
Huffman, 319 U.S. 293, 30002 (1943). Michael T. Morley, Public Law at the Cathedral:
Enjoining the Government, 35 C
ARDOZO
L. R
EV
. 2453, 2455 (2014) (quoting California v.
Grace Brethren Church, 457 U.S. 393, 408 (1982) to note that “[t]he Supreme Court has held
in public law cases that ‘there is little practical difference between injunctive and declaratory
relief.’).
92
Fair Assessment in Real Estate Ass’n, Inc. v. McNary, 454 U.S. 100, 116 (1981); Nat’l
Private Truck Council, Inc. v. Okla. Tax Comm’r, 515 U.S. 582, 58688 (1995).
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 20 19-OCT-18 12:58
638 Harvard Civil Rights-Civil Liberties Law Review [Vol. 53
relief for constitutional grievances in other domains. A group of St. Louis
property owners had brought a § 1983 damages action in federal court, al-
leging that their county violated the federal constitution by unfairly assess-
ing newer homes at a higher rate and retaliating against property owners that
appealed their assessments. A narrow majority of the Supreme Court held
that comity required federal courts to deny damages relief under § 1983 for
challenges to state tax regimes, except where state remedies were not “plain,
adequate, and complete.”
93
One of the reasons that the Court found Mis-
souri’s remedies to be sufficiently plain, adequate, and complete was the
availability of a § 1983 remedy in state court.
94
The majority, led by then-
Justice Rehnquist, recognized that this ruling conflicted with the general
thrust of § 1983 jurisprudence, which broadly allowed for active federal
court intervention to protect against state violations of federal constitutional
rights.
95
Nonetheless, the Court worried that damages liability would suffi-
ciently intimidate state tax officials, apocalyptically predicting that a dam-
ages lawsuit would “in every practical sense operate to suspend collection of
the state taxes.”
96
Beyond the principle of comity, the majority opinion did
not clearly articulate the nature of the barrier to §1983 damages actions in
federal court.
Noting this omission, Justice Brennan’s concurrence in the judgment
described the majority’s holding as jurisdictional
analogous to the TIA
despite earlier case law that placed comity within the equity court’s discre-
tion whether to grant relief.
97
Rather than relying on jurisdictional limitations
defined by comity or the TIA, the four concurring justices in Fair Assess-
ment identified a historical rule of judicial administration that required state
exhaustion before pursuing a damages action in federal court.
98
An exhaus-
tion requirement would not have salvaged the St. Louis homeowners’ law-
93
Fair Assesment, 454 U.S. at 116.
94
Id. at 11617.
95
Id. at 105 (1981) (recognizing that, generally, “comity does not apply where § 1983 is
involved, and that a litigant challenging the constitutionality of any state action may proceed
directly to federal court”); see also id. at 10304.
96
Id. at 115 (quoting Great Lakes Dredge and Dock Co. v. Huffman, 319 U.S. 293, 299
(1943)). To support its reasoning by practical equivalence, the Court looked to precedent that
immediately followed the passage of the TIA. In Great Lakes Dredge and Dock Co., the
Supreme Court had been confronted with the recently-created remedy of the declaratory judg-
ment. 319 U.S. at 299300. Declaratory judgments in federal court had been first created by
the Federal Declaratory Judgments Act in 1934. 48 Stat. 955. The Great Lakes Court analo-
gized the declaratory judgment to equity procedures, implicitly contrasting declaratory judg-
ment to damages and other remedies at law, and grounded its extension of comity principles in
this analogy between declaratory judgment and equity practice. 319 U.S. at 300. Rather than
engaging with the analogy that formed the reasoning of Great Lakes on this point, the later
Fair Assessment opinion relied on a dictum that emphasized the practical effect of declaratory
judgment. Shortly after the Fair Assessment decision, the Supreme Court held that the TIA
itself deprived federal courts of jurisdiction to grant declaratory judgment in state tax cases.
California v. Grace Brethren Church, 457 U.S. 393, 409-11 (1982).
97
Fair Assessment, 454 U.S. at 119.
98
Id. at 13335 (discussing First Nat’l Bank of Greeley v. Board of Comm’rs of Weld
Cty., 264 U.S. 450 (1924)). Because the rule was implicitly and favorably discussed in the
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 21 19-OCT-18 12:58
2018] Exclusionary Taxation 639
suit, but it would have allowed plaintiffs to bring a federal lawsuit if they
could not obtain relief through state processes. Under Justice Brennan’s pro-
posed regime, federal courts would have played a limited supervisory role
over state taxes, but would not have abdicated responsibility completely.
Thus, over the objections of a vigorous concurrence in the judgment, the
Fair Assessment court decided that comity prevented taxpayers from assert-
ing § 1983 challenges to state tax systems in federal courts.
In National Private Truck Council,
99
the Supreme Court invoked this
comity-based exclusion of § 1983 tax actions from federal courts to hold
unanimously that § 1983 claims were additionally impermissible in state
fora, if an adequate remedy was available under state law.
100
Oklahoma law
required a taxpayer to pay taxes under protest, and, if successful in the chal-
lenge, obtain a declaration of unconstitutionality, preclude future collection
of the tax, and receive a refund.
101
The Oklahoma Tax Commission asserted
that this state procedure was an adequate and exclusive state-court remedy
for tax disputes.
102
Disregarding Fair Assessment’s explicit discussion of a
state-court § 1983 remedy, the National Private Truck Council Court located
the comity principle in § 1983 itself. By the Court’s reasoning, “the back-
ground presumption that federal law generally will not interfere with admin-
istration of state taxes” should be read into Congressional intent and the
operation of the statute.
103
Injunctive and declaratory relief could not there-
fore be available under § 1983 if state law provided an adequate remedy (i.e.
a refund).
104
Although the National Private Truck Council opinion addressed
only injunctive and declaratory relief, state courts have found its reasoning
to be equally applicable to damages actions against cities or state officials.
105
In sum, despite the availability of federal remedies for constitutional torts at
that time, National Private Truck Council limited its growth into state
taxation.
106
TIA’s legislative history, Justice Brennan argued that it overrode the general presumption
against an exhaustion requirement for § 1983 actions. Id. at 13637.
99
515 U.S. 582 (1995).
100
The National Private Truck Council petitioners had filed a class action in the
Oklahoma trial court challenging the constitutionality of state taxes imposed upon vehicles
registered in certain other states. Id. at 584. While the Oklahoma Supreme Court reversed the
trial court’s disposition in favor of the state and awarded a refund of the taxes under state law,
it declined to award prospective injunctive relief under § 1983 or the corresponding attorney’s
fees under § 1988. Id. at 585.
101
Kendall Houghton, U.S. Supreme Court Rejects State Taxpayers’ Right to Attorney’s
Fees,5 J. M
ULTISTATE
T
AX
N
196, 200 (1995) (discussing remedy in National Private Truck
Council).
102
Br. of Respondents, Nat’l Private Truck Council v. Oklahoma Tax Comm’n, 1995 WL
130557 at *12-*16 (Mar. 24, 1995).
103
Nat’l Private Truck Council, 515 U.S. at 588.
104
Id. at 591. The court did note that a state’s refund remedy may be considered inade-
quate
and that the § 1983 injunctive remedy may be available
if state officials continue to
collect a tax after it has been declared unconstitutional in a refund action. Id. at 591 n.6.
105
See, e.g., General Motors Corp. v. City & County of San Francisco, 69 Cal. App. 4th
448, 460 (Cal. 1999); see also Coverdale, supra note 80, at 125 n.336 (collecting cases).
R
106
Houghton, supra note 101, at 196.
R
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 22 19-OCT-18 12:58
640 Harvard Civil Rights-Civil Liberties Law Review [Vol. 53
Fair Assessment and National Private Truck Council broadened the ef-
fective application of the TIA to preclude any constitutional challenge to
state or local taxes outside of procedures provided by the state.
107
This ex-
pansion could have still left meaningful access to federal remedies if courts
vigorously policed alternative state remedies to determine whether they were
“plain, speedy, and efficient.” However, as described below, the Supreme
Court watered down this standard at the same time as it expanded comity.
2. “Plain, Speedy and Efficient Remedy”
The TIA limits federal judicial interference “of any tax under State law
where a plain, speedy and efficient remedy may be had in the courts of such
State.”
108
Although the “plain, speedy, and efficient remedy” standard ini-
tially played a robust role, it has increasingly lost its meaning and potential
as a safeguard against wholesale federal abdication in tax policy. Some
lower courts nonetheless remained faithful to that initial robust role by con-
tinuing to scrutinize state remedies and to articulate the importance of a
meaningful “plain, speedy, and efficient” analysis, but intervening Supreme
Court precedent has made it difficult.
109
Garrett v. Bamford illustrates the potential of a strong “plain, speedy,
and efficient remedy” standard to ensure that wronged taxpayers have ac-
cess to meaningful judicial review, particularly in the context of racial dis-
crimination. In Garrett, the Third Circuit adjudicated a complaint by
homeowners in predominantly non-white areas of Berks County, Penn-
sylvania, arguing that property tax assessment methods constituted inten-
tional discrimination.
110
Concerned with the unavailability of a class action
mechanism for the predominantly low-income, minority taxpayers, the Court
held that the TIA did not bar federal district court jurisdiction.
111
In doing so,
the Garrett Court argued that its decision was required by, rather than con-
107
We should note briefly that the Supreme Court appeared to allow greater federal inter-
vention in the Establishment Clause case of Hibbs v. Winn, 542 U.S. 88 (2004), which seemed
to hold that the TIA and comity doctrines did not block injunctive relief if the injunction would
lead to increased state tax revenues. Id. at 107 n.9. The Court soon limited the Hibbs rule,
although its precise contours remain unclear. Levin v. Commerce Energy, Inc., 560 U.S. 413,
430 (2010).
108
28 U.S.C. § 1341 (2012) (emphasis added).
109
See, e.g., Northwest Airlines, Inc. v. Tennessee State Bd. of Equalization, 11 F.3d 70
(6th Cir. 1993) (holding that a state remedy was inadequate because it deprived state courts of
authority to review factual findings of the administrative agency that considered an initial
appeal); Louisville and N. R. Co. v. Public Service Commission, 631 F.2d 426 (6th Cir. 1980)
(holding that state remedy was inadequate because of a state procedural rule that prohibited
claims on unequal assessment by overpaying taxpayers); Garrett v. Bamford, 538 F.2d 63, 65
(3d Cir. 1976); U.S. Steel Corp v. Multistate Tax Comm’n, 367 F. Supp. 107, 11517
(S.D.N.Y. 1973) (finding state remedies to be inadequate, in part because they would require a
multiplicity of suits).
110
Garrett v. Bamford, 538 F.2d 63, 65 (3d Cir. 1976). The plaintiffs raised claims under
the constitution and the Civil Rights Act of 1866, but not the FHA.
111
Id. at 71.
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 23 19-OCT-18 12:58
2018] Exclusionary Taxation 641
trary to, the spirit of the TIA: “A denial of a federal forum . . . would allow a
state to depend upon burdensome piecemeal review procedures as an effec-
tive defense to an allegedly unconstitutional tax structure[, turning] the leg-
islative intent of [the TIA] on its head.”
112
After Pennsylvania amended its
procedure for reviewing tax assessments to allow class litigation, the Third
Circuit held the state procedures to be theoretically sufficient for the TIA to
apply, while leaving the door open to a future claim that the procedures were
inadequate in practice.
113
Yet the promise of Garrett soon faded when the Supreme Court hol-
lowed out the “plain, speedy, and efficient” requirement in Rosewell v.
LaSalle Nat’l Bank. The plaintiff in that case had brought an equal protection
claim, alleging that Cook County’s assessment scheme produced “disparities
in assessments [that] were ‘far greater in number and size in older, inner
city and county areas, owned, inhabited or used to a larger extent by minori-
ties and poorer people.’
114
Without reaching the merits of this discrimina-
tion claim, the Court considered whether the Illinois refund remedy was
“plain, speedy, and efficient” such that the TIA should apply. The Illinois
remedy was available only to property owners who had paid their taxes
under protest.
115
Although the process generally took two years, the taxpayer
did not receive interest on any refunded tax payments.
116
The Court held that
Illinois’s remedy was “plain, speedy, and efficient” because (i) the remedy
was not alleged to be uncertain or unclear, and therefore was “plain”; (ii)
the two-year wait was “regrettably . . . not unusual” and therefore did not
fall “outside the boundary of a ‘speedy’ remedy”; and (iii) “the Illinois rem-
edy imposes no unusual hardship on respondent requiring ineffectual activity
or an unnecessary expenditure of time or energy, [and therefore one] cannot
say that it is not ‘efficient.’
117
Rather, the Court emphasized that this stan-
dard only required “certain minimal procedural criteria.”
118
Rosewell’s definitions of “plain,” “speedy,” and “efficient” were lax
and have been cited approvingly by subsequent Supreme Court decisions.
119
112
Id. at 72.
113
Garrett v. Bamford, 582 F.2d 810, 812 (3d Cir. 1978). Although it affirmed the district
court, the Third Circuit caveated its affirmance by maintaining that “the federal forum should
remain available to the appellants in the event that, contrary to our prophesy, the Pennsylvania
courts do not interpret the amended remedy in a way which satisfies the requirements of the
Tax Injunction Act.” Id. at 819. Specifically, taxpayers had “contend[ed] that although the
1977 amendments create a class action procedure in the administrative context, the amend-
ments do not extend that procedure to judicial review of the agency action.” While the Third
Circuit felt that this extension was a natural and likely corollary, it encouraged the retention of
jurisdiction should the scheme operate contrary to belief. Id. at 814.
114
Rosewell v. LaSalle Nat’l Bank, 450 U.S. 503, 508 (1981).
115
Id. at 508.
116
Id. at 512.
117
Id. at 51620.
118
Id. at 512 (emphasis in original).
119
See e.g., California v. Grace Brethren Church, 457 U.S. 393, 411 (1982) (quoting
Rosewell’s mention of minimal procedural criteria to satisfy the “plain, speedy, and efficient”
requirement of the TIA). Nonetheless, that approving reference by the majority occurred over
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 24 19-OCT-18 12:58
642 Harvard Civil Rights-Civil Liberties Law Review [Vol. 53
The definition of a “plain” remedy as neither “uncertain” nor “unclear”
appears reasonable. Yet in rendering the remedy “speedy” insofar as it was
not “unusual[ly]” long vis-`a-vis the norm of judicial delays, and “efficient”
insofar as it required no “unusual hardship,” the Court dug into its standard
of “minimal” procedural criteria.
120
On the heels of Rosewell, the Supreme
Court emphasized that it “must construe narrowly the ‘plain, speedy and
efficient’ exception to the Tax Injunction Act” and apply the TIA broadly.
121
Since Rosewell, some have argued that the judicial interpretation of “plain,
speedy, and efficient” is so minimal as to be “toothless.”
122
Nonetheless, courts have occasionally found state remedies to be insuf-
ficient for the TIA’s application, even after Rosewell. The First Circuit found
that a Puerto Rican tax refund regime was not “plain, speedy, and efficient”
because it imposed a cap on payments of judgments, as well as discretionary
reductions from even the capped amounts.
123
These limitations “largely in-
sure that the judgment is worthless for all practical purposes.”
124
In a prop-
erty-tax challenge, the Ninth Circuit suggested in dicta that the Garrett
skepticism and scrutiny of state remedies may remain good law for claims
that involve protected classes, notwithstanding Rosewell.
125
How precisely
these particular lower court cases comport with the law enunciated in
Rosewell, while an important question, remains outside the scope of this
paper. Nonetheless, we read these cases as rare but important incidents of
courts deploying the meaningful scrutiny originally envisioned under the
TIA’s “plain, speedy, and efficient” requirement.
The Supreme Court’s reluctance to intervene in state tax systems forty
years ago has tempered but not eliminated the scrutiny of federal courts. It is
vital that courts recognize the remaining availability of federal judicial re-
view where state remedies are plainly lacking, to ensure that taxpayers are
able to meaningfully assert their federal antidiscrimination rights in some
venue.
a dissent that specified how “[w]hen one compares the layers of review that must be ex-
hausted in the California system with the direct appeal to this Court provided by 28 U.S.C.
§ 1252, one surely cannot conclude that the state system provides the “plain, speedy and effi-
cient” remedy that Congress intended for the resolution of the federal questions these cases
present.” Id. at 422 (Stevens, J., dissenting).
120
It should be noted that the specific calculus of “hardship,” based on “ineffectual activ-
ity” and “unnecessary expenditure of time or energy,” remained vague.
121
Grace Brethren Church, 457 U.S. at 413.
122
John B. Oakley, Prospectus for the American Law Institute’s Federal Judicial Code
Revision Project, 31 U.C. D
AVIS
L. R
EV
. 855, 903-04 (1998). Oakley has suggested that the
judicially imposed meaning is so distant from a plain meaning of the text as to require statu-
tory revision. Id.
123
Wal-Mart Puerto Rico, Inc. v. Zaragoza-Gomez, 834 F.3d 110, 121 (1st Cir. 2016).
124
Id.
125
Lowe v. Washoe Cty., 627 F.3d 1151, 1156 (9th Cir. 2010). The Ninth Circuit cited the
earlier case of Waldron v. Collins, 788 F.2d 736, 739 (11th Cir.1986), which interpreted Gar-
rett as applying only to cases where “state tax codes utilize classifications which are constitu-
tionally suspect” and held that the State of Georgia’s procedures were not inadequate despite
the unavailability of a class action. Id.
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 25 19-OCT-18 12:58
2018] Exclusionary Taxation 643
3. Deferential Constitutional Review Article XIIIA, Allegheny,
and Nordlinger
Alongside the procedural barriers to federal review of state tax policies,
“longstanding judicial deference towards tax measures” particularly in the
context of constitutional challenges, undermines plaintiffs ability to seek re-
lief for unfair taxes on race-neutral grounds.
126
When “no specific federal
right, apart from equal protection, is imperiled,” the Supreme Court has
granted “States . . . large leeway in making classifications . . . [to] produce
reasonable systems of taxation.”
127
For a brief period, the Supreme Court
seemed willing to abandon such a deferential posture, as it did in Allegheny
Pittsburgh Coal Co. v. Cty. Comm’n of Webster Cty., W. Va.
128
But deference
was resuscitated in Nordlinger v. Hahn, a challenge to Article XIIIA as en-
acted by Proposition 13.
129
In Allegheny, the Supreme Court indicated a willingness to undertake
substantive constitutional review of state tax systems. The Webster County,
West Virginia, assessor had effectively adopted an acquisition-value assess-
ment system, making “only minor modifications in the assessments of land
which had not been recently sold.”
130
Upon a challenge by Allegheny Pitts-
burgh Coal Company to its alleged overassessment as compared to neigh-
bors, the Court unanimously held that the assessment practice violated the
Equal Protection Clause.
