FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF DALLAS
AN ECONOMIC INTERPRETATION
OF SUICIDE CYCLES IN JAPAN
Jahyeong Koo
and
W. Michael Cox
Research Department
Working Paper 0603
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF DALLAS
An Economic Interpretation of Suicide Cycles in Japan
Jahyeong Koo and W. Michael Cox
*
September 15, 2006
Abstract: Suicide rates in Japan have increased dramatically in recent years, making.
Japan’s male rate the highest among developed economies. This study revises the
standard economic model of suicide to accommodate Japan’s experience, focusing on the
change in human capital for the unemployed. We then use the new model and de-trended
data to empirically investigate the relationship between the suicide cycle and the
unemployment cycle. Unlike previous aggregate time series studies, we find that the
relationship between the suicide rate and the unemployment rate is significantly and
robustly positive for both males and females even after controlling for several social
variables.
Keywords: suicide, cycles, unemployment, Japan
JEL classification: I12; J60; E30
*
We thank Genevieve Solomon for excellent research assistant. We also thank two
anonymous referees and seminar participants at the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas for
comments on an earlier draft that led to significant improvements in the paper. The views
in this paper are those of the authors and not necessarily the views of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Dallas or the Federal Reserve System.
Koo: Economist, Research Department, Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas, 2200 N.
Pearl St. Dallas, TX 75201. Phone 1-214-922-5179, Fax 1-214-922-5194, E-mail address
Cox: Senior Vice President and Chief Economist, Research Department, Federal
Reserve Bank of Dallas, 2200 N. Pearl St. Dallas, TX 75201. Phone 1-214-922-5150, Fax
1-214-922-5194, E-mail address [email protected]
2
An Economic Interpretation of Suicide Cycles in Japan
I. Introduction
Since the early 1990s, Japan has experienced a tremendous increase in its suicide
rate, especially among middle-aged males. At the same time, most other industrialized
countries have seen suicide rates fall or increase only mildly [Figure 1]. Although Japan
has a culture that is more accepting of suicide than societies with Christian roots, the
recent surge in the suicide rate has drawn the attention of policy makers and economists.
The rate is unprecedented, and the suicide epidemic is probably related to the economic
recession that the world’s second biggest economy has suffered [Figure 2].
The male suicide rate in Japan in 2003 was 37.5 deaths per 100,000 persons—
more than twice the U.S. rate of 17.8 deaths per 100,000 in 2002. Japan currently has the
highest suicide rate among developed nations. The male rate is only lower than the
suicide rates of the former Soviet Union and East European countries, which have
endured a long and difficult economic transition, and Sri Lanka, which has suffered a
long civil war. Japan’s male suicide rate almost doubled from 1990 to 2003, a time when
the country was in an economic recession. Japanese unemployment rates increased from
2.1 percent in 1990 to 5.3 percent in 2004. An unemployment rate of 5.3 percent may
look quite healthy from European and U.S. perspectives, but it represents significant
hardship in a country where the average unemployment rate for the last five decades has
been 2.3 percent.
In standard economic models, suicide is considered a decision that a rational,
optimizing agent makes when his expected remaining lifetime utility falls below a certain
2
threshold.
1
Suicide rates, therefore, should be higher when perceived lifetime incomes
decrease. Models that follow the rational choice approach predict that the old age cohorts
will have higher suicide rates, all other things being equal, as the costs of maintaining
health increase with age.
2
Empirical research, however, does not always support the theory. Most of the
work on suicide uses the unemployment rate as a measure of economic hardship and
lifetime earnings because measuring an agent’s perceived lifetime income is not easy in
practice. Empirical tests involving panel data show a strong correlation between
unemployment and suicide (see Platt, 1984; Ruhm, 2000; Gerdtham and Johannesson,
2003), but studies with aggregated time-series data produce mixed results on at least two
key points. First, the relationship between unemployment and suicide tends to be less
sensitive in empirical models that incorporate more social variables, such as age, religion
and divorce rates (Yang 1992, 1994). Second, aggregate time-series research often finds
gender differences in responding to economic hardship. Vigderhous and Fishman (1978),
Yang (1992), Brainerd (2001) and others report that female suicide does not respond at
all (or at best shows little sensitivity) to unemployment compared with male suicide in
the countries they examined.
A monotonically increasing relationship between age and suicide has been
documented since Durkheim (1897) for many countries. However, the relationships have
disappeared as youth suicide rates have surged and overall suicide rates have declined in
1
Hamermesh and Soss (1974) formulate an economic model of suicide that treats individuals as rational,
optimizing agents. Marcotte (2003) extended the Hamermesh and Soss framework to analyze nonfatal
suicide attempts. Cutler, Glaeser and Norberg (2000) and Mathur and Freeman (2002) examine theories of
youth suicide.