131
The holding was predicated, however, on the in-
consistency between the assessor’s practices and state law, which required
that “taxation shall be equal and uniform throughout the State, and all prop-
erty, both real and personal, shall be taxed in proportion to its value.”
132
And
while the Court struck down the West Virginia county’s assessment scheme,
it explicitly reserved consideration of California’s then recently-passed Pro-
position 13 or any generally-applied state law.
133
Shortly after Allegheny, some Californians attempted to use the holding
as authority that Article XIIIA was unconstitutional insofar as it produced
126
Eduardo Mois´es Pe˜nalver, Regulatory Taxings, 104 C
OLUM
. L. R
EV
. 2182, 2189
(2004).
127
Lehnhausen v. Lake Shore Auto Parts Co., 410 U.S. 356, 359 (1973).
128
488 U.S. 336, 338 (1989).
129
505 U.S. 1, 2 (1990).
130
Allegheny, 488 U.S. at 338.
131
Id. The Court made note of the striking disparities. See id. at 344 (“But the present
action is not an example of transitional delay in adjustment of assessed value resulting in
inequalities in assessments of comparable property. Petitioners’ property has been assessed at
roughly 8 to 35 times more than comparable neighboring property, and these discrepancies
have continued for more than 10 years with little change. The county’s adjustments to the
assessments of property not recently sold are too small to seasonably dissipate the remaining
disparity between these assessments and the assessments based on a recent purchase price.”).
132
Id. at 338 (quoting W. V
A
. C
ONST
. art. X, § 1). Although the Supreme Court had previ-
ously allowed states to divide property into differentially-taxed classes, the Allegheny Court
painted the contested county practice as an “aberrational enforcement policy,” id. at 344 n.4,
divorced from not only statutory authority but also “even-handed,” implicit policy, id. at 345.
133
Id. at 344.
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 26 19-OCT-18 12:58
644 Harvard Civil Rights-Civil Liberties Law Review [Vol. 53
disparate property tax assessments between newer and older owners.
134
But
the Nordlinger Court declined to extend Allegheny’s holding to California’s
system.
135
Under rational basis scrutiny, the Nordlinger majority identified
two rationales “that justify denying petitioner the benefits of her neighbors’
lower assessments:”
136
first, “local neighborhood preservation, continuity,
and stability,” and second, “legitimate expectation and reliance interests.”
137
Justice Stevens alone dissented. He believed that the feudalistic system
could not be sustained under even rational basis scrutiny because of the par-
ticularly tenuous relationship between the tax structure and the legitimate
purported goal of community stability.
138
He emphasized that “deference is
not abdication and ‘rational-basis scrutiny’ is still scrutiny” and had earlier
led the court to “invalidate[ ] tax schemes under such a standard of re-
view.”
139
While he agreed that “neighborhood preservation” was a legiti-
mate state interest, he could not “agree that a tax windfall for all persons
who purchased property before 1978 rationally furthers that interest [as]
Proposition 13 [was] too blunt a tool to accomplish such a specialized goal.
134
The California Supreme Court had previously rejected a state and federal constitutional
challenge to Proposition 13. Amador Valley Joint Union High Sch. Dist. v. State Bd. of Equali-
zation, 583 P.2d 1281, 1284 (1978) (rejecting constitutional challenges to four distinct ele-
ments of Proposition 13: (1) 1% annual property tax ceiling; (2) restricting increases in
assessed value of property to 2%; (3) making it more difficult to pass non-ad valorem state
taxes; and (4) making it more difficult to pass non-ad valorem local taxes limits the method of
changes in State taxes). But Allegheny appeared to offer intervening contrary authority. See
Nordlinger v. Lynch, 275 Cal. Rptr. 684, 688 (Cal. Ct. App. 1990), aff’d sub nom, 505 U.S. 1
(1992). The California Supreme Court rejected the revived constitutional arguments, and the
Supreme Court granted certiorari to consider the constitutionality of acquisition-value assess-
ment. 502 U.S. 807 (1991) (granting certiorari).
135
To distinguish from Allegheny, the Court wrote: “Allegheny Pittsburgh was the rare
case where the facts precluded any plausible inference that the reason for the unequal assess-
ment practice was to achieve the benefits of an acquisition-value tax scheme. By contrast,
Article XIIIA was enacted precisely to achieve the benefits of an acquisition-value system.
Allegheny Pittsburgh is not controlling here.” Nordlinger, 505 U.S. at 15. Justice Thomas,
writing separately, acknowledged the inconsistency between Allegheny and the Nordlinger de-
cision, but would have resolved the discrepancy by overruling Allegheny. Id. at 2728
(Thomas, J., concurring in the judgment).
136
Nordlinger, 505 U.S. at 12.
137
Id. at 12-13; see also Clayton P. Gillette, Courts, Covenants, and Communities, 61 U.
C
HI
. L. R
EV
. 1375, 1404 (1994) (describing the Supreme Court’s invocation of the “assump-
tion that neighborhood stability is a positive good that fosters useful relationships among indi-
viduals . . . to uphold property tax schemes that discriminate in favor of longstanding
residents.”).
138
Scholars, and even jurists, have generally noted that Proposition 13 violates the tax
principle of horizontal equity, which requires that similarly situated taxpayers should be taxed
the same. See Richard J. Wood, Supreme Court Jurisprudence of Tax Fairness, 36 S
ETON
H
ALL
L. R
EV
. 421, 45556 (2006); John A. Miller, Rationalizing Injustice: The Supreme Court and
the Property Tax, 22 H
OFSTRA
L. R
EV
. 79, 82 (1993) (“I will argue that Proposition 13’s
disregard for horizontal equity is so pervasive and so deep that it should not be considered to
have a rational basis.”); Amador Valley Joint Union High Sch. Dist. v. State Bd. of Equaliza-
tion, 22 Cal. 3d 208, 249, 583 P.2d 1281, 1303 (1978) (C.J. Bird, dissenting) (“The right to
equality of taxation is as basic to our democracy as is the right to representation in matters of
taxation.”).
139
Nordlinger, 505 U.S. at 3031 (Stevens, J., dissenting).
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 27 19-OCT-18 12:58
2018] Exclusionary Taxation 645
The severe inequalities created by Proposition 13 cannot be justified by such
an interest.”
140
Rather, he critiqued the exemption, which could
be invoked repeatedly and indefinitely, allowing the Proposition
13 windfall to be passed from generation to generation . . . [T]he
rationale for such disparity is not merely “negligible,” it is nonex-
istent. Such a law establishes a privilege of a medieval character:
Two families with equal needs and equal resources are treated dif-
ferently solely because of their different heritage.
141
Since Nordlinger, taxpayers have had little success bringing federal
constitutional challenges to acquisition-value assessment systems.
142
But as
we discuss below, the Fair Housing Act, and particularly its disparate impact
standard, offers a more hospitable analytic framework for Justice Stevens’s
analysis than the “discriminatory purpose” standard required by the Equal
Protection Clause.
143
Despite a lack of constitutional purchase, Justice
Steven’s criticism of Proposition 13 as an overly-broad mechanism by which
to advance neighborhood stability could nonetheless be relevant to the
FHA’s disparate impact framework
his criticism could undermine a state or
local government’s ability to justify an adverse impact on statutorily pro-
tected classes.
140
Id. at 3738 (1992) (Stevens, J., dissenting). Justice Stevens also criticized the major-
ity’s reasoning concerning the reliance interest and argued that “[i]t cannot be said . . . that the
earlier purchasers of property somehow have a reliance interest in limited tax increases.” Id. at
38.
141
Nordlinger, 505 U.S. at 2930 (Stevens, J., dissenting).
142
Some of these cases explicitly acknowledge the disproportionate impact on racial mi-
norities. See, e.g., Columbus-Muscogee Cty. Consol. Gov’t v. CM Tax Equalization, Inc., 579
E.2d 200, 201-05 (Ga. 2003) (invoking Nordlinger to reverse lower court, which had found
that racial minorities were “probable victims” of the County’s taxation scheme and had found
the county’s acquisition-value based system to violate Equal Protection); see also Melissa J.
Morrow, Twenty-Five Years of Debate: Is Acquisition-Value Property Taxation Constitutional?
Is It Fair? Is It Good Policy?, 53 E
MORY
L.J. 587, 61015 (2004) (describing state court
decisions regarding acquisition-value taxation). Additionally, in Amador, the California Su-
preme Court rejected the argument that Proposition 13 unconstitutionally infringed on nonresi-
dents’ right to travel. 583 P.2d at 1295 (noting that “by reducing inflationary increases in
assessments, by limiting tax rates, and by permitting the taxpayer to make more careful and
accurate predictions of future tax liability,” Proposition 13 might have encouraged migration if
“prospective purchasers of real property might have been deterred from purchasing . . . by
reason of the unpredictable nature of future property tax liability resulting from unlimited
inflationary pressures.”).
143
Washington v. Davis, 426 U.S. 229, 240 (1976) (articulating “the basic equal protec-
tion principle that the invidious quality of a law claimed to be racially discriminatory must
ultimately be traced to a racially discriminatory purpose.”). A meaningful equal protection
remedy may have been of use to the African-American residents of Edwards, Mississippi, who
brought Bland v. McHann, 463 F.2 21 (5th Cir. 1972), but it is not clear how common such
practices are today.
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 28 19-OCT-18 12:58
646 Harvard Civil Rights-Civil Liberties Law Review [Vol. 53
B. State Restrictions on Review
Alongside the federal limitations on judicial interference with state tax
systems, states have established analogous barriers. Heterogeneity in state
tax procedure yields inconsistent access to individual, and particularly col-
lective, taxpayer redress. Through statutory prohibitions on relief, a lack of
adjudicatory independence, and absent aggregate procedures, state restric-
tions may impair the enforcement of federal civil rights.
California,
144
New York,
145
and Michigan
146
each have statutes generally
prohibiting declaratory or injunctive relief against property taxes. Some
states’ courts have identified exceptions to allow certain tax-related injunc-
tions, but these exceptions are often limited in ways that restrict challenges
to assessment inequities.
147
These mini-TIAs channel taxpayers into special-
ized procedures for resolving tax disputes.
148
There are three main ways in which a property tax levy can be ex-
amined by an adjudicatory body. The first form is an immediate appeal of an
assessed property value. In states where properties are reassessed annually,
these appeals must generally be brought very quickly to be timely.
149
Sec-
ond, a taxpayer may pay a disputed tax and seek a refund for the tax.
150
144
C
AL
. R
EV
. & T. C
ODE
§ 4807. Note, also, that California similarly prohibits injunctions
against state collection of any tax. See C
AL
. C
ONST
. art. XIII, § 32.
145
See N.Y. R
EAL
P
ROP
. T
AX
§ 700; Niagara Mohawk Power Corp. v. City Sch. Dist. of
Troy, 451 N.E.2d 207, 268 (N.Y. 1983) (“Article 7 of the Real Property Tax Law applies to
taxes collected because of erroneous assessments. It is the exclusive procedure for review of
property assessments ‘unless otherwise provided by law.’).
146
M
ICH
. C
OMP
. L
AWS
205.731; 205.741.
147
See Charlotte Crane, Maintaining Class Actions in Tax Cases: Why Have Federal Liti-
gants Been So Much Less Successful?, 11 P
ITT
. T
AX
R
EV
. 179, 18485 (2014) (noting many
courts’ efforts to create remedies for tax challenges outside administrative processes); Niagara
Mohawk, 451 N.E.2d at 210 (allowing general-jurisdiction courts to consider challenges to a
system of assessment, but not a particular valuation); Wikman v. City of Novi, 322 N.W.2d
103, 114 (Mich. 1982) (noting that the Michigan Tax Tribunal lacks jurisdiction to hold a
statute unconstitutional, but holding that constitutionally framed challenges to tax assessments
fall within the Tribunal’s exclusive jurisdiction).
148
State procedures vary on several dimensions, including whether a taxpayer can chal-
lenge a tax levy before paying it or must sue for a refund, the nature of the first-level decision-
maker, whether aggregate procedures, such as a class action, are available, and the applicable
statute of limitations. See generally C
OUNCIL ON
S
TATE
T
AXATION
, T
HE
B
EST AND
W
ORST OF
S
TATE
T
AX
A
DMINISTRATION
(Dec. 2016), http://cost.org/globalassets/cost/state-tax-resources-
pdf-pages/cost-studies-articles-reports/final-scorecard-in-templateupdatedbookmarked.pdf
[https://permacc/8N2R-Y58M] (describing the variation in tax tribunals on many of these
axes).
149
See, e.g., N.Y. R
EAL
P
ROP
. T
AX
§§ 525(2)(a); 706(2), For more description of these
processes, see Laura Bucher Murphy, Cafo Grief: Using Tax Grieving Procedures to Protest
Industrial Animal Factories, 23 J. E
NVTL
. L. & L
ITIG
. 357, 367 (2008).
150
Consider, for example, the Illinois property tax refund process in Rosewell: “Respon-
dent first exhausted her administrative remedy by appealing unsuccessfully for a correction of
her 1977 assessment before the Cook County Board of Appeals [and] [h]er only remaining
state remedy was to pay the contested tax under protest, and then to file an objection to the
Cook County Collector’s Application for Judgment before the Circuit Court of Cook County.”
Rosewell v. LaSalle Nat’l Bank, 450 U.S. 503, 508 (1981).
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 29 19-OCT-18 12:58
2018] Exclusionary Taxation 647
Finally, for those who are unable to afford property taxes and end up in
arrears, the property may be subject to a tax lien for the back taxes. If the
taxes remain unpaid, some states require the taxing jurisdiction to obtain a
foreclosure from a court before selling or taking ownership of the
property.
151
State fora for tax-related adjudication vary significantly in their position
within the state government and therefore vary in independence.
152
The
structure and independence of a state forum should inform whether the rem-
edy is “plain, speedy, and efficient,” as required for the TIA to preclude
federal intervention. (Of course, the Rosewell standard makes it difficult to
characterize a state tax procedure as legally insufficient.)
The availability of state aggregate procedures is also relevant to the
federal TIA analysis. As both the Garrett and Lowe courts recognized, such
procedures may partly determine whether the tax procedure constitutes a
“plain, efficient, and speedy” remedy. Through the aggregation of smaller
recoveries, class actions can offer more persuasive incentives for individu-
als, including attorneys.
153
Some states do not allow for class actions at all,
having never adopted state level parallels of Rule 23 of the Federal Rules of
Civil Procedure.
154
In many states, despite an apparent class action proce-
dure, state courts enforce a strict requirement for taxpayers to individually
pay the taxes and seek refunds before challenging them, effectively eliminat-
ing the prospect for a broad, class-action challenge.
155
On the other hand,
151
In some states, rather than a foreclosure, the second stage is a “tax sale,” where a
partial or full interest in the property is sold. J
OHN
R
AO
, N
AT
L
C
ONSUMER
L
AW
C
TR
., T
HE
O
THER
F
ORECLOSURE
C
RISIS
: P
ROPERTY
T
AX
L
IEN
S
ALES
12 (2012), https://www.nclc.org/
images/pdf/foreclosure_mortgage/tax_issues/tax-lien-sales-report.pdf [https://permacc/Q4FE-
6QMR]. The purchaser acquires an interest in the property subject to, in most states, redemp-
tion by the former owner, so full rights do not pass at the sale alone. Id. at 17. Not every state
allows for (quasi-)judicial review, and certain proceedings may be limited in the issues that
parties can address.
152
There are “Judicial Branch Courts,” or tax tribunals in the judicial branch of state
government; “Independent Tax Appeal Agencies,” which are tax-specialized and located in
the executive branch; “Generalist Appeal Agencies,” which utilize general administrative law
judges and are located in the executive branch; and “Revenue Agencies,” which operate
within the state revenue collecting agency. Elizabeth Buroker Coffin, The Case for A State Tax
Court, 8 S
T
. & L
OC
. T
AX
L
AW
. 63, 7879 (2003). Depending on the assignment of burdens of
proof, appeals to these agencies may also be extremely costly, requiring extensive expert testi-
mony on the valuation of a property. The identity of the first-line decision-maker in tax appeals
is consequential to the decision-maker’s independence and familiarity with relevant legal prin-
ciples. Id. at 93 (describing bills in Alabama and West Virginia to, in part, assure the compe-
tence of tax dispute adjudicators).
153
See, e.g., Maureen Carroll, Class Action Myopia, 65 D
UKE
L.J. 843, 845 (2016); see
also Amchem Prods., Inc. v. Windsor, 521 U.S. 591, 617 (1997).
154
See, e.g., Linda S. Mullenix, Aggregate Litigation and the Death of Democratic Dis-
pute Resolution, 107 N
W
. U. L. R
EV
. 511, 534 n.126 (2013) (discussing how Mississippi does
not allow class actions, while Virginia lacks a class action rule but nonetheless permits class
relief in some situations).
155
See, e.g., Ziegler v. Indiana Dep’t of State Revenue, 797 N.E.2d 881, 88586 (Ind. T.C.
2003); Coverdale, supra note 80, at 123.
R
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 30 19-OCT-18 12:58
648 Harvard Civil Rights-Civil Liberties Law Review [Vol. 53
states like Louisiana and North Carolina have made efforts to expand tax-
payer access to class relief.
156
Tax scholar Charlotte Crane has identified a surprising willingness
among at least some state courts to employ aggregate procedures to evaluate
challenges to legally dubious local government taxes. Under pressure to ju-
dicially resolve political uncertainty around new taxes, state courts might
have “encouraged some cases by signaling that innovative procedures, in-
cluding class actions, may be available.”
157
In recent years, a number of
states, including Alabama, Florida, and Louisiana, have changed the archi-
tecture of their appeals system in favor of taxpayers.
158
These changes have
included decreased evidentiary burdens for plaintiffs; the elimination of fees
or tax prepayment as a condition of accessing redress; and extended filing
periods.
159
156
Louisiana recently held that the Louisiana Board of Tax Appeals has jurisdiction to
certify and hear a class action. St. Martin v. State, 25 So. 3d 736, 737 (La. 2009). The class
action specifically sought “the payment of statutorily mandated interest due as a result of tax
refunds or credits.” Id. North Carolina’s highest court essentially nullified the prerequisite that
all class members seek a refund, with the goal of expanding access to class relief. Coverdale,
supra note 80, at 12425 (“Under these circumstances, the [North Carolina Supreme Court]
R
held a class action could be brought on behalf of all taxpayers who had paid the unconstitu-
tional tax even though many of them had not filed a timely administrative claim for refund.
Although the [c]ourt’s decision is open to criticism as an example of judicial nullification of a
statute, it underlines the shortcomings of the present system which allows states to escape in
practice their obligation to refund unconstitutional taxes.”).
157
Crane, supra note 147, at 186.
R
158
Florida recently established that “the taxpayer’s burden is now governed by a prepon-
derance of the evidence standard,” abrogating a less taxpayer-friendly regime that had, in
certain circumstances, required a clear and convincing standard. Recent Development, Finance
& Taxation, 43 S
TETSON
L. R
EV
. 447, 447 (2014). In 2014, the then-governor of Alabama
signed into law the “Alabama Taxpayer Fairness Act” that eliminated a tax appeal tribunal
located within the state Department of Revenue and replaced it with an independent state
agency based on the American Bar Association’s Model State Administrative Tax Tribunal Act.
Ferdinand Hogroian, More Movement Toward Fairness in State Tax Administration and Ap-
peals, 25-JUL J. M
ULTISTATE
T
AX
N
28, 28-29 (2015). Additionally, “[t]here is also no ‘pay
to play’ required for appeals to the Tax Tribunal, although there continues to be a tax prepay-
ment (or bond) requirement for subsequent appeals to circuit court. (The bond requirement has
been loosened somewhat: taxpayers with a net worth of $250,000 or less need not post a bond
or pay the tax before filing suit.).” Id. at 28. Louisiana and New Mexico also made recent
changes to their tax appeal systems to allow for more time to file the complaint, increased
transparency by public posting of tax tribunal opinions, and increased fora for redress. Id. at
2832 (describing Louisiana’s Act 198, providing taxpayers 180 days from the date of final
determination of a federal adjustment for the filing of an amended state tax return; Louisiana’s
Act 640, whereby taxpayers may appeal assessments of local sales and use taxes to the Board
of Tax Appeals without prepayment; New Mexico’s Senate Bill 356, which creates a new
‘administrative hearings office’ under the Department of Finance and Administration, and sep-
arate from the Taxation and Revenue Department, involving hearing officers with tax law
knowledge; and Arkansas’s Senate Bill 490, which provides 180 days for taxpayers to seek
judicial relief from a final assessment or determination). “In sum, 2014 and 2015 have been
very successful years for proponents of increasing fairness in state tax administration and ap-
peals.” Id. at 32.
159
Supra note 158. Relatedly, using data from New York, Andrew Hayashi finds that
R
certain property taxpayers
racial minorities, immigrants, and working families
have lower
legal salience by virtue of using mortgage escrow to (bundle and) pay their taxes, and such
mortgage escrow usage predicts a much lower use of tax appeals, even controlling for overas-
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 31 19-OCT-18 12:58
2018] Exclusionary Taxation 649
Such procedural liberalization aside, studies of taxpayer appeals sug-
gest that appeals may disproportionately benefit residents of wealthier neigh-
borhoods, despite greater density of extremely high assessment ratios in poor
neighborhoods.
160
One facet of this problem may be the fact that lawyers and
non-lawyers often agree to represent petitioners in real property tax assess-
ment challenges on a contingency basis.
161
Empirical studies from Miami-
Dade County, Florida and Texas suggest that tax representatives, who assist
homeowners in appealing tax assessments, disproportionately target higher
value homes and neighborhoods, for which formal appeals are more likely to
be filed.
162
Yet, as reflected in an analysis of data from Chicago, extremely
high assessment ratios are often concentrated at low sales prices.
163
Because
they work on contingency, profit-maximizing tax representatives may priori-
tize higher value properties over lower-value areas with nonetheless propor-
tionally greater overassessments.
The federal and state trends discussed above present significant proce-
dural barriers to property owners who face unjustifiably unequal, and poten-
tially illegally unfair, property tax assessments.
164
However, more recent
sessment and other covariates. Andrew Hayashi, The Legal Salience of Taxation, 81 U. C
HI
. L.
R
EV
. 1443, 148486 (2014).
160
Infra notes 162 and 163, and accompanying text.
R
161
See Charles T. Beeching, Jr., The Billable Hour Is Dead. Long Live . . . What?, 30 N.Y.
S
T
. B.J. 12, 12 (1995) (“Lawyers have been charging contingent fees for personal injury cases,
condemnation proceedings, real property tax assessment challenges, and a number of other
types of legal proceedings for decades if not centuries.”); see also Michele Cotton, Experi-
ment, Interrupted: Unauthorized Practice of Law Versus Access to Justice, 5 D
E
P
AUL
J. S
OC
.
J
UST
. 179, 204 (2012) (“The difference between the courts, where nonlawyers are generally
not permitted to appear on behalf of parties, and administrative hearings, where nonlawyer
representation sometimes occurs, may be understood as reflecting differences between judicial
and legislative functions.”).
162
See William Doerner & Keith Ihlanfeldt, The Role of Representative Agents in the
Property Tax Appeals Process, 68 N
AT
L
T
AX
J
OURNAL
59, 60 (2015) (finding that data on
single-family homes located in Miami-Dade County, Florida are consistent with a theory that
tax representatives target higher-value neighborhoods based off of greater expected payoffs).
A study examining Texas property tax appeals in the first decade of the twenty-first century
similarly found that “higher market values increase the probability of appeal and the likeli-
hood of filing a formal rather than an informal appeal.” Id. at 62 (summarizing Rodney His-
song & Robert F. Hawley, Analyzing the Residential Property Appraisal and Outcomes to
Determine if a Property Tax Revolt is Imminent, 93 S
OC
. S
CI
. Q. 191(2012)). “An informal
appeal is a meeting between the petitioner and a member of the tax assessor’s office. In a
formal appeal both the petitioner and the assessor’s representative present their case in front of
a value adjustment board.” Id. at 61-62.
163
Doerner & Ihlanfeldt, supra note 162, at 62 (summarizing Rachel Weber & Daniel P.
McMillen, Ask and Ye Shall Receive? Predicting the Successful Appeal of Property Tax As-
sessments, 38 P
UB
. F
IN
. R
EV
. 74 (2010). Doerner and Ihlanfeldt argue that unlike Weber and
McMillen, whose “primary interest was on how the probability of appeal and the probability
of obtaining an assessment reduction are affected by thin markets (i.e., few comparable
sales),” their “interest is in the role played by tax representatives in the appeals process, who
according to our data from Miami-Dade County, Florida, are used by an overwhelming major-
ity of property owners.” Id. at 60.
164
The MorningSide litigation in Detroit, to which we will turn shortly, provides an exam-
ple of this. Although the county acknowledged that property tax assessments were incorrect,
the admission came after the appeals period passed. Homeowners are therefore unable to use
this admission in the state tax procedures.
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 32 19-OCT-18 12:58
650 Harvard Civil Rights-Civil Liberties Law Review [Vol. 53
developments, to which we now turn, present a new opening to address
property tax assessment inequities
at least where they have a disparate im-
pact on a protected class.
III. R
EVIVING
M
EANINGFUL
S
TATE
-C
OURT
R
EVIEW
We argue that the FHA’s disparate impact theory may swing the pendu-
lum away from deference to state tax regimes and toward a meaningful re-
view of property tax policies that disproportionately affect protected classes.
The opportunity to address exclusionary taxation is reinforced by recent
cases in which the Court exhibited a stronger concern for preservation of
federal rights in state courts, including rights related to state and local taxa-
tion. These jurisprudential trends do not overcome the TIA’s explicit statu-
tory limitation on federal injunctions, but they suggest an expansion of
meaningful state-court review.
A. Inclusive Communities: Reaffirmed Disparate Impact
The primary vehicle for challenges to exclusionary taxation lies in the
FHA, particularly after the Supreme Court’s confirmation that FHA plaintiffs
may prove discrimination through disparate impact theories.
165
The FHA of-
fers both procedural guarantees that are unavailable to constitutional plain-
tiffs and a substantive standard that allows for review of tax policies with
unintentionally discriminatory effects.
The FHA resulted from decades of activism by mid-twentieth century
fair housing advocates who viewed limitations on the ability to inherit, lease,
sell, hold, and convey real and personal property “as a denial of full citizen-
ship.”
166
Those advocates argued not only “that America would be a truly
democratic society when all races lived in one community”
167
but also that
“all citizens had a responsibility to participate in the housing market in a
nondiscriminatory manner.”
168
Under the FHA, it is illegal both “to otherwise make unavailable or
deny[ ] a dwelling to any person because of race, color, religion, sex, and
family origin” and “[t]o discriminate against any person in the terms, con-
ditions, or privileges of sale or rental of a dwelling, or in the provision of
services or facilities in connection therewith, because of race, color, religion,
sex, familial status, or national origin,” among other prohibitions.
169
Courts
165
Tex. Dep’t of Hous. & Cmty. Affairs v. Inclusive Cmtys. Project, Inc., 135 S. Ct. 2507,
2525 (2015).
166
Wendell E. Pritchett, Where Shall We Live? Class and the Limitations of Fair Housing
Law, 35 U
RB
. L
AW
. 399, 403 (2003).
167
Id.
168
Id. at 406. Pritchett also identifies the importance of the FHA to securing opportunity
for middle-class African Americans, while acknowledging its limitations in ensuring opportu-
nity for lower-income communities. Id. at 407.
169
42 U.S.C. § 3604(a)-(b).
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 33 19-OCT-18 12:58
2018] Exclusionary Taxation 651
have recognized that these provisions encompass challenges to discrimina-
tory property taxes.
170
Several features of the FHA should give courts pause if defendants try
to import comity arguments from the § 1983 cases or to interpose insuffi-
cient state remedies. The FHA contains an explicit preemption provision that
overrides state laws that would conflict with the operation of the statute.
171
Moreover, the FHA’s private right of action provision explicitly allows for
an “aggrieved person [to] commence a civil action in an appropriate . . .
State court.”
172
A wide range of plaintiffs are entitled to bring FHA claims,
including members of a racial majority who are wronged by the deprivation
of a racially diverse community.
173
If the FHA reached only intentional (disparate treatment) discrimina-
tion claims, these procedural features would be relevant in a small number of
cases. They would effectively replace the unavailable § 1983 claim for a
violation of the Equal Protection Clause, but offer little additional relief.
174
However, in Inclusive Communities, the Supreme Court recently reaf-
firmed the viability of an FHA disparate impact theory, which proscribes
seemingly neutral rules that are discriminatory in operation.
175
Disparate im-
170
See Coleman v. Seldin, 687 N.Y.S.2d 240, 250 (Sup. Ct. 1999) (recognizing cause of
action for discriminatory property-tax foreclosures under the Fair Housing Act); MorningSide
v. Sabree, Case No. 16-008807-CH (Mich. Ct. App. Sept. 21, 2017) (same). The property tax-
related foreclosures, instead of the property taxes themselves, address the immediate issue of
preventing the foreclosures of the clients’ homes, undergirded by the broader property tax
system. See United States v. Cty. of Nassau, 79 F. Supp. 2d 190, 191 (E.D.N.Y. 2000) (deny-
ing jurisdiction for Fair Housing Claims under the TIA).
171
42 U.S.C. § 3615 (2012); see David Franklin, Civil Rights vs. Civil Liberties? The
Legality of State Court Lawsuits Under the Fair Housing Act, 63 U. C
HI
. L. R
EV
. 1607,
161013 (1996) (discussing FHA’s interaction with local rules, including striking down
facially neutral zoning ordinances with disparate impacts). The preemptive effect of the FHA
is highlighted by the fact that, at least in the context of race cases, the FHA was enacted
pursuant to section 2 of the Thirteenth Amendment, U.S. C
ONST
. amend. XIII, which granted
Congress the power to pass statutes to “eliminate the badges and incidents of slavery.” Mitch-
ell v. Cellone, 389 F.3d 86, 8788 (3d Cir. 2004) (citing Jones v. Alfred H. Mayer Co., 392
U.S. 409, 43940 (1968)). This power, established after the Civil War, was explicitly granted
to Congress to overwhelm intransigent state actions to deprive people of civil rights.
172
42 U.S.C § 3613(a)(1)(A) (2012).
173
See Trafficante v. Metro. Life Ins. Co., 409 U.S. 205, 20912 (1972); see also Bank of
America v. City of Miami, 137 S. Ct. 1296, 1298 (2017) (reaffirming the holding of
Trafficante).
174
Washington v. Davis, 426 U.S. 229, 24447 (1976) (articulating “the basic equal pro-
tection principle that the invidious quality of a law claimed to be racially discriminatory must
ultimately be traced to a racially discriminatory purpose”). Such a remedy may have been of
use to the African-American residents of Edwards, Mississippi, who brought Bland v.
McHann, 463 F.2d 21 (5th Cir. 1972), but it is not clear how common such practices are today.
175
Inclusive Cmtys., 135 S. Ct. at 2525; J. William Callison, Inclusive Communities: Geo-
graphic Desegregation, Urban Revitalization, and Disparate Impact Under the Fair Housing
Act, 46 U. M
EM
. L. R
EV
. 1039, 104142 (2016); Michael G. Allen, Jamie L. Crook, & John P.
Relman, Assessing HUD’s Disparate Impact Rule: A Practitioner’s Perspective, 49 H
ARV
.
C.R.-C.L. L. R
EV
. 155, 156 (2014). Although the Supreme Court did not explicitly address the
viability of a disparate impact to enforce § 3604(b), its reasoning regarding § 3605(a) would
apply equally; both provisions use the word “discriminate,” which the Court held to include
disparate impact theories in this context. See Inclusive Cmtys., 135 S. Ct. at 251819.
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 34 19-OCT-18 12:58
652 Harvard Civil Rights-Civil Liberties Law Review [Vol. 53
pact theories emerged in administrative agencies almost immediately after
the passage of the Civil Rights Act of 1964
176
and were solidified by the
Supreme Court’s 1971 decision in Griggs v. Duke Power.
177
Soon after, the
Eighth Circuit was the first to recognize disparate impact under the FHA.
178
All of the other circuits, other than the D.C. Circuit, followed suit, rec-
ognizing two effects-based claims under the FHA:
179
(i) when the challenged
practice has a greater adverse impact on members of a protected class (a
“disproportionate effect”) and (ii) when the practice tends to “create, rein-
force, or perpetuate patterns of segregation” (a “segregative effect”).
180
Courts have invoked the FHA’s disparate impact analysis across a multitude
of housing-related practices, from exclusionary zoning ordinances and lend-
ing practices to landlord and housing provider reference policies and occu-
pancy restrictions.
181
The purposes of disparate impact liability are contested, including in
the FHA context, but the Supreme Court’s decision in Inclusive Communities
rules against narrower theories linking disparate impact to intent.
182
At one
extreme, earlier commentators had treated disparate impact theories as
merely an alternative means of proving discriminatory intent, potentially in-
cluding unconscious or implicit biases.
183
A more moderate version of this
176
See Olatunde Johnson, The Agency Roots of Disparate Impact, 49 H
ARV
. C.R.-C.L. L.
R
EV
. 125, 13334 (2014).
177
See 401 U.S. 424, 432 (1971) (holding that educational and testing requirements that
“that operate as ‘built-in headwinds’ for minority groups and are unrelated to measuring job
capability” are impermissible employment discrimination under Title VII, regardless of in-
tent). Id. at 432.
178
See U.S. v. City of Black Jack, Mo., 508 F.2d 1179, 1181 (8th Cir. 1974) (ruling that a
St. Louis suburb’s prohibition on multifamily housing would not only perpetuate segregation in
the metropolitan area but also have a disproportionate impact on African Americans).
179
See Inclusive Cmtys., 135 S. Ct. at 2519 (collecting cases).
180
We borrow these labels from Allen, et al., supra note 175, at 160; see also Langlois v.
R
Abington Hous. Auth., 207 F.3d 43, 54 (1st Cir. 2000) (“Because ‘subconscious discrimina-
tion’ in housing tends to manifest itself in practices that, although not overtly racial, have the
effect of freezing segregation, I . . . [ask] whether defendants’ use of local preferences within
the jurisdictions they represent may have the effect of ‘perpetuat[ing] segregation and thereby
prevent[ing] interracial association.’ ”) (quoting Metro. Hous. Dev. Corp. v. Vill. of Arlington
Heights, 558 F.2d 1283, 1290 (7th Cir. 1977)).
181
See Allen, et al., supra note 175, at 15657.
R
182
Inclusive Cmtys., 135 S. Ct. at 2521-22 (acknowledging the evidentiary role of dispa-
rate impact as one of multiple purposes). As Bagenstos has recognized, this statement also
makes the novel step of characterizing unconscious prejudice as a form of discriminatory in-
tent. See Samuel R. Bagenstos, Disparate Impact and the Role of Classification and Motiva-
tion in Equal Protection Law after Inclusive Communities, 101 C
ORNELL
L. R
EV
. 1115,
113435 (2016).
183
See George Rutherglen, Disparate Impact Under Title VII: An Objective Theory of
Discrimination, 73 V
A
. L. R
EV
. 1297, 1311 (1987) (proffering a theory of disparate impact as a
hedge against pretext and hidden intent); Audrey J. Lee, Note, Unconscious Bias Theory in
Employment Discrimination Litigation, 40 H
ARV
. C.R.-C.L. L. R
EV
. 481, 48990 (2006) (dis-
cussing the role of unconscious bias theory in disparate impact claims around subjective em-
ployment practices, such as Watson v. Fort Worth Bank & Trust, 487 U.S. 977 (1988)). But see
Stacy E. Seicshnaydre, Is the Road to Disparate Impact Paved with Good Intentions?, 42
W
AKE
F
OREST
L. R
EV
. 1141 (2007) (critiquing this approach).
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 35 19-OCT-18 12:58
2018] Exclusionary Taxation 653
theory suggests that disparate impact liability polices “racially selective in-
difference”
described by Paul Brest as “the unconscious failure to extend
to a minority the same recognition of humanity, and hence the same sympa-
thy and care, given as a matter of course to one’s own group.”
184
Because
disparate impact analysis requires justification for, and recognition of,
harms, it can force a decision-maker to consider the policy’s effects on a
protected class (both in anticipation of potential liability and through the
process of litigation).
185
Inclusive Communities can be read as partially endorsing the bottleneck
theory of disparate impact that ascribes a role for antidiscrimination law in
eliminating “bottlenecks to opportunity,”
186
practices that unjustifiably in-
hibit economic opportunity. The bottleneck framework calls attention to the
extent to which an opportunity-limiting practice operates arbitrarily or in
furtherance of a meaningful goal.
187
The Court likewise articulated that “dis-
parate-impact liability mandates the ‘removal of artificial, arbitrary, and un-
necessary barriers,’ not the displacement of valid governmental policies.”
188
To address the competing goals, the Court largely embraced a three-part bur-
den-shifting test promulgated by the Department of Housing and Urban De-
velopment (“HUD”).
189
This test, described below, provides a framework
for courts to make these distinctions.
190
In addition to the bottleneck theory, other disparate impact theories ex-
hibit less concern with policymakers’ mental states. One such theory presents
disparate impact liability as a means to address policies that perpetuate struc-
tural and historical discrimination.
191
Griggs itself endorsed this theory, not-
ing: “Under [Title VII], practices, procedures, or tests neutral on their face,
and even neutral in terms of intent, cannot be maintained if they operate to
‘freeze’ the status quo of prior discriminatory employment practices.”
192
184
Paul Brest, Foreword: In Defense of the Antidiscrimination Principle, 90 H
ARV
. L.
R
EV
. 1, 78 (1976); see also Olatunde Johnson, Disparity Rules 107 C
OLUM
. L. R
EV
. 374,
39495 (2007) (describing a classic Title VI disparate-impact case as reflecting racially selec-
tive indifference).
185
The political connotations of various theories of intent in antidiscrimination law, par-
ticularly Equal Protection law, have changed over time. See generally Katie Eyer, Ideological
Drift and the Forgotten History of Intent, 51 H
ARV
. C.R.-C.L. L. R
EV
. 1 (2016).
186
Samuel Bagenstos, Bottlenecks and Antidiscrimination Theory, 93 T
EX
. L. R
EV
. 415,
42324 (2014) (reviewing Joseph Fishkin, B
OTTLENECKS
(2014)).
187
See Joseph Fishkin, The Anti-Bottleneck Principle in Employment Discrimination Law,
91 W
ASH
. U. L. R
EV
. 1429, 1477-78 (2014) (arguing that both disparate treatment and dispa-
rate impact laws do, and should, function to preclude bottlenecks in the opportunity structure).
188
Inclusive Cmtys., 135 S. Ct. at 2522 (quoting Griggs v. Duke Power Co., 401 U.S. 424,
431 (1971)).
189
Inclusive Cmtys., 135 S. Ct. at 251415 (2015).
190
Infra Section III.B.
191
See, e.g., Richard Primus, Equal Protection and Disparate Impact: Round Three, 117
H
ARV
. L R
EV
. 493, 52425 (2003). In the employment context, a related form of disparate
impact litigation addresses biological differences between ethnicities or genders
for example,
height requirements. See, e.g., Dothard v. Rawlinson, 433 U.S. 321 (1977). It is difficult to
think of an analogue to these cases in the FHA context.
192
Griggs, 401 U.S. at 430.
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 36 19-OCT-18 12:58
654 Harvard Civil Rights-Civil Liberties Law Review [Vol. 53
Richard Thompson Ford recognized the FHA’s “potential to attack the struc-
ture of racially identified residential spaces,” particularly through the appli-
cation of a disparate impact standard.
193
In the words of Griggs, the
discrimination inquiry should be focused not only on intent but whether a
barrier is “artificial, arbitrary and unnecessary.”
194
Although the Court did not explicitly decide among these competing
theories in Inclusive Communities, the opinion reflects a sensitivity to dispa-
rate impact’s role in unseating structural discrimination on a particularly rel-
evant tax policy front: the privileging of individual residents based on
preexisting ties.
195
The opinion identifies so-called “barrier” cases, including
those where potential residents are excluded based on their relationship to
existing residents in a place, as “resid[ing] at the heartland of disparate
impact liability.”
196
The Court cabined this focus on historical and structural discrimination
by articulating a “robust causality requirement” and evincing concern that
defendants not be “held liable for racial disparities they did not create.”
197
Yet, as Stacy Seicshnaydre has written, this “robust causality requirement”
simply extends precedent that has traditionally policed segregative practices
rather than statistical disparities alone.
198
The FHA has always required a
meaningful nexus between the challenged policy and the alleged disparity.
199
Of course, courts should not ignore a policy’s disparate impact because the
effect was caused by its interaction with existing social and historical reali-
ties.
200
As courts continue to confront and clarify the meaning of causality in
193
Richard Thompson Ford, The Boundaries of Race: Political Geography in Legal Analy-
sis, 107 H
ARV
. L. R
EV
. 1841, 1894 (1994).
194
Griggs, 401 U.S. at 431.
195
See Inclusive Cmtys., 135 S. Ct. at 251516.
196
Id. at 2522.
197
Id. at 2523. Opponents of the disparate impact theory immediately found solace in
these statements, noting that nearly every facially neutral policy
including in Griggs
causes
a discriminatory effect by virtue of its interaction with existing social realities. See Roger
Clegg, Silver Linings Playbook: Disparate Impact and the Fair Housing Act, 2015 C
ATO
S
UP
.
C
T
. R
EV
. 165, 17071 (2015). On remand to the district court, this causality requirement was
the first of several grounds on which the court rejected Inclusive Communities Project’s
claims. See Inclusive Communities Project, Inc. v. Texas Dep’t of Hous. & Cmty. Affairs, No.
3:08-CV-0546-D, 2016 WL 4494322, at *8*9 (N.D. Tex. Aug. 26, 2016).
198
Stacy Seicshnaydre, Disparate Impact and the Limits of Local Discretion After Inclu-
sive Communities, 24 G
EO
. M
ASON
. L. R
EV
. 663, 67677 (2017).
199
Id. at 67879 (collecting cases that recognized the need for a causal relationship before
Inclusive Communities). Those who have seized upon the “robust causality requirement” to
assert that the requirement tightened the disparate impact standard thus ignore the historical
development of the standard. See, e.g., Paul Hancock, Symposium: The Supreme Court recog-
nizes but limits disparate impact in its Fair Housing Act decision, SCOTUS
BLOG
3 (Jun. 26,
2015, 8:58 AM), http://www.scotusblog.com/2015/06/paul-hancock-fha/ [https://permacc/
2A3K-ESJ9] (“While supporters of the disparate-impact theory may perceive the Court’s deci-
sion as a ‘win,’ the decision imposes significant limitations on the application of the theory,
which provide an important benefit to defendants in FHA cases.”).
200
Noah Zatz, Disparate Impact and the Unity of Equality Law, 97 B.U. L. R
EV
. 1357,
1379 (2017).
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 37 19-OCT-18 12:58
2018] Exclusionary Taxation 655
particular fact patterns,
201
FHA plaintiffs must, as always, articulate the con-
nections between allegedly discriminatory policies and disparate impacts.
Because Congress has established disparate impact liability only in cer-
tain domains, our argument would be unlikely to reach to other aspects of
state tax systems, such as sales, income, or even non-residential property
taxes.
202
Although changes to such tax regimes may indirectly affect residen-
tial patterns and access to housing, the effects are unlikely to satisfy the
“robust causality requirement” that the Court articulated in Inclusive Com-
munities.
203
For example, some have made the argument that the mortgage-
interest deduction incentivizes segregation.
204
Even if armed with quantita-
tive evidence pertaining to a particular state’s mortgage-interest deduction
(as a federal analogue), such a deduction, as a second-order tax benefit, is
unlikely to fall under the specific FHA statutory language
whether “terms,
conditions, or privileges of sale or rental of a dwelling, or in the provision of
services or facilities in connection therewith” or as a basis “to otherwise
make [housing] unavailable.”
205
In contrast, property taxes have been ex-
plicitly recognized as regulated by the FHA in the Coleman case, described
below.
206
201
Courts after Inclusive Communities are confronting and defining the contours of cau-
sality. See In De Reyes v. Waples Mobile Home Park Ltd. P’ship, 205 F. Supp. 3d 782, 79394
(E.D. Va. 2016) (holding that the robust causality requirement was not met by showing that a
policy against undocumented immigrants disproportionately affected Latinos but doing so on
the arguably erroneous ground that undocumented immigrants are not protected by the Fair
Housing Act). Note also that this causality requirement is distinct from the requirement that a
plaintiff show that damages were proximately caused by a wrongful action in order to collect
damages under the FHA. Bank of America v. City of Miami, 137 S. Ct. 1296, 1306 (2017)
(reversing and remanding for further consideration that foreseeability alone was not a suffi-
cient showing of causality for municipalities to be awarded damages under the FHA).
202
Disparate impact liability is also available in the context of employment and credit
discrimination, under Title VII and ECOA, respectively. However, neither statute provides a
cause of action for government regulatory or taxing activity. See 42 U.S.C. § 2000e2; 15
U.S.C. § 1691e(a).
203
Inclusive Cmtys., 135 S. Ct. at 2523.
204
Michelle D. Layser, How Federal Tax Law Rewards Housing Segregation, 93 I
ND
. L.J.
(forthcoming 2018). Layser focuses on optimal policy, noting that “it is not necessary to prove
legal liability to establish that the LIHTC program in these and many other cities has rewarded
segregation and limited housing choice.” See also Dennis J. Ventry, Jr., The Accidental Deduc-
tion: A History and Critique of the Tax Subsidy for Mortgage Interest, 73 L
AW
& C
ONTEMP
.
P
ROBS
. 233, 25759 (2010) (describing the history of the MID and longstanding acknowledge-
ment of the inequities embedded in it).
205
42 U.S.C. § 3604(a), (b).
206
See infra Section IV.A.1. Interestingly, Lee Anne Fennell has made the point that
§ 3608(d) of the FHA, which requires federal agencies to cooperate with HUD in affirmatively
furthering fair housing, could be construed as a basis (though not requirement) to reduce tax
subsidies for homeownership, including the mortgage-interest deduction. Lee Anne Fennell,
Searching for Fair Housing, 97 B.U. L. R
EV
. 349, 417 (2017); see also 42 U.S.C. § 3608 (“All
executive departments and agencies shall administer their programs and activities relating to
housing and urban development (including any Federal agency having regulatory or supervi-
sory authority over financial institutions) in a manner affirmatively to further the purposes of
this subchapter and shall cooperate with the Secretary to further such purposes.”).
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 38 19-OCT-18 12:58
656 Harvard Civil Rights-Civil Liberties Law Review [Vol. 53
B. HUD’s Disparate Impact Framework
Adverse impact alone does not, and should not, render a policy illegal
under the FHA if the policy or practice causing the disparity is warranted by
a sufficient justification. While Inclusive Community Project’s appeal was
pending before the Fifth Circuit, HUD promulgated an evidentiary frame-
work for evaluating a disparate impact claim under the FHA that recognizes
the need to evaluate both impact and justification.
207
The HUD rule articulates a three-part burden-shifting test for determin-
ing when a practice with a discriminatory effect violates the Fair Housing
Act. First, the plaintiff bears the burden of proving a prima facie case that a
policy or practice (i) actually or predictably results in a discriminatory effect
(a “disproportionate effect”) or (ii) “creates, increases, reinforces or per-
petuates segregated housing patterns” (a “segregative effect”) on the basis
of a protected characteristic.
208
As the Supreme Court has articulated, “[a]
disparate-impact claim relying on a statistical disparity must fail if the plain-
tiff cannot point to a defendant’s policy or policies causing that disparity.”
209
If the plaintiff proves a prima facie case, the burden of proof shifts to
the defendant to prove that the challenged practice is “necessary to achieve
one or more of its substantial, legitimate, nondiscriminatory interests.”
210
Commenters had requested that HUD’s final rule state that profit maximiza-
tion, cost minimization, and increasing market share all qualify as such inter-
ests. HUD expressly declined to do so, reasoning that “a determination of
what qualifies as a substantial, legitimate, nondiscriminatory interest for a
given entity is fact-specific and must be determined on a case-by-case basis
[and a]ccordingly, the final rule does not provide examples of interests that
would always qualify as substantial, legitimate, nondiscriminatory interests
for every respondent or defendant in any context.”
211
If the defendant satisfies this burden, the plaintiff may still establish
liability by proving that the “substantial, legitimate, nondiscriminatory inter-
est” could be advanced by a practice that has a less discriminatory effect.
212
207
See Implementation of the Fair Housing Act’s Discriminatory Effects Standard, 78 Fed.
Reg. 11460 (Feb. 15, 2013).
208
24 C.F.R. § 100.500(c) (2012); see also Implementation of the Fair Housing Act’s Dis-
criminatory Effects Standard, 78 Fed. Reg. 1146001, 11470 (Feb. 15, 2013) (“The word ‘le-
gitimate,’ used in its ordinary meaning, is intended to ensure that a justification is genuine and
not false, while the word ‘nondiscriminatory’ is intended to ensure that the justification for a
challenged practice does not itself discriminate based on a protected characteristic.”).
209
Inclusive Cmtys., 135 S. Ct. at 2512; see also id. at 2509 (“A robust causality require-
ment is important in ensuring that defendants do not resort to the use of racial quotas.”).
210
24 C.F.R. § 100.500(c).
211
Implementation of the Fair Housing Act’s Discriminatory Effects Standard, 78 Fed.
Reg. 11460, 11471 (Feb. 15, 2013).
212
Id. at 11460. For a list of cases in which defendants have succeeded, as well as cases in
they have failed, to persuade courts that the challenged policy is needed to advance a legiti-
mate interest, see Robert G. Schwemm & Calvin Bradford, Proving Disparate Impact in Fair
Housing Cases After Inclusive Communities, 19 N.Y.U. J. L
EGIS
. & P
UB
. P
OL
Y
685, 696,
nn.47-48 (2016).
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 39 19-OCT-18 12:58
2018] Exclusionary Taxation 657
This less discriminatory alternative “must be supported by evidence” that
the proposed alternative would serve the interests supporting the challenged
practice.
213
In a recent lawsuit, plaintiffs alleged that a city’s decision to re-
zone a parcel of land as residential-townhouse (“R-T”), facilitating only a
small number of single-family residential homes, as opposed to multifamily-
residential (“R-M”), permitting a larger number of residential units, violated
the Fair Housing Act.
214
On remand from the Second Circuit, the district
court found that the “R-M” zoning was less discriminatory towards racial
minorities than the R-T proposal while still serving the city’s interests in
minimizing school overcrowding and controlling traffic.
215
HUD’s test is holistic and analogous to other disparate impact tests
from antidiscrimination law. In the preamble to the final rule, the agency
clarified that the ‘substantial, legitimate, nondiscriminatory interest’ stan-
dard . . . is equivalent to the ‘business necessity’ standard” that agencies
have applied in both the fair lending context and the job-relatedness standard
of Title VII.
216
Further, the Fair Housing Act’s “broad, remedial goal” re-
quires both that “practices with discriminatory effects cannot be justified
based on interests of an insubstantial nature” and that “[t]he determination
of whether goals, objectives, and activities are of substantial interest to a
respondent or defendant such that they can justify actions with a discrimina-
tory effect requires a case-specific, fact-based inquiry.”
217
C. Diminished Deference
In addition to the procedural and substantive opportunities carved out
by the FHA, two twenty-first century Supreme Court cases offer support for
rigorous state-court protection of federal claims, including claims regarding
state taxes. We focus on Haywood v. Drown,
218
which reasserts federal
supremacy and scrutinizes state procedural sufficiency, and Direct Market-
ing Association v. Brohl,
219
which cabins efforts to strip federal courts of
jurisdiction over tax challenges.
The Supreme Court’s decision in Haywood rejected New York’s at-
tempted use of a specialized state adjudicatory forum to undermine enforce-
ment of federal rights.
220
In other words, state jurisdictional bait-and-
switches cannot be used to deprive actors of a meaningful mechanism to
213
Implementation of the Fair Housing Act’s Discriminatory Effects Standard, 78 Fed.
Reg. 11460, 1147273, 11482 (Feb. 15, 2013).
214
MHANY Mgmt., Inc. v. Cty. of Nassau, No. 05CV2301(ADS)(ARL), 2017 WL
4174787, at *1*2 (E.D.N.Y. Sept. 19, 2017).
215
See id. at *5, *9*12.
216
Implementation of the Fair Housing Act’s Discriminatory Effects Standard, 78 Fed.
Reg. 1146001, 11470 (Feb. 15, 2013).
217
Id. (emphasis added).
218
556 U.S. 729 (2009).
219
135 S. Ct. 1124 (2015).
220
Haywood, 556 U.S. at 733.
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 40 19-OCT-18 12:58
658 Harvard Civil Rights-Civil Liberties Law Review [Vol. 53
vindicate federal protections. Although the case arose outside the context of
taxation, it undermines prospective arguments that FHA challenges to taxes
must be shunted to non-judicial or other specialized tax adjudicators, partic-
ularly where the adjudicator would lack full authority to analyze the FHA
claim or provide a full remedy.
221
The Haywood Court struck down the New York statute, which stripped
state courts of general jurisdiction over state prisoners’ § 1983 claims and
relocated those claims in an alternative tribunal without jurisdiction to hear
personal-capacity claims, as unconstitutional.
222
The presumption of concur-
rency (between state and federal courts) is defeated only in “two narrowly
defined circumstances: first, when Congress expressly ousts state courts of
jurisdiction; and second, ‘[w]hen a state court refuses jurisdiction because
of a . . . state rule’” that applies neutrally to federal and non-federal
claims.
223
In analyzing whether the challenged jurisdictional rule qualified as
a neutral rule, the Court reaffirmed that “our cases have established that a
State cannot employ a jurisdictional rule ‘to dissociate [itself] from federal
law because of disagreement with its content or a refusal to recognize the
superior authority of its source.’
224
This mandate persists even though the
Supremacy Clause does not compel states to establish local courts ideally
positioned to effectuate federal law.
225
The Court rejected the neutrality argu-
ment and found that N.Y. Correction Law § 24 contravened Congress’s in-
tent to provide § 1983 relief and therefore contravened the Supremacy
Clause.
226
Haywood was, in some regard, a case of first impression, where the
Court disapproved of the jurisdictional subversion of federal mandates.
227
The Court had yet to confront a state statute “that registers its dissent by
221
See discussion supra Part II.B. This issue arose in the MorningSide case, discussed
below. See infra notes 28688, and accompanying text.
222
Haywood, 556 U.S. at 734. In precluding state courts of general jurisdiction from hear-
ing claims against Department of Corrections employees, N.Y. Correction Law § 24 left the
aggrieved party to “pursue a claim for damages against an entirely different party (the State) in
the Court of Claims
a court of limited jurisdiction.” N.Y. Correct. Law § 24.
223
Haywood, 556 U.S. at 735 (quoting Howlett v. Rose, 496 U.S. 356, 371 (1990)). The
express ousting was not implicated in Haywood.
224
Id. at 736 (quoting Howlett, 496 U.S. at 371).
225
See Howlett, 496 U.S. at 372 (“The States thus have great latitude to establish the
structure and jurisdiction of their own courts.”) (internal quotation marks and citations omit-
ted). Federal rights only need be enforced in state courts with jurisdiction “adequate to the
occasion.” Id. at 373 (quoting Second Employers’ Liab. Cases, 223 U.S. 1, 59 (1912)).
226
The Court specifically rejected New York’s rationale that the suits against corrections
officers are “too numerous or too frivolous (or both).” Haywood, 556 U.S. at 736. In doing so,
the Court explained that such a rationale “is contrary to Congress’s judgment that all persons
who violate federal rights while acting under color of state law shall be held liable for dam-
ages.” Id. at 730.
227
The Supreme Court explained that, while Congress passed § 1983 “to interpose the
federal courts between the States and the people, as guardians of the people’s federal rights . . .
state courts as well as federal courts are entrusted with providing a forum for the vindication of
federal rights violated by state or local officials acting under color of state law.” Id. at 735
(internal citations omitted).
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 41 19-OCT-18 12:58
2018] Exclusionary Taxation 659
divesting its courts of jurisdiction over a disfavored federal claim in addition
to an identical state claim.”
228
In establishing the procedural insufficiency of
the alternative tribunal, the Court noted that “plaintiffs in the Court of
Claims must comply with a 90day notice requirement; are not entitled to a
jury trial; have no right to attorney’s fees; and may not seek punitive dam-
ages or injunctive relief.”
229
Nondiscrimination, here manifested in New
York’s equal disapproval of state and federal claims against corrections of-
ficers, was not sufficient to insulate it from a Supremacy Clause challenge.
A jurisdictional rule that limits the relief available in a federal cause of ac-
tion, for example by channeling a federal claim to a forum that is unable to
provide the full range of legal and injunctive relief, should not be considered
“neutral.”
Another case, more squarely within the state-tax context, indicates the
Supreme Court’s willingness to limit expansive readings of the TIA, poten-
tially indicating openness to claims against state taxes more generally. In
Direct Marketing Association, the Court used the history of the TIA and
comity to explain that the TIA’s restriction on reviewing “the assessment,
levy or collection of any tax under State law” could not be stretched to strip
jurisdiction over challenges to any tax-related process.
230
Colorado, to improve tax collections from online purchases, required
retailers that did not collect Colorado sales or use tax to notify Colorado
customers of their use-tax liability and to report tax-related information to
customers and the Colorado Department of Revenue.
231
Direct Marketing
Association sued under § 1983, claiming that the use tax discriminated
against out-of-state retailers in violation of the dormant commerce clause.
232
Rejecting Colorado’s invocation of the TIA, the Supreme Court empha-
sized the explicit text of the Act, which limits district court’s power to “en-
join, suspend or restrain the assessment, levy or collection” of a state tax.
233
The Court held that Colorado’s “notice and reporting requirements” fell
outside these three categories because they “precede the steps of ‘assess-
ment’ and ‘collection.’
234
The Court likewise rejected a broad interpretation
of “suspend or restrain” in the Act, noting that “early courts did not refuse
to hear every suit that would have a negative impact on States’ revenues.”
235
228
Haywood, 556 U.S. at 73738.
229
Id. at 734 (internal citations omitted).
230
Direct Mktg. Ass’n v. Brohl, 135 S. Ct. 1124, 1126, 113132 (2015).
231
As the Court explained, Colorado requires its consumers who purchase goods from a
retailer that does not collect use taxes (“noncollecting retailers”) to remit taxes to the Colorado
Department of revenue directly. Because of predictably low rates of voluntary compliance,
Colorado enacted legislation imposing notice and reporting obligation on noncollecting retail-
ers. Id. at 112728.
232
Id. at 1128.
233
28 U.S.C.S. § 1341 (2012) (emphasis added).
234
Brohl, 135 S. Ct. at 1131. The Court explained that “the TIA is not keyed to all activi-
ties that may improve a State’s ability to assess and collect taxes,” thereby limiting the scope
of the Act. Id. at 1126.
235
Id. at 1133.
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 42 19-OCT-18 12:58
660 Harvard Civil Rights-Civil Liberties Law Review [Vol. 53
While the Court found that the TIA did not bar the suit as a jurisdictional
matter, Direct Marketing admittedly left open the question of whether com-
ity, as a nonjurisdictional doctrine, might favor dismissal.
236
While Direct
Marketing does not clearly permit injunctions regarding property tax assess-
ment,
237
the opinion reflects an openness to federal litigation regarding state
taxes, at least where a state taxing authority seeks to expand the jurisdiction-
stripping effect of the TIA beyond existing doctrine. This may signal a re-
treat from the earlier expansive interpretations of the TIA and comity doc-
trines, although it is unclear whether this trend will lead to greater judicial
comfort with damages lawsuits in federal courts or changed interpretations
of when a state remedy is “plain, speedy, and efficient.”
238
These procedural trends, when combined with the opportunity of the
FHA, offer taxpayer plaintiffs one path around the procedural obstacles of
the TIA and comity doctrine. Courts may be less willing to extend the limi-
tations on § 1983 claims from Fair Assessment and National Private Truck
Council to the FHA, in light of the statute’s explicit discussion of a cause of
action in state court.
239
Thus, FHA damages claims for discriminatory taxes
would be available in federal court, as by its terms, the TIA concerns only
injunctive (and related declaratory) relief. To the extent that plaintiffs seek
injunctive relief such as reassessments, however, the TIA would still ap-
ply
in fact, federal courts have specifically cited the availability of “effi-
cient”
240
FHA remedies in the state courts as a basis to apply the TIA’s
jurisdictional bar.
241
FHA claims for injunctive relief may therefore be lim-
ited to state courts in states where those courts provide a “plain, speedy, and
efficient remedy” for FHA claims.
Those state courts should take heed of Haywood’s prohibition on the
use of state procedural or jurisdictional rules to limit federal causes of ac-
tion. That is, a state may not be able to automatically relocate FHA chal-
236
Id. at 113334.
237
Id. at 1130 (“[Assessment] might also be understood more broadly to encompass the
process by which [the tax owed] is calculated.”).
238
See generally supra Part II (discussing the evolving application of the TIA and comity
in challenges to tax policies).
239
42 U.S.C. § 3613(a)(1)(A) (“An aggrieved person may commence a civil action in an
appropriate United States district court or State court.”).
240
Cmty. Dev., Inc. v. Sarpy Cty. Neb., No. 8:16CV135, 2016 WL 3748710, at *3 (D.
Neb. May 26, 2016), report and recommendation adopted, No. 8:16CV135, 2016 WL
3747545, at *1 (D. Neb. July 11, 2016) (relying on the FHA’s discussion of a cause of action in
state court as the plain, speedy and efficient state-court remedy depriving the federal district
court of jurisdiction over an FHA claim).
241
Reed v. Dorchester Cty., C/A No. 2:1476RMG, 2014 WL 3799433, at *3 (D.S.C.
July 8, 2014), report and recommendation adopted as modified, C/A No. 2:14CV76RMG,
2014 WL 3799502, at *2 (D.S.C. July 31, 2014) (same); cf. United States v. County of Nassau,
N.Y., 79 F. Supp. 2d 190, 19697 (E.D.N.Y. 2000) (relying on the Attorney General’s power
to intervene in a state court FHA case as sufficient state-court remedy to invoke the TIA). We
note that one court displaced FHA claims based on the incorrect reasoning that there is a plain,
speedy, and efficient remedy for constitutional claims in state courts. See Georgetown Property
Owners Ass’n v. Town of Georgetown, No. 01881SLR, 2002 WL 31319469 (D. Del. Sept.
27, 2002).
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 43 19-OCT-18 12:58
2018] Exclusionary Taxation 661
lenges to state tax tribunals from state courts of general jurisdiction, since a
“jurisdictional rule cannot be used as a device to undermine federal law, no
matter how evenhanded it may appear.”
242
Because of the aforementioned
state heterogeneity in tax appeal procedures and institutional arrange-
ments,
243
the proper forum for FHA challenges under Haywood must be de-
termined on a state-by-state basis. Meaningful state-court review requires a
state forum with the institutional and procedural disposition to adjudicate
these federal claims. Haywood also suggests that federal courts adopt a more
aggressive interpretation of the TIA’s exception for lack of a “plain, speedy,
and efficient remedy” in FHA cases. Where a limited-jurisdiction venue un-
dermines the relief available for an FHA claim, for example through lack of
capacity to evaluate discrimination claims, by limiting the availability of
systemic relief, or by providing no injunctive remedy, the state remedy is not
“plain, speedy, and efficient” and should not displace federal equity
jurisdiction.
244
IV.
N
ORDLINGER
R
EVISITED
: A
DDRESSING
E
XCLUSIONARY
T
AXATION
WITH THE
F
AIR
H
OUSING
A
CT
Having identified the potential for fair housing challenges to property
tax policies, we consider, in this Part, how courts have and should adjudicate
challenges to exclusionary taxation regimes. Although different aspects of a
tax regime could have actionable discriminatory effects,
245
we focus here on
the use of the FHA to address property tax assessment policies.
We have chosen California’s Proposition 13, and resulting Article
XIIIA, as our poster child for exclusionary taxation, based in part on the
Supreme Court’s holding in Nordlinger that the regime passed constitutional
muster.
246
Because of California’s increasingly diverse population, the poten-
tially perpetual property tax relief Article XIIIA provides to historically
early homebuyers, and particularly their inheritors, is ripe for challenge
under the Fair Housing Act. We identify several avenues for potential FHA
plaintiffs to change all or part of California’s Article XIIIA. These include
both disproportionate effect claims, based on the higher taxes that recent
242
Haywood, 556 U.S. at 739.
243
See supra section II.B discussing state review heterogeneity.
244
The 9th Circuit has recognized, in an equal protection case, that these protections are
all the more important in cases alleging racial discrimination. See Lowe, 627 F.3d at 1156.
Admittedly, the opinion does not mention the FHA, a non-constitutional remedy for
discrimination.
245
For example, many states and localities tax or assess multifamily properties at a differ-
ent rate from single-family properties. Differential treatment of multifamily property is famil-
iar territory for “exclusionary zoning” litigation, so it would be unsurprising to find similar
discriminatory effects from tax disadvantages for multifamily property. See Lawrence Gene
Sager, Tight Little Islands: Exclusionary Zoning, Equal Protection, and the Indigent, 21 S
TAN
.
L. R
EV
. 767, 78081 (1969) (defining and initially explaining exclusionary zoning, albeit
outside the disparate impact framework that would later develop around the Fair Housing Act).
246
Nordlinger, 505 U.S. at 1718.
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 44 19-OCT-18 12:58
662 Harvard Civil Rights-Civil Liberties Law Review [Vol. 53
arrivals pay relative to their more established neighbors, and segregative ef-
fect claims, based on the racial calcification of housing patterns. In particu-
lar, we predict that courts will be skeptical of the privileged treatment of
intrafamilial transfers.
247
To inform our discussion of the claims against California’s system, we
first examine two important, yet underanalyzed, examples of property tax
litigation under the FHA. We then discuss the questions that would be raised
at each stage of the FHA analysis. How could a plaintiff prove a disparate
impact under various theories? Even given a disparate impact, what might
constitute a “substantial, legitimate, nondiscriminatory interest” to justify
Article XIIIA, and what might comprise a less discriminatory alternative to
the current property tax policy?
A. Prior Disparate Impact Challenges to Property Tax Assessment
We now examine the challenges and consequences of disparate impact
liability through prior litigation. Both cases detailed below address allega-
tions of racially discriminatory property value assessments based, in part, on
a lack of universal and current fair market value assessments. In Long Is-
land, the allegations stemmed from the underassessment of property values
in non-minority neighborhoods relative to fair market value. This led minor-
ity homeowners to bear a greater share of the tax burden. In Wayne County
(which houses Detroit), plaintiffs alleged that the overassessment of property
values in African-American neighborhoods led to such unreasonable tax bur-
dens for African-American homeowners that the county foreclosed on their
homes for inability to pay. The cases, particularly the Wayne County litiga-
tion, also illustrate how heterogeneous state procedures and remedies (or
lack thereof) can stymie collective redress.
1. Coleman v. Seldin
At the turn of the twenty-first century, a New York state trial court
recognized the FHA’s prohibition on exclusionary taxation, amid significant
procedural and jurisdictional tumult.
248
The resulting settlement completely
overhauled Nassau County’s assessment scheme. This case, barely discussed
247
These provisions were added to Proposition 13’s structure by Propositions 58 (Nov.
1986) and 193 (Mar. 1996). See Cal. Const., Art. XIIIA § 2.
248
While the plaintiffs alleged an additional federal statutory violation under Title VI
based on a disparate impact theory, the state court rejected this theory and invoked Second
Circuit precedent to support its conclusion. Coleman v. Seldin, 687 N.Y.S.2d 240, 242 (Sup.
Ct. 1999). In 2005, the U.S. Supreme Court agreed and found that Title VI does not permit a
private right of action to enforce its regulatory disparate impact liability. Alexander v. Sando-
val, 532 U.S. 275, 293 (2001). Thus, for the purposes of contemporary law and this Article,
there are no disparate impact challenges to property taxation schemes cognizable under Title
VI.
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 45 19-OCT-18 12:58
2018] Exclusionary Taxation 663
in legal scholarship,
249
represents an invocation of the FHA to challenge an
allegedly racially discriminatory system and the procedural challenges that
face plaintiffs who seek to change discriminatory systems.
Nassau County’s “controversial and archaic” assessment system oper-
ated as follows at the end of the twentieth century.
250
Nassau County as-
sessed residences housing one to three families and certain condominiums
using a combination of construction cost in 1938 dollars, less depreciation,
and value of the underlying land as determined by a county-wide valuation
from 1964.
251
The continued use of this system in the late 1990s reflected a
variation on the “tax revolt” narrative
efforts by property owners to re-
strict and lower property taxes.
252
A 1975 New York Court of Appeals deci-
sion insisting on equal assessments for all property classes statewide
spurred, in the words of the New York Times, the “kind of anger that fueled
[California’s] Proposition 13.”
253
In response, New York state legislators,
led by representatives from Nassau County, passed a statute that specifically
preserved the county’s assessment system.
254
The omission of contemporary market valuation in assessment caused
an adverse impact on African-American and Hispanic homeowners in the
county.
255
Since the system reflected historical rather than current market
values and “[b]ecause property values in non-minority areas ha[d] risen
faster than property values in minority neighborhoods,” the system com-
pelled Nassau County’s minority owners to pay higher property taxes, as a
fraction of the current market property value, than property owners in non-
minority areas.
256
By one estimate, homeowners in largely minority areas
249
There are fleeting mentions of Coleman, 687 N.Y.S.2d at 242 in only three law review
articles uncovered in our research of Coleman and the federal companion case, United States
v. Cty. of Nassau, 79 F. Supp. 2d 190, 19192 (E.D.N.Y. 2000); see also Alan Vinegrad, The
Role of the Prosecutor: Serving the Interests of All the People, 28 H
OFSTRA
L. R
EV
. 895, 903
(2000) (noting author’s involvement in “[a] landmark lawsuit challenging Nassau County’s
method of valuating residential real estate for tax purposes
a system that has resulted in gross
inequities that disfavored minorities for many years.”); Florence Wagman Roisman, Opening
the Suburbs to Racial Integration: Lessons for the 21st Century, 23 W. N
EW
E
NG
. L. R
EV
. 65,
110 n.241 (2001) (referencing Coleman as an example of how to challenge discriminatory
housing taxes).
250
Cty. of Nassau, 79 F. Supp. 2d at 19697.
251
See id. at 19192.
252
See supra note 1415 (discussing historical meaning of “tax revolt”).
R
253
Eric Schmitt, L.I. Rebels Over Property-Tax Rises, N.Y. T
IMES
(Feb. 26, 1989), http://
www.nytimes.com/1989/02/26/nyregion/li-rebels-over-property-tax-rises.html [https://perma
cc/386R-VPVX]; see also Darien Shanske, How Less Can Be More: Using the Federal In-
come Tax to Stabilize State and Local Finance, 31 V
A
. T
AX
R
EV
. 413, 44445 (2012) (describ-
ing Proposition 13 as the “first shot of the modern property tax revolt”).
254
O’Shea v. Bd. of Assessors of Nassau Cty., 864 N.E.2d 1261, 126264 (N.Y. 2007)
(describing the course of events leading to the Coleman litigation).
255
Id.
256
Cty. of Nassau, 79 F. Supp. 2d at 191. Although these allegations were never put to
proof at trial, we accept the analysis as true for the purpose of this discussion.
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 46 19-OCT-18 12:58
664 Harvard Civil Rights-Civil Liberties Law Review [Vol. 53
paid taxes on assessments that were “27% higher relative to current property
values than assessments in mostly white areas.”
257
The litigation against Nassau County’s tax system operated on two par-
allel tracks: county residents represented by the New York Civil Liberties
Union exercised the FHA’s private right of action in state court, while then-
U.S. Attorney for the Eastern District of New York Loretta Lynch brought
parallel claims in federal court.
258
The federal district court dismissed the U.S. Attorney’s lawsuit, relying
on the availability of the state court FHA claim as a “plain, speedy, and
efficient” remedy.
259
Even prior to the dismissal, the federal court seemed
particularly concerned about the lawsuit’s interference in state taxation, not-
ing that “diversion of employees’ time and attention from municipal busi-
ness . . . to otherwise assist in the pursuit of this litigation, would be an
unnecessary expense in the event that Nassau County’s motion to dismiss is
ultimately granted.”
260
The court thus held that it lacked jurisdiction under
the TIA to enter injunctive or declaratory relief and would refrain from
awarding damages under principles of comity.
261
In the state court action, Coleman v. Seldin, the court denied the
county’s motion to dismiss, holding that the FHA permitted a disparate im-
pact cause of action for the aggrieved taxpayers.
262
The court noted the broad
application of the FHA, the strength of the public policy interest in its en-
forcement, and the validity of the disparate impact standard.
263
The court
particularly noted the relationship to insurance redlining cases. Like discrim-
inatory tax assessments, discriminatory insurance practices both discriminate
in “the provision of services in connection with a dwelling” and would
make housing more expensive (and therefore “unavailable”).
264
Coleman
257
Id.
258
Id. The federal government complaint alleged that “this assessment methodology con-
stitutes discrimination in the terms, conditions, and privileges of the sale of dwellings and in
the provision of services and facilities related to the sale of dwellings, in violation of the Fair
Housing Amendments Act of 1988, 42 U.S.C. §§ 3604(b) and 3605(a)” and “further contends
that Nassau County’s methodology constitutes a pattern and practice of resistance to minorities’
enjoyment of rights under the Fair Housing Act, as amended, 42 U.S.C. § 3601 et seq. Cty. of
Nassau, 79 F. Supp. 2d at 191.
259
Cty. of Nassau, 79 F. Supp. 2d at 197. The United States did not challenge Nassau
County’s assertion that a speedy and efficient remedy existed under New York law. Rather, the
United States argued that the TIA contained an implicit exception “allowing the Government
to sue to effectuate its own statutes and policies.” Id.
260
United States v. Cty. of Nassau, 188 F.R.D. 187, 189 (E.D.N.Y. 1999). In granting the
county’s request to stay discovery pending a ruling on the county’s ultimately successful mo-
tion to dismiss, the court believed that “[t]he interests of fairness, economy and efficiency
therefore favor[ed] the issuance of a stay of discovery at th[at] time.”
261
Id.
262
Coleman, 687 N.Y.S.2d at 250. The county does not appear to have argued that the
court lacked jurisdiction to hear the FHA claim.
263
Id. at 248-50.
264
Id. at 249 (citing N.A.A.C.P. v. Am. Family Mut. Ins. Co., 978 F.2d 287 (7th Cir.
1992)); see N.A.A.C.P., 978 F.2d at 297-98 (accepting the applicability of these prohibitions in
the FHA to insurance redlining); 42 U.S.C. § 3604(a)-(b) (2012).
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 47 19-OCT-18 12:58
2018] Exclusionary Taxation 665
settled two days prior to going to trial in state court.
265
Consequently, the
court did not evaluate Nassau County’s justifications for the assessment
practice.
266
As a practical matter, the litigation led the county, home to some
of the nation’s highest property taxes, to engage in mass reassessment.
267
The
new assessment scheme raised the property taxes of an estimated one third
of affected homeowners,
268
catalyzing an increase in taxpayer appeals. But it
also placed the county on more solid fiscal footing, while resolving the legal
challenge to the prior discriminatory regime.
269
Perhaps inspired by the suc-
cess in Nassau County, a coalition of property owners recently filed an FHA
case in state court to change New York City’s assessment system.
270
Coleman illustrates the potential of the FHA to compel a local govern-
ment to overhaul its assessment methods where the chronic underassessment
of historically early homeowners leads to racially disparate impacts. On a
narrow procedural ground, Coleman also reinforced the applicability of the
TIA in a new context
for litigation brought by the federal government
and reflected a fair application of the “plain, speedy, and efficient remedy”
standard where a state court’s jurisdiction over the federal claim compelled
the dismissal of a related civil rights action in federal court.
271
Because of the
settlement, however, the Coleman court never reached the merits or consid-
ered the justifications for Nassau County’s assessment scheme.
2. MorningSide v. Sabree
Unlike Coleman, where the allegations of racially discriminatory as-
sessments were premised in the underassessment of non-minority neighbor-
hoods relative to fair market values, MorningSide v. Sabree focused on the
overassessment of minority neighborhoods relative to fair market values.
The lawsuit’s FHA claim was dismissed on jurisdictional grounds that raise
significant questions about whether Michigan courts provide a “plain,
265
Bruce Lambert, Nassau Property Taxes: Going Up, Going Down, and Getting Fairer,
N.Y. T
IMES
(Jul. 10, 2002), http://www.nytimes.com/2002/07/10/nyregion/nassau-property-
taxes-going-up-going-down-and-getting-fairer.html [https://permacc/N8WM-Z4M4].
266
Id.
267
Id.
268
Id.
269
Aside from the allegations of racial discrimination, the earlier assessments had left the
county in debt. Property owners would successfully go to court to challenge their assessments
as excessive and secured more than $100 million of refunds annually. Id. These refunds con-
tributed to the county’s fiscal crisis, resulting in a bailout by the state of New York and the
appointment of a state board to oversee the county’s finances. Id. By implementing the Cole-
man settlement, the county increased its property tax revenue by more than $119 million,
helping to close a recurring budget deficit. N
ASSAU
C
OUNTY
I
NTERIM
F
INANCE
A
UTHORITY
,
2003 A
NNUAL
R
EPORT
(2003), https://www.nifa.state.ny.us/reports_financial/annual/2003An-
nualReport.pdf [https://permacc/4ZZ3-QAYG].
270
Complaint, Tax Equity Now NY LLC v. City of New York, No. 153759/2017 (Sup. Ct.
N.Y. Cnty.Apr. 25, 2017); see Lois Weiss, NYC’s property tax assessment system is unconsti-
tutional: suit, N.Y. P
OST
(Apr. 25, 2017), https://nypost.com/2017/04/25/nycs-property-tax-
assessment-system-is-unconstitutional-suit/ [https://permacc/YB24-AVWN].
271
See Coleman v. Seldin, 687 N.Y.S.2d 240 (Sup. Ct. 1999).
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 48 19-OCT-18 12:58
666 Harvard Civil Rights-Civil Liberties Law Review [Vol. 53
speedy, and efficient” remedy for racially discriminatory property tax sys-
tems.
272
Moreover, the MorningSide FHA claim presented several challeng-
ing questions regarding proof of impact and legitimate, non-discriminatory
justification, which could arise in other litigation against exclusionary
taxation.
In 2016, the ACLU of Michigan and NAACP Legal Defense Fund, rep-
resenting a group of Detroit neighborhood associations and homeowners,
filed a class-action lawsuit in state court against the Treasurer of Wayne
County, Michigan.
273
The homeowners sought an injunction pursuant to the
FHA
274
halting tax foreclosure practices that have a racially disproportionate
impact across the county, due in part to unverified and racially discrimina-
tory tax assessments.
275
The complaint alleged that owner-occupied homes in
census blocks where the majority of homeowners were African-American
were more than ten times more likely to be at risk of foreclosure sale than
such homes in majority non-African-American census blocks.
276
Tax assess-
ment in Michigan is initially conducted by municipalities, although counties
have a role in reviewing tax assessments and conducting tax foreclosures.
277
Because assessors in Detroit (and majority-African-American suburbs)
failed to update assessments to reflect declines in property values during the
Great Recession, Detroit homeowners were assessed taxes as if their homes
272
MorningSide Cmty. Org., supra note 12, (ruling that the trial court lacked jurisdiction),
R
leave to appeal denied, 905 N.W.2d 597 (Mich. 2018).
273
MorningSide v. Sabree, No. 16-008807-CH (Mich. 3d Cir. Ct.).
274
42 U.S.C. § 3613(a)(1)(A) (2012) (granting private parties a cause of action to seek an
injunction enforcing the Fair Housing Act).
275
Complaint at 4648, MorningSide v. Sabree, No. 16-008807-CH (Mich. 3d Cir. Ct.
July 13, 2016) [hereinafter MorningSide Complaint]. The lawsuit includes a separate constitu-
tional due process claim, alleging that the City of Detroit’s process for granting tax exemptions
for homeowners in poverty is procedurally defective. Id. at 47-48. The MorningSide plaintiffs
allege that the significant racial disparities in tax foreclosures are caused by the County’s prac-
tice of foreclosing on owner-occupied homes for unpaid taxes without meaningfully verifying
the accuracy of the underlying tax debts. Id. at 15-21. Under the Michigan constitution, the
taxable value of a property can be no more than one-half its True Cash Value (a defined term
corresponding to fair market value). M
ICH
. C
ONST
. Art. IX § 3. See generally Bernadette
Atuhene & Timothy R. Hodge, Stategraft 91 S. C
AL
. L. R
EV
. (forthcoming 2018). Wayne
County did not contest the underlying questions of assessment accuracy or disparate impact,
even in response to a preliminary injunction motion. Instead, the county largely relied on
jurisdictional arguments, arguments that the Fair Housing Act does not relate to property tax
foreclosure, and arguments about whether the disparities were caused by a County policy.
County Defendants’ Motion for Summary Disposition at 8-13, MorningSide v. Sabree, No. 16-
008807-CH [hereinafter MorningSide Motion for Summary Disposition]. As discussed below,
the courts have so far resolved the issue on the jurisdictional ground.
276
MorningSide Complaint, supra note 275, at 21. Since 2002, more than 150,000 proper-
R
ties, strongly concentrated in African-American communities, have gone through the Wayne
County tax foreclosure auction. Loveland Technologies, 2017 Tax Foreclosure Auction, L
OVE-
LAND
, https://makeloveland.com/2016/mi/wayne#b=admin [https://permacc/W77D-3Z6Q].
277
Mich. Comp. Laws § 211.10 (2018) (municipal assessment), § 211.34 (2018) (equali-
zation), § 211.57 (2018) (municipal return of delinquent taxes to county treasurer for
collection).
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 49 19-OCT-18 12:58
2018] Exclusionary Taxation 667
were worth between double and eleven times the actual fair-market value.
278
Assessors in other Wayne County municipalities that have greater propor-
tions of white homeowners assessed homes more frequently and more accu-
rately.
279
Detroit’s inflated property values had a particularly stark effect on
homeowners because the city’s property tax rates are among the highest in
the country.
280
State and local officials acknowledged that Detroit properties
were overassessed and began reducing property assessments beginning in
2014.
281
But this admission came too late for homeowners whose overas-
sessed taxes were already in default, leading to foreclosure.
282
The MorningSide case crystallizes the procedural issues that sometimes
arise when assessment policies are challenged under the FHA in a jurisdic-
tion with a designated tax adjudicator. Michigan law vests exclusive juris-
diction over tax matters with the Michigan Tax Tribunal, an administrative,
quasi-judicial body with limited powers and jurisdiction.
283
Wayne County
successfully argued that any claim that touches on property tax assessment
must be litigated in the Tax Tribunal.
284
The case therefore squarely con-
cerned the effect of the FHA’s guarantee of a cause of action in “state
court,” as well as the significance of Haywood’s protection of federal claims
against state procedural interference. Because the Tax Tribunal has limited
278
For a description of the declining value of Detroit properties, see Housing Finance
Policy Center, Detroit Housing Tracker, U
RBAN
I
NSTITUTE
5 (Apr. 2016), http://www.urban
.org/sites/default/files/alfresco/publication-pdfs/2000739-Detroit-Housing-Tracker-Q1-2016
.pdf [https://permacc/3QT3-PP3R]; see also Michelle Wilde Anderson, The New Minimal Cit-
ies, 123 Y
ALE
L. J. 1118, 114243 (2014) (discussing the role of falling property values in
Detroit and other economically insolvent cities’ fiscal troubles, with a particular focus on the
effects of reverse redlining). In addition to Detroit, smaller majority African-American cities in
Wayne County, such as Inkster and Highland Park also experienced high rates of tax foreclo-
sure. See Anderson, 123 Y
ALE
L. J., at 113536, 1180 (discussing how economically “dis-
tressed suburb[s]” are being pushed to become “new minimal cit[ies]”).
279
See generally Atuahene, supra note 21.
280
At 3.385%, Detroit’s effective tax rates on owner-occupied properties have consistently
ranked among the very highest in the country. See L
INCOLN
C
ENTER FOR
L
AND
P
OLICY
&
M
INNESOTA
C
ENTER FOR
F
ISCAL
E
XCELLENCE
, supra note 36, at 2.
281
See Most Detroit Residents to See Property Assessment Reductions This Summer, C
ITY
OF
D
ETROIT
(Jan. 28, 2015), http://www.detroitmi.gov/News/ArticleID/24/Most-Detroit-
Homeowners-to-See-Property-Assessment-Reductions-This-Summer [https://permacc/X8PN-
84N7]; Christine MacDonald, State Launches Look into Detroit Tax Assessments, D
ETROIT
N
EWS
(Apr. 9, 2013), 2013 WLNR 8740534.
282
Detroit residents must appeal an assessment between February 1 and February 15 of
the relevant tax year. Detroit, Michigan, Municipal Code § 18-9-3(b). Property assessments
are announced in late January, and taxes are not billed until the summer. Relying on homeown-
ers’ failure to appeal their assessments, the county has asserted that the tax assessments must
be treated as accurate
particularly once a foreclosure judgment has been entered. Morning-
Side Motion for Summary Disposition, supra note 275, at 13.
R
283
See MorningSide Opinion on County Defendants’ Motion for Summary Disposition (on
file with authors); Mich. Comp. Laws 205.731. The exclusivity of the Tax Tribunal’s jurisdic-
tion has been construed broadly to include any “attack on the validity of . . . property tax
assessments,” even when that attack is couched in constitutional terms. Johnson v. State, 317
N.W.2d 652, 657 (1982).
284
County Defendants’ Motion for Summary Disposition at 13, MorningSide v. Sabree,
No. 16-008807-CH.
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 50 19-OCT-18 12:58
668 Harvard Civil Rights-Civil Liberties Law Review [Vol. 53
powers and expertise, it lacks the ability to offer relief for the MorningSide
disparate impact claim; the purportedly neutral state procedural rule granting
it exclusive jurisdiction would thus nullify the federal cause of action, remi-
niscent of how the New York limited-jurisdiction court could not offer relief
for § 1983 claims against prison guards.
285
Beyond the jurisdictional issues, the MorningSide case also introduced
important questions for the consideration of a taxing jurisdiction’s “substan-
tial, legitimate, nondiscriminatory interest” under the Fair Housing Act dis-
parate impact analysis.
A troubled county undoubtedly has a legitimate interest in the collec-
tion of revenue. Older, predominantly African-American cities such as East
Cleveland and Detroit continue to grapple with existential crises borne of
declining economic activity and property tax bases.
286
But foreclosures based
on inaccurate assessments are unnecessary for revenue collection, particu-
larly given their ineffectiveness.
287
Moreover, they are hardly the least dis-
criminatory means to advance that interest.
288
Plaintiffs have offered
nondiscriminatory alternatives, such as preferential treatment of occupied
properties, which could generate greater tax revenue in the longer term by
maintaining value in the property at issue and surrounding properties.
285
For example, while a claim may require analyzing the relationship between tax assess-
ments and the value of the assessed properties, the assessment issues are not the full extent of
the Fair Housing Act prima facie case, and the Tax Tribunal’s expertise in technical matters of
taxation does not correspond to an expertise in evaluating evidence of disparate racial impact.
The Michigan Court of Appeals did not adopt this reasoning. MorningSide v. Wayne Cty., No.
336430, 2017 WL 4182985 at *3. Moreover, the racial effects of a tax assessment policy may
not be observable until after the time frame for agency review of taxes or assessments. In the
case of Wayne County, the disparity arose as a result of the county’s foreclosure policies
which affected homeowners years after the appeal period for assessments.
286
Michelle Wilde Anderson, Cities Inside Out: Race, Poverty, and Exclusion at the Ur-
ban Fringe, 55 UCLA L. R
EV
. 1095, 112223 (2008) (describing how cities like Cleveland,
Dallas, and Detroit struggle to adapt to declining manufacturing sectors and growing poverty).
Some have argued that reviving these localities may require redrawing their fiscal and political
borders. See, e.g., Michael W. McConnell & Randal C. Picker, When Cities Go Broke: A
Conceptual Introduction to Municipal Bankruptcy, 60 U. C
HI
. L. R
EV
. 425, 427 (1993)
(describing various ways to conceptualize the city, and the implications of such definition for
redrawing fiscal borders); Emily Bamforth, What East Cleveland Bankruptcy Could Mean for
a Cleveland Merger, Plus Other Aspects to Consider, C
LEVELAND
.
COM
(May 12, 2016), http://
www.cleveland.com/metro/index.ssf/2016/05/what_bankruptcy_could_mean_for.html [https://
permacc/5SDC-BJX2] (describing consequences of East Cleveland’s bankruptcy for neighbor-
ing jurisdictions).
287
The MorningSide plaintiffs presented preliminary evidence that foreclosure auctions
fail to recover the unpaid tax revenue because of limited demand. See Margaret Dewar, et al.,
Disinvesting in the City: The Role of Tax Foreclosure in Detroit, 51 U
RB
. A
FFAIRS
R
EV
. 587,
592 (2015). For occupied properties, the process of foreclosure too often led to disinvestment,
undermining neighborhoods and weakening the tax base further. Id. at 60005.
288
In one regard, the situation in Detroit notably resembles the claim in Allegheny Pitts-
burgh, supra note 128, at 435. In both cases, inaccurate property assessments were the result
R
of municipal assessors’ choices and mistakes contrary to the requirements of state law, as
opposed to a set of inaccurate assessments that resulted from a particular assessment regime
mandated by law. It would therefore be implausible for Wayne County to collect the admit-
tedly inaccurate assessments.
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 51 19-OCT-18 12:58
2018] Exclusionary Taxation 669
The county may also assert procedural interests, such as the uniform
application of state tax procedures, the finality of tax assessments, or an
efficient tax foreclosure process. These interests are conceptually distinct
from an argument that state law requires a certain set of procedures, which
would likely be insufficient in light of the FHA’s preemption provision. For
example, the general preference for intrastate uniformity is sensible.
289
How-
ever, using this interest to justify a practice with a disparate impact would
ignore an important feature of the disparate impact claim. Disparate impact
claims often reflect the interaction of neutral policies with social realities
related to protected classes. For example, in the MorningSide case, the dispa-
rate impact arises because of racial segregation across Wayne County and
uneven assessment quality between municipalities.
290
A strong regard for in-
tra-state uniformity would therefore undermine the effectiveness of the dis-
parate impact remedy to address those circumstances in which a neutral
policy has discriminatory effects.
291
As for the goals of efficiency and final-
ity, they are generally closely tied with the underlying goal of revenue col-
lection. To the extent that tax foreclosures fail to collect revenue effectively,
a more speedy process offers little independent interest for a local
government.
292
So far, the Michigan courts have not accepted plaintiffs’ arguments that
the general jurisdiction court is the appropriate venue for an FHA lawsuit.
The Michigan Court of Appeals recently affirmed the dismissal of Plaintiffs’
FHA claims as falling within the exclusive jurisdiction of the Tax
Tribunal.
293
In both Wayne County and Nassau County, assessment practices fa-
vored white homeowners over minority homeowners. Litigants’ attempts to
challenge these systems illustrate the need for meaningful state-court review,
or a federal-court backstop, to ensure that their rights under the FHA are
protected. Moreover, these cases call into question the justification for as-
sessment policies that fail to reflect current property values.
289
Cf. Wilson v. Garcia, 471 U.S. 261, 26668 (1985) (recognizing generally, in the con-
text of statutes of limitations across courts, the value of intra-state uniformity).
290
See the discussion of the origins and purposes of disparate impact claims at supra
notes 176194, and accompanying text.
R
291
Moreover, in other contexts, courts nominally look more favorably on narrow, as-ap-
plied challenges to state actions, rather than more intrusive facial challenges. See Richard H.
Fallon, Jr., Fact and Fiction About Facial Challenges, 99 C
AL
. L. R
EV
. 915, 923 (2011). The
result of a successful as-applied challenge is disuniformity in the application of the challenged
law or policy.
292
In the Michigan example, the tax foreclosure system was streamlined to prevent blight
that had resulted from murky titles. See Kevin T. Smith, An Update on Foreclosure of Real
Property Tax Liens Under Michigan’s New Tax Foreclosure Process, 36 M
ICH
. R
EAL
P
ROP
.
R
EV
. 30 (2009).
293
MorningSide v. Wayne Cty., No. 336430, 2017 WL 4182985.
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 52 19-OCT-18 12:58
670 Harvard Civil Rights-Civil Liberties Law Review [Vol. 53
B. Litigating Challenges to California’s Article XIIIA
We now turn to California’s Article XIIIA to illuminate the theoretical
conflicts between rights afforded to increasingly diverse residents under the
FHA and the justification that already withstood rational-basis review: local
communities’ “stability.”
1. The Prima Facie FHA Case and Relevant Empirical Evidence
There are several FHA claims that could be brought against California’s
system. While we discuss suggestive empirical evidence and illustrative cal-
culations, we leave the requisite detailed empirical assessments to prospec-
tive litigants and future researchers.
294
First, more recently arrived California homeowners
295
could challenge
Article XIIIA as discriminating in the provision of services or facilities in
connection with their dwellings.
296
This “disproportionate effect” claim
would therefore mirror the claim in Coleman that succeeded in forcing
changes to the Long Island underassessment of minority households.
Hispanic or Asian-American homeowners may be able to show that
California’s system leads to higher property taxes for them as compared to
their white neighbors. As discussed above, the additional property tax bur-
den borne by a newer resident could add the equivalent of an additional 20%
of the newer resident’s monthly mortgage payment.
297
Indeed, Isaac William
Martin and Kevin Beck have estimated that rate and assessment limitations
such as Article XIIIA have a statistically significant effect favoring white
homeowners over homeowners of other races.
298
They conclude that property
294
Supra notes 5455 and accompanying text.
R
295
Although contemporary non-resident investors in California homes may also be more
diverse than their predecessors, courts have rejected claims by such commercial investors for
Fair Housing Act protection based on the investors’ own identities. See, e.g., Germain v. M&T
Bank Corp., 111 F. Supp. 3d 506, 52122 (S.D.N.Y. 2015); Home Quest Mortg. v. Am. Fam-
ily Mutual Ins. Co., 340 F.Supp.2d 1177, 1185 (D. Kan. 2004).
296
42 U.S.C. § 3604(b) (2012). Although it would not be binding on a California state
court, the Ninth Circuit relied on this provision of the Fair Housing Act to support a post-
acquisition cause of action based on failure to provide municipal services and the distribution
of property tax revenues for predominantly Hispanic unincorporated neighborhoods in The
Committee Concerning Community Improvement v. City of Modesto, 583 F.3d 690, 714 (9th
Cir. 2009).
297
See supra notes 5455, and accompanying text.
R
298
Isaac William Martin & Kevin Beck, Property Tax Limitations and Racial Inequality in
Effective Tax Rates, 43 C
RITICAL
S
OC
. 221, 229 (2017) (“Although most of the interaction
terms taken singly are not statistically significant, a test of joint statistical significance shows
that the interaction terms are jointly different from zero (
÷
2 = 22.5, 9 df, p < .05), providing
evidence that the effects of property tax limitation differ by race and ethnicity. Most of these
coefficients are consistent with the interpretation that white homeowners derive the greatest
benefit from property tax limitation.”). Martin and Beck’s methodology relies both on a na-
tionally-representative longitudinal dataset of self-reported tax burdens and the fact that differ-
ent states have different property tax regimes, which have changed over time. Id. at 226. They
can thus estimate how property tax burdens differ for respondents based on race and state
property tax features, after controlling for other demographic covariates. Id. at 228.
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 53 19-OCT-18 12:58
2018] Exclusionary Taxation 671
tax limitations serve to “entrench, and even to exacerbate, structural features
of local property taxation that favor white property owners, most especially
the bias in favor of long-term owners of high-value homes.”
299
While their
suggestive evidence provides support for the racial effects from a broader
landscape, a jurisdiction-specific legal challenge would likely require more
granular, rather than national, data for the pleadings.
The Martin and Beck study is consistent with California’s story, in light
of the interaction between assessment growth ceilings and significant demo-
graphic shifts since 1978. Between 1980 and 2015, the Asian-American and
Hispanic shares of California’s population both more than doubled.
300
Newer
California homeowners are presumably more likely to have been a member
of these ethnic groups, even putting aside the differences in wealth across
racial groups for Californians who were present in 1978.
301
Because the
newer, ethnically diverse homeowners bought their houses later, the benefit
that they receive from Article XIIIA’s assessment growth ceiling would be
less than their longer-standing, white neighbors. Similarly, newly affluent
“ethnoburbs”
302
have seen significant growth in property value since
299
Id. at 233. This Article primarily addresses what Beck and Martin describe as “assess-
ment limitation,” whereas they also study “rate limitations” (1% in California after Proposi-
tion 13).
300
Public Policy Institute of California, California’s Population, March 2017, http://www
.ppic.org/publication/californias-population/ [https://permacc/976F-BBA3]. At the same time,
“homeownership among Californians 45 and younger has fallen by around one-third since
1980.” C
AL
. L
EG
. A
NALYST
S
O
FFICE
, C
OMMON
C
LAIMS
A
BOUT
P
ROPOSITION
13, 42 (2016),
http://www.lao.ca.gov/reports/2016/3497/common-claims-prop13-091916.pdf [https://perma
cc/2629-JQ6S]; see also Comment by Fernando Vendramel Ferreira on Nada Wasi & Michelle
White, Property tax limitations and mobility: the lock-in effect of California’s Proposition 13,
B
ROOKINGS
-W
HARTON
P
APERS ON
U
RBAN
A
FFAIRS
59, 94 (Figure 2), 2005 (charting Califor-
nia’s homeownership rate by age bracket based on 2000 Census data).
301
To illustrate 1978 inequalities, consider that the 1970 Census identified a 54% home-
ownership rate for all Californians in metropolitan areas and 61.4% in non-metropolitan areas,
while African-American Californians had only a 39% homeownership rate in metropolitan
areas and 44% in nonmetropolitan areas. U.S. C
ENSUS
B
UREAU
, 1970 C
ENSUS OF
P
OPULATION
AND
H
OUSING
: C
ALIFORNIA
9 (1971). While mixed-race availability in the 2000 Census makes
it unwise to create a comparison, we note that the homeownership rates for the 2000 Census
were 56.9 percent overall in California, and the racial rates were 62.6 percent for those identi-
fying only as white, 38.8 percent for those identifying only as African-American, and 43.7
percent for those identifying as Hispanic. U.S. C
ENSUS
B
UREAU
, H
ISTORICAL
C
ENSUS OF
H
OUSING
T
ABLES
(2000), https://www.census.gov/hhes/www/housing/census/historic/owner-
shipbyrace.html [https://permacc/26RR-ULJM]. Since 2000, the demographic composition of
homeownership has continued to change. In 2000, there were approximately 4.3 million
owner-occupied homes in California headed by non-Hispanic white people; 1.1 million by
Hispanic people; 613,000 by Asian-American people; and 308,000 by African-American peo-
ple. In 2010, there were approximately 4.2 million owner-occupied homes headed by non-
Hispanic white people; 1.5 million by Hispanic people; 880,000 by Asian-American people;
and 311,000 by African-American people. U.S. C
ENSUS
B
UREAU
, G
ENERAL
H
OUSING
C
HARAC-
TERISTICS
, QT-H1 (2000 and 2010 Census Summary Files).
302
Wei Li, Anatomy of a New Ethnic Settlement: The Chinese Ethnoburb in Los Angeles,
35 U
RBAN
S
TUDIES
479, 479 (1998) (“Ethnoburbs are suburban ethnic clusters of residential
areas and business districts in large American metropolitan areas.”).
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 54 19-OCT-18 12:58
672 Harvard Civil Rights-Civil Liberties Law Review [Vol. 53
1978.
303
Residents of these ethnic enclaves must therefore pay proportion-
ately higher taxes than residents of more long-standing but otherwise similar
suburban communities.
In addition to the claims of current homeowners, a prospective buyer
could allege that she would purchase a home, if not for the disproportion-
ately high property tax burden.
304
To establish the disproportionate nature of
the exclusion, she could compare the racial composition of the pool of po-
tential buyers who could afford a lower overall cost (including a fairer prop-
erty tax bill) with the racial demographics of potential buyers who could
afford the homes amid the heightened newcomers’ property taxes. To the
extent that she would be unable to move into a community that was largely
occupied by people of a different race or ethnicity, her plight could also
present a claim that Article XIIIA perpetuates segregated housing patterns
a “segregative effect” claim.
Where housing patterns reflect prior historical segregation, Article
XIIIA could be understood to have a segregative effect by maintaining or
amplifying currently segregated patterns.
305
Under this theory, a plaintiff
would seek to prove that Article XIIIA disincentivizes property owners from
moving and therefore calcifies existing, segregated housing patterns
par-
ticularly in communities that are predominantly composed of owner-occu-
pied housing.
306
Empirical studies have documented the fall of mobility after
the passage of Proposition 13 and suggested a causal relationship between
the two.
307
These studies corroborate the economic intuition that households
303
See, e.g., T
IMOTHY
F
ONG
,T
HE
F
IRST
S
UBURBAN
C
HINATOWN
174 (1994) (noting the
stark rise of property values in Monterey Park, CA, an early “ethnoburb” in the late 1970s and
early 1980s); W
EI
L
I
, E
THNOBURB
: T
HE
N
EW
E
THNIC
C
OMMUNITY IN
U
RBAN
A
MERICA
(2009)
(discussing how the migration of affluent immigrants has reshaped suburban America and
discussing Fremont and Cupertino, CA in particular).
304
For further insight on how a plaintiff might attempt to make such a case, see the discus-
sion of zoning changes that make homeownership more expensive in Robert G. Schwemm &
Calvin Bradford, Proving Disparate Impact in Fair Housing Cases after Inclusive Communi-
ties, 19 N.Y.U. J. L
EGIS
. & P
UB
. P
OL
Y
685, 75660 (2016).
305
A leading commentator has called into question the viability of segregative effect
claims, as they were not mentioned in Inclusive Communities. See Robert G. Schwemm, Fair
Housing Litigation After Inclusive Communities, 115 C
OLUM
. L. R
EV
. S
IDEBAR
106, 122
(2015).
306
See C
AL
. L
EG
. A
NALYST
S
O
FFICE
, C
OMMON
C
LAIMS
A
BOUT
P
ROPOSITION
13, 1112
(2016), http://www.lao.ca.gov/reports/2016/3497/common-claims-prop13-091916.pdf [https://
permacc/U7TW-HMBD] (describing the post-Proposition 13 ossification of the housing mar-
ket, with property turnover falling from 16% in 1977 to 5% in 2012). In light of other contrib-
utors such as an aging population and rising real estate prices, one finding that has been used
to validate Proposition 13’s role in this trend is the fact that “homeowners 55 and over appear
to be more likely to move in response to state laws allowing them to transfer their tax relief to
a new home.” Id.
307
See, e.g., Fernando Ferreira, You can take it with you: Proposition 13 tax benefits,
residential mobility, and willingness to pay for housing amenities, 94 J. P
UB
. E
CON
. 661, 662
(2010) (estimating the lock-in effect using a regression discontinuity design comparing house-
holders who are 55 with those who are 54 using finding that 55-year olds have a 1.21.5
percentage point higher rate of moving on top of a base rate of approximately 4%); Nada Wasi
& Michelle White, Property tax limitations and mobility: the lock-in effect of California’s
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 55 19-OCT-18 12:58
2018] Exclusionary Taxation 673
respond to the incentive to stay by, in fact, staying.
308
Segregative effect
claims may accordingly be dependent on the housing patterns of a particular
geography. Current homeowners could also bring a segregative effect claim
under a line of Supreme Court cases recognizing that individuals who are
deprived of an integrated community
for example white tenants whose
landlord discriminates against African Americans
suffer sufficient cogni-
zable injury to bring an FHA claim.
309
Injunctive relief would likely be nec-
essary to remedy either of these segregative effects
a one-time
compensation would not be likely to disrupt tax-related segregation.
Even apart from the treatment of initial owners themselves, a court
would likely find the preferential treatment of transfers to children and
grandchildren to raise the strong specter of discriminatory effect.
310
In Inclu-
sive Communities, the Supreme Court identified a municipal ordinance “re-
stricting the rental of housing units to only ‘blood relatives’ in an area of the
city that was 88.3% white and 7.6% black” as lying within the “heartland of
disparate-impact liability”
311
Thus, the Supreme Court has made clear how
hereditary housing privilege contravenes the FHA’s vision of pluralism.
The appropriate geographic scope of these claims would vary depend-
ing on the nature of the claim. A segregative effects claim requires analysis
of specific housing patterns and a counterfactual analysis of prospective
housing patterns without the higher cost and entrenchment caused by Article
XIIIA. These patterns would be more straightforwardly examined at a local
level, establishing the effect of Article XIIIA as implemented by a particular
county or set of counties.
312
The success of such a segregative effect lawsuit
would interfere with the intrastate uniformity of Article XIIIA’s application,
Proposition 13, B
ROOKINGS
-W
HARTON
P
APERS ON
U
RBAN
A
FFAIRS
59, 60 (2005) (finding that
Proposition 13 lengthened the tenure of owners in particular properties, with stronger effects as
the effective subsidy provided by Proposition 13 was greater). But see Joseph Nagy, Did Pro-
position 13 Affect the Moblity of California Homeowners?, 25 P
UBLIC
F
INANCE
R
EVIEW
102,
103 (1997) (finding declines in mobility in seven California metropolitan statistical areas
(MSAs) as well as in seven non-California MSAs, suggesting that the decline in mobility may
have been following a national trend).
308
Comment by Fernando Vendramel Ferreira on Nada Wasi & Michelle White, Property
tax limitations and mobility: the lock-in effect of California’s Proposition 13, B
ROOKINGS
-
W
HARTON
P
APERS ON
U
RBAN
A
FFAIRS
59, 92 (2005) (“The lock-in effect of California’s Pro-
position 13 is very intuitive: households respond to those property tax incentives by staying
longer in the same house. As a result, average tenure for households in California has in-
creased since 1978.”).
309
See Havens Realty Corp v. Coleman, 455 U.S. 363, 37678 (1982); Gladstone, Real-
tors v. Village of Bellwood, 441 U.S. 91, 109-11, 114-15 (1979); Trafficante v. Metro. Life
Ins. Co., 409 U.S. 205, 20812 (1972).
310
See supra note 56.
R
311
Inclusive Cmtys., 135 S. Ct. at 2522 (citing Greater New Orleans Fair Housing Action
Center v. St. Bernard Parish, 641 F. Supp. 2d 563, 569, 57778 (E.D. La. 2009)); see also U.S.
v. Town of Oyster Bay, 66 F. Supp. 3d 285, 29192 (E.D.N.Y. 2014) (holding that allegations
that a town had given a priority in its affordable housing program to children of the town’s
residents to “keep our children here, keep the generations flowing in the Town” were suffi-
cient to state a claim of intentional discrimination under the FHA).
312
Even though California’s constitution binds county tax assessment, counties are the
assessing jurisdiction in California. C
AL
. G
OV
T
C
ODE
§ 51501 (West 2018).
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 56 19-OCT-18 12:58
674 Harvard Civil Rights-Civil Liberties Law Review [Vol. 53
but such interference appears to be contemplated by the FHA’s express pre-
emption clause.
313
A plaintiff could establish a disproportionate effect the-
ory, on the other hand, on a statewide basis, by aggregating higher taxes paid
by minority newcomers across the state.
2. “Preservation, Continuity, and Stability”: Legitimate?
Nondiscriminatory?
In rejecting petitioners’ constitutional challenge to California’s Article
XIIIA, the Nordlinger majority identified two rationales “that justify deny-
ing petitioner the benefits of her neighbors’ lower assessments.”
314
The Court
noted first that the State has a legitimate interest in “local neighborhood
preservation, continuity, and stability,” and second, that “the State legiti-
mately can conclude that a new owner at the time of acquiring his property
does not have the same reliance interest warranting protection against higher
taxes as does an existing owner.”
315
Given judicial and intuitive recognition
of these values, they may likely be invoked by defendants in a FHA case.
“[P]reservation, continuity, and stability” reflect not only the most sa-
lient justifications for Article XIIIA but also ongoing themes in land use and
property scholarship.
316
In fact, preservation of community character was
presented as justifications for exclusionary zoning in the 1969 Stanford Law
Review Article that popularized the term.
317
As Anika Singh Lemar has de-
scribed in the context of aesthetic rulemaking, we have “embraced cultural
stability and the preservation of buildings and places that are icons in the
community mind . . . [reflecting] an assumption that a person’s neighbors
have a legitimate interest in ‘preserving’ the neighborhood in the state in
which it existed on the day that they purchased their homes.”
318
Yet as Singh
Lemar aptly points out, “changing cultural norms, immigration, population
growth, increasing diversity, and other evolving factors will often require
society to reconsider whether stability is a worthy policy goal.”
319
313
See supra note 289, and accompanying text discussing intrastate uniformity concerns.
R
314
Nordlinger, 505 U.S. at 12.
315
Id.; see also Clayton P. Gillette, Courts, Covenants, and Communities, 61 U. C
HI
. L.
R
EV
. 1375, 1404 (1994) (describing the Supreme Court’s invocation of the “assumption that
neighborhood stability is a positive good that fosters useful relationships among individuals”
to uphold property tax schemes that discriminate in favor of longstanding residents).
316
Bd. of Supervisors of Cerro Gordo Cty. v. Miller, 170 N.W.2d 358, 361 (Iowa 1969)
(explaining that “[p]reservation of the character of the neighborhood is a valid reason for
zoning regulations” and that such regulations “promote the general welfare and are valid
where they stabilize the value of property, promote the permanency of desirable home sur-
roundings and add to the happiness and comfort of citizens.”).
317
Sager, supra note 245, at 796.
R
318
Anika Singh Lemar, Zoning As Taxidermy: Neighborhood Conservation Districts and
the Regulation of Aesthetics, 90 I
ND
. L.J. 1525, 153031 (2015).
319
Id. at 1541.
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 57 19-OCT-18 12:58
2018] Exclusionary Taxation 675
The exclusion of newcomers resonates with California’s fraught history
of property-based racial exclusion, including its alien land laws.
320
Through
the 1940s, California limited the property rights of non-citizens, and even
attempted to extend these limitations to the citizen children of Japanese-
American immigrants.
321
Notably, although Congress included protections
for non-citizens in the Reconstruction era Civil Rights Acts, with an eye
toward the treatment of Chinese immigrants in California, non-citizens were
notably left out of the property-related protections that would later be codi-
fied at 42 U.S.C. § 1982.
322
Though Western frontier states initially used
alien land rights to attract residents in the late nineteenth century,
323
prop-
erty-based exclusion persisted in periods of relatively open European immi-
gration in the twentieth century.
324
Perceptions of “discrete culture gardens,
separated by different habits and values” motivated an early twentieth cen-
tury California Congressman to argue for the law that barred immigration
from India and Japan, restrictions that persisted until the Immigration and
Nationality Act of 1965.
325
His exclusionary discourse ascribed “to [ra-
cially] different peoples different capacities for movement [and] different
attachments to place.”
326
320
See Rose Cuison Villazor, Rediscovering Oyama v. California: At the Intersection of
Property, Race, and Citizenship, 87 W
ASH
. U. L. R
EV
. 979, 979-80 (2010) (discussing how
California’s Alien Land Law restricting property rights among Japanese Americans was ruled
unconstitutional and how the ruling informs more contemporary local efforts to restrict prop-
erty rights for undocumented immigrants); Gabriel J. Chin & John Ormonde, The War Against
Chinese Restaurants, 67 D
UKE
L. J. 101, 15657 (2018) (“It is not particularly surprising that
Arizona, California, Montana, Oregon, and Utah targeted Chinese restaurants, as those states
had pervasive anti-Asian policies reflected by a range of anti-Asian statutes that prohibited
Asians from intermarrying with whites and owning land. But eastern and midwestern states
like Illinois, Massachusetts, Minnesota, New York, Ohio, and Pennsylvania had no antimis-
cegenation or property laws targeting Asians or any other races, and those states or cities
within them carried on heretofore unexplored legal attacks on Chinese economic activity. Ra-
cial discrimination imposed by law was not restricted to the South, and racial discrimination
with respect to Asians was not limited to the Pacific Coast or western states.”); see also Kris-
tin A. Collins, Illegitimate Borders: Jus Sanguinis Citizenship and the Legal Construction of
Family, Race, and Nation, 123 Y
ALE
L.J. 2134, 214046 (2014) (describing a 19th century
Maryland Court of Appeals case, Guyer v. Smith, that legitimized property expropriation on
the basis that the mother of the property’s inheritors was “partly of African blood or descent,”
in purported violation of Maryland’s then alien land laws).
321
Cuison Villazor, supra note 320, at 992.
R
322
Lucas Guttentag, The Forgotten Equality Norm in Immigration Preemption: Discrimi-
nation, Harassment, and the Civil Rights Act of 1870, 8 D
UKE
J. C
ONST
. L. & P
UB
. P
OL
Y
1,
1718 (2013).
323
Polly Price, Alien Land Restrictions in the American Common Law: Exploring the Rel-
ative Autonomy Paradigm, 43 A
M
. J. L
EGAL
H
IST
. 152, 169 (1999).
324
Id. at 184, 208 (discussing estimates of twentieth century immigration, particularly
from Europe); see also Ran Abramitzky, Leah Platt Boustan, & Katherine Eriksson, Europe’s
Tired, Poor, Huddled Masses: Self-Selection and Economic Outcomes in the Age of Mass
Migration, 102 A
M
. E
CON
. R
EV
. 1832, 1832 (2012) (describing the “mass migration” of 30
million European immigrants to the United States between 1850 and 1913 as “one of the
largest migration episodes in human history”).
325
Sherally Munshi, Race, Geography, and Mobility, 30 G
EO
. I
MMIGR
. L.J. 245, 211-12,
246, 281 (2016).
326
Id. at 248.
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 58 19-OCT-18 12:58
676 Harvard Civil Rights-Civil Liberties Law Review [Vol. 53
Proposition 13 need not have been motivated by the anti-Asian animus
of California’s historic discriminatory laws for courts to recognize the troub-
ling parallel between this history and a law that “welcomes the stranger”
with a higher tax burden
when that stranger is more likely to be Asian or
Latino.
327
Advocates for “stability” may not only entrench old collectivities
over new ones, but they may also presume that those nonnative peoples
value stability itself differentially.
Regardless of its historical origins, a goal of unqualified community
stability is inconsistent with the pluralist, and interventionist, vision of the
FHA.
328
The FHA envisioned a new stability
as the Supreme Court articu-
lated, there “can be no question about the importance to a community of
promoting stable, racially integrated housing.”
329
The path from stable, seg-
regated housing to stable, racially integrated housing would require transi-
tion. Courts must therefore pause before labeling the goal of community
stability “legitimate” and “nondiscriminatory” against the demands of the
FHA.
Of particular concern are the hereditary housing privileges, including
inheritable underassessments, that offend any legitimate conception of sta-
bility under the FHA. Inclusive Communities critiqued such policies as ex-
emplifying what the FHA meant to prohibit.
330
In particular, the “parent-
child tax exemption” that allows children to receive their parents’ homes
without an updated assessment for the purpose of property taxes preserves
the biological, and likely racial, hue of a community. An interest in in-
tergenerational community stability
maintaining the same “character” of
residents in a community
is thus suspect under the FHA. Although there
may be a legitimate interest in allowing certain cash-poor families to pre-
serve homeownership, such an interest can be better served by less discrimi-
natory means.
331
Nordlinger also suggested that individual homeowners have an interest
in a stable expectation of property tax. While the California Supreme Court
correctly noted that, formally, Article XIIIA benefits all by providing a more
stable and certain estimation of future property tax liability, the amount of
that benefit varies wildly, and such inequitable “benefits” are precisely what
lie in the FHA’s ambit.
332
Moreover, as Nordlinger’s critics have written:
327
See Nordlinger, 505 U.S. at 6 (describing Article XIIIA as a “welcome stranger” as-
sessment system).
328
The purpose of the Fair Housing Act was “to replace the ghettos ‘by truly integrated
and balanced living patterns.’ Trafficante, 409 U.S. at 211 (quoting 114 CONG. REC. 3421,
3422 (1968) (statement of Sen. Mondale)); see also Austin W. King, Note, Affirmatively Fur-
ther, 88 N.Y.U. L. R
EV
. 2182, 2184 (2013) (collecting further legislative history).
329
Gladstone, Realtors v. Village of Bellwood, 441 U.S. 91, 111 (1979) (quoting Linmark
Assocs., Inc. v. Willingboro Twp., 431 U.S. 85, 94 (1977)).
330
Inclusive Cmtys., 135 S. Ct. at 2522.
331
See infra Section IV.B.3.
332
Nordlinger v. Lynch, 275 Cal. Rptr. at 692, aff’d sub nom, 505 U.S. 1 (1992) (“The
change from a current value system to an acquisition system was intended to benefit all prop-
erty owners, past and future, resident and nonresident, by reducing inflationary pressures in
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 59 19-OCT-18 12:58
2018] Exclusionary Taxation 677
A taxpayer has no right to insist that the taxing scheme in effect on
his date of birth or on some other date is the only one that may
apply to him throughout his life. Tax laws change; sometimes the
changes are even retroactive. The mere fact of change in the law
by itself never entitles the taxpayer to object to the law.
333
Proposition 13 renders a preferential tax, based on one’s ability to have pur-
chased earlier, rather than a stable tax.
334
California’s patterns of property
ownership in the 1970s reflected racial wealth disparities, prior housing and
lending discrimination, and recent racialized immigration policy.
335
The sta-
ble expectation, or reliance interest, is only persuasive for owners who strug-
gle to afford tax increases. That is, the legitimate interest in stability should
be homeowner-specific and implicated only as an individual means-tested
safety net.
336
Article XIIIA does serve one truly non-discriminatory interest. Because
property taxation reflects the value of illiquid capital, property value in-
creases can strongly affect land-rich, cash-poor homeowners. Thus, caps can
serve as a form of “insurance” against liquidity constraints.
337
It is legitimate
and nondiscriminatory for a jurisdiction to enact some policy to further the
interest of protecting those homeowners, but as we discuss below, acquisi-
tion-value taxation and many of its tax-revolt cousins are not the least dis-
criminatory alternative to effect that goal.
3. Less Discriminatory Alternatives
Unlike the Nordlinger Court’s constitutional rational basis query, our
inquiry does not end with an assertion of a legitimate interest. Rather, the
FHA’s burden shifting framework provides, in some sense, more room for
the logic of Justice Stevens’s dissent. While he agreed that “neighborhood
preservation” was a legitimate state interest, Justice Stevens thought “that a
tax windfall for all persons who purchased property before 1978 . . .[was]
too blunt a tool to accomplish such a specialized goal.”
338
In disagreeing
assessments, by limiting tax rates, and by permitting the taxpayer to make a more careful and
accurate prediction of future tax liability.”).
333
John A. Miller, Rationalizing Injustice: The Supreme Court and the Property Tax, 22
H
OFSTRA
L. R
EV
. 79, 118 (1993).
334
We note that an assessment limitation could preserve stable expectations without tying
the assessment to transfers of ownership, as illustrated by the Nassau County system. See
supra Part IV.A.1. In particular, the Coleman litigation illustrates that such limitations may
nonetheless create different problematic racial effects as assessments stray further from the fair
market value of the underlying properties, potentially leading certain communities to pay more
than their fair share. Id.
335
See supra notes 300-303, 316-326 and accompanying text.
R
336
For example, see the discussion of Philadelphia’s LOOP program, infra note 347, and
R
accompanying text.
337
See Nathan B. Anderson, Property Tax Limitations: An Interpretive Review, 59 N
AT
L
T
AX
J. 685, 687 (2006).
338
Nordlinger, 505 U.S. at 36 (Stevens, J., dissenting).
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 60 19-OCT-18 12:58
678 Harvard Civil Rights-Civil Liberties Law Review [Vol. 53
with the Court’s majority, and writing that “the severe inequalities created
by Proposition 13 cannot be justified by such an interest,” he raised the
obvious question of what alternatives might arise.
339
This discussion of alter-
natives was academic in the context of the rational basis scrutiny employed
by the Nordlinger Court. Under the Fair Housing Act, however, analysis of
alternatives is required to prove an effects-based case,
340
if the defendant has
articulated a legitimate non-discriminatory interest justifying the policy that
causes an adverse impact or perpetuates segregation.
A less discriminatory alternative can be found in targeted property tax
relief.
341
In fact, California currently offers one form of such relief: property
tax postponement, which in other states is called deferral.
342
Property tax
postponement allows qualified taxpayers to stay in their homes and delay
property tax payment until the realization of their rising property value
through a sale or probate.
343
Deferral might require the taxing authority to
wait until the owner passes away and the estate is settled, with the back taxes
secured by a lien on the property.
344
Tax deferral admittedly presents chal-
lenges for the heirs of the owner, as the back taxes become due if the home-
owner dies (with an exception for surviving spouses). A tax deferral system
thus allows low-income senior citizens to stay in their homes without creat-
ing a heritable entitlement.
Alternatively, property tax and assessment freezes can be tied to some
combination of age, disability, and veteran status, as well as asset and in-
come thresholds.
345
Some jurisdictions use means-tested limits on property
taxes, rather than a freeze; these programs are often described as tax “circuit
339
Id. at 38 (Stevens, J., dissenting).
340
We use “effects-based” here to incorporate both discriminatory and segregative ef-
fects, and to distinguish between an intent-based disparate treatment case.
341
Hui Shan, Property taxes and elderly mobility, 67 J. U
RBAN
E
CON
. 194, 198 (2010)
(“Deferralprograms are considered by academics the most targeted and cost-effective way of
providing property tax relief.”).
342
C
AL
. R
EV
. & T
AX
C
ODE
§§ 2050120646 (establishing property tax assistance and
postponement programs for low-income senior citizen and disabled homeowners). At the local
level, senior citizens may also be exempt from non-ad valorem parcel taxes. See generally
C
ALIFORNIA
T
AX
F
OUNDATION
, C
ENTER FOR
S
PECIAL
T
AXES
(2017), http://www.caltaxfounda-
tion.org/special-taxes/ [https://permacc/YZ3T-YC6W]. If one uses the “search by county”
function, the website shows whether a local jurisdiction provides age-based exemptions.
343
See C
ALIFORNIA
S
TATE
C
ONTROLLER
,P
ROPERTY
T
AX
P
OSTPONEMENT
F
ACT
S
HEET
,
http://www.sco.ca.gov/ardtax_fact_sheet.html [https://permacc/JQ3F-9ZMV]. We note that
currently, California homeowners who are seniors, are blind, or have a disability need to meet
certain criteria, including 40 percent equity in the home and an annual household income of
$35,500 or less, to avail themselves of the State Controller’s Property Tax Postponement Pro-
gram. Id. While the parameters of such a policy may need to be recalibrated, the very existence
of restrictive parameters can render these policies less discriminatory for the purposes of the
FHA analysis. Cf. Shanske, Revitalizing Local Political Economy, supra note 1, at 146 (ex-
R
plaining how a modern property tax “should be embedded in the income tax to make sure that
the property tax never consumes more than a reasonable percentage of a taxpayer’s income”
and should take advantage of the information, and liquidity, provided by realization events).
344
Andrew T. Hayashi, Property Taxes and Their Limits: Evidence from New York City,
25 S
TAN
. L. & P
OL
Y
R
EV
. 33, 51 (2014).
345
Shanske, Revitalizing Local Political Economy, supra note 1, at 14647.
R
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 61 19-OCT-18 12:58
2018] Exclusionary Taxation 679
breakers.”
346
Consider, for example, Philadelphia’s Longtime Owner Occu-
pant’s Program (LOOP), commonly referred to as the city’s “gentrification
protection” program.
347
The program provides tax relief for homeowners
who (i) have lived in their homes for at least 10 years, (ii) have income
below a limit for a household of their size (about $120,000 for a family of
4), and (iii) have experienced a reassessment that tripled the property’s “cer-
tified market value” from one tax year to the next.
348
Some might argue that a fair housing challenge to Article XIIIA would
harm homeowners in gentrifying communities. As a predicate matter, pro-
tecting homeowners in gentrifying neighborhoods is distinct from protecting
residents in gentrifying neighborhoods. Some residents are renters rather
than homeowners. Moreover, although a disparate impact claim by prospec-
tive homeowners in a gentrifying neighborhood would be theoretically plau-
sible, the threat is limited as an empirical matter. Isaac William Martin and
Kevin Beck combine longitudinal data on individual residence with data on
state property tax assessment and levy limitations to test how such property
tax policies might preclude the displacement traditionally associated with
gentrification. They find little evidence that these policies mediate the rela-
tionship between gentrification and homeowner displacement.
349
Even if a court was to recognize a interest in family-related stability,
there are certainly less discriminatory alternatives than inheritable assess-
346
See N
AT
L
C
ONF
.
OF
S
TATE
L
EGISLATURES
, S
TATE
P
ROPERTY
T
AX
F
REEZE AND
A
SSESS-
MENT
F
REEZE
P
ROGRAMS
(2012), http://www.ncsl.org/research/fiscal-policy/state-property-tax-
freezes-and-assessment-freezes.aspx [https://permacc/7CTU-2SVB] (summarizing key fea-
tures across 14 states). Often, under state law, localities may opt into such programs but are
not required to do so, and the eligibility thresholds may differ across localities. Id.
347
See Katie Colaneri, Philadelphia City Council votes to extend ‘gentrification protec-
tion’ program, WHYY (Mar. 17, 2016), https://whyy.org/articles/philadelphia-city-council-
votes-to-extend-gentrification-protection-program/ [https://permacc/CV5F-6NCZ].
348
C
ITY OF
P
HILADELPHIA
, L
ONGTIME
O
WNER
O
CCUPANTS
P
ROGRAM
, https://beta.phila
.gov/services/payments-assistance-taxes/income-based-assistance-programs/longtime-owner-
occupants-program/ [https://permacc/G33H-RFSF]. The City Council voted to extend the
original program in 2016. See Philadelphia City Council, Bill 160012, https://phila.legistar
.com/LegislationDetail.aspx?ID=2554763&GUID=F1CB6188-9714-41FD-82A5-A6AAFB7
1B289 [https://permacc/E73Y-YF39].
349
Isaac William Martin & Kevin Beck, Gentrification, Property Tax Limitation, and Dis-
placement, 54 U
RBAN
A
FFAIRS
R
EVIEW
33, 50 (2016) (“We find no evidence for[ ] the hy-
pothesis that property tax assessment limitation moderates the effect of gentrification on the
probability that long-term homeowners will move out. We also find no evidence that property
tax levy limitations reduce the probability that a homeowner in a gentrifying neighborhood will
move out.”). Moreover, we would caution that the empirical realities of gentrification differ
significantly from many common impressions of the trend. See, e.g., Jackelyn Hwang, Pio-
neers of Gentrification: Transformation in Global Neighborhoods in Urban America in the
Late Twentieth Century, 53 D
EMOGRAPHY
189, 189 (2016) (summarizing that, across 23 cit-
ies,“[a]n early presence of Asians was positively associated with gentrification,” “an early
presence of Hispanics was positively associated with gentrification in neighborhoods with sub-
stantial shares of blacks and negatively associated with gentrification in cities with high His-
panic growth, where ethnic enclaves were more likely to form”, and “[l]ow-income,
predominantly black neighborhoods and neighborhoods that became Asian and Hispanic desti-
nations remained ungentrified despite the growth of gentrification during the late twentieth
century.”) (emphasis added).
\\jciprod01\productn\H\HLC\53-2\HLC201.txt unknown Seq: 62 19-OCT-18 12:58
680 Harvard Civil Rights-Civil Liberties Law Review [Vol. 53
ments without qualification under Article XIIIA. In California, a child who
has never lived in the state, much less on the underassessed property, may
nonetheless avail herself of a chronic underassessment. By contrast, targeted
rent stabilization policies require a potential successor to have a minimum
period of cohabitation with the original tenant.
350
In sum, the FHA offers a new means to counter the effects of Article
XIIIA and its successors. The FHA prohibits government policies that have a
disproportionate effect on particular racial or ethnic groups or have the effect
of perpetuating segregation, unless the policy is justified by a legitimate
nondiscriminatory interest and there is no less discriminatory means to reach
that goal. In the context of California, we have provided preliminary evi-
dence that Article XIIIA has both disproportionate and segregative effects.
We have also shown that traditional community interests in stability are un-
likely, on their own, to survive the scrutiny demanded by the FHA, while
identifying potential less discriminatory alternatives. The analysis above is
specific to California’s tax regime and the demographic changes that have
occurred in the decades since Proposition 13. However, the broader nation’s
changing demography and historical exclusion of African-Americans, Lati-
nos, and Asian-Americans from homeownership suggests that there are other
places where acquisition-value property tax systems or similar tax-revolt ef-
forts would produce disparate impacts.
351
To avoid liability under federal fair
housing law, localities must recognize the unintended inequities and dispa-
rate impacts created by such broad-based tax policies and use finer instru-
ments to address the legitimate issues of residential stability that arise under
increasing tax burdens.
C
ONCLUSION
The goal of fair housing requires fair property taxes, despite longstand-
ing scholarly and judicial neglect of this relationship. By illuminating the
potential for Fair Housing Act claims against a range of property tax poli-
cies, we hope to have unearthed the procedural complexities inhibiting such
claims and the vision of equality that the federal civil rights statutes re-
present. The mathematical formulae of property tax assessment raise deep
questions about the meanings of change and fairness in an America that
increasingly diverse individuals aspire to call “home.”
350
See, e.g., N.Y.C. R
ENT
G
UIDELINES
B
OARD
,S
UCCESSION
R
IGHTS
(2016), http://www
.nycrgb.org/html/resources/faq/succession.html#rules [https://permacc/7B9U-QC4H].
351
See, e.g., supra notes 320326, and accompanying text (describing the history of alien
R
land laws); R
ICHARD
R
OTHSTEIN
, T
HE
C
OLOR OF
L
AW
6367 (2017) (describing federal agen-
cies’ redlining practices starting in the 1930s and their limiting effects of homeownership by
racial minorities); P
EW
R
ESEARCH
C
ENTER
, 10 D
EMOGRAPHIC
T
RENDS THAT ARE
S
HAPING THE
U.S.
AND THE
W
ORLD
(2016), http://www.pewresearch.org/fact-tank/2016/03/31/10-demo-
graphic-trends-that-are-shaping-the-u-s-and-the-world/ [https://permacc/7VKL-3F9M] (docu-
menting changes in the American population along axes of race, religion, national origin, and
sex).