2
In the Hamermesh and Soss (1974) setup, the age-specific rates depend upon the distribution of distastes
for suicide and the distribution of permanent incomes.
3
developed countries, including the U.S. and U.K. In the U.S., the suicide rates of young
adults (ages 20-24) are equal to those for prime-age adults (Cutler et. al. 2000). In former
Soviet Union countries, the suicide rates of prime-age adults rose dramatically in the
1990s. This distribution of suicide rates by age follows an observed recent pattern of the
labor markets in former Soviet countries (Brainard 2001).
Revising the Hamermesh and Soss (1984) setup and using filtered time series data,
this article assesses how well an economic model can explain suicide cycles in Japan. An
individual’s economic and social conditions likely play an important role in suicidal
behavior, although we acknowledge the influence of many non-economic and non-
socioeconomic factors on the decision, such as physical and psychiatric illness.
In our revised model, we explain the cases where suicide is not a monotonically
increasing function of age. In Japan, the suicide rate of middle-aged males has surged
more than any other group. The model is also refined to incorporate the relationship
between the suicide rate and the divorce rate, the most frequently examined social
variable. We add the fertility rate, the female labor market participation rate, and alcohol
consumption to control for the role of social variables in estimating the relationship
between economic factors and suicide rate cycles in Japan.
II. Suicide in Japan: An overview
According to the standard model, suicide rates are positively correlated with
income and age. In Japan, however, this simple framework has not served well to explain
the rise in the country’s suicide rates. Suicide trends by sex and age have not followed the
standard theory’s predictions.
4
In Japan, as in most other countries, the female suicide rate is lower than the male
rate during the period we examine (1950 -2003). However, the male suicide rate shows a
distinctive upward trend, whereas the female rate has been declining (Figure 2). The
female suicide rate is not positively correlated with the unemployment rate. We suspect
that improving social conditions for women have led to the downward sloping trend of
the female suicide rate, thus any regression analysis which does not control for the trend
of woman’s status might end up with a negative or insignificant relationship between
female suicide and unemployment
3
. Furthermore, running a regression that invloves non-
stationary variables with trends can result in a complicated econometric problem of
spurious regression.
If we focus on the cyclical components of the time series, even a casual look
reveals a positive correlation between the unemployment rate and both the male and
female suicide rates. During our sample period, Japan experienced three peaks of suicide
rates which correspond to aggregate economic conditions. The first peak was during the
mid-1950s, the second was after the second oil crisis and the third was the result of the
economic recession of the 1990s. The cyclical components of the suicide rate in Japan
were high when the unemployment rate cycles were high.
As the standard model predicts, female suicide rates in Japan increase with age.
The patterns do not change when we compare the statistics of 1988, 1993, 1998, and
2003 (Figure 3). Male suicide rates show a significant hump shape for the middle-aged
group between age 45 and 60 during the years 1998 and 2003. This pattern is not found in
3
Durkheim (1897) described women’s suicide in the 19
th
century as a byproduct of ‘excessive regulation’
that manifests itself in the form of women’s their subordinate social status. In China today, the female
suicide rate in the rural area is three times that in the cities. The relatively lower social status of women in
rural area is considered to be a major cause of higher rural female suicide rates (Lee and Kleinman 2000)
.
5
other developed economies and is not clearly predicted by standard suicide models. We
conjecture that changes in the labor market in Japan, including the devaluation of human
capital to older unemployed workers and small business owners, is related to the high
suicide rate of the middle age group.
III. An Economic model of suicide
To accommodate the patterns of Japanese suicide cycles and the distribution of
suicide among age groups, we refine the standard suicide model first laid out by
Hammermesh and Soss (1974) and assess how well our economic model explains the
patterns of Japanese suicide cycles and the distribution of suicide among age groups.
Our revised model follows the framework of the standard model by assuming that
individuals decide to commit suicide if the expected lifetime utility falls below a certain
threshold. The utility function for an individual in the standard model is defined as,
U
m
= U [C (m, Y) – K(m)] (1)
where m is the individual’s age, Y is income that could be devoted to consumption C, K
is the cost of maintaining health in each year (presumably K´ > 0). Then the discounted
present value of an individual’s lifetime utility at age α is:
Z(α , Y) =
e
ω
α
-r(m-α)
U
m
P(m) dm (2)
where r is the discount rate, ω is maximum life expectancy, P(m) is the probability of
living to age m at given age α. An individual chooses suicide when the discounted utility,
Z(α , Y), falls below some critical threshold. Since Z is a decreasing function of α (due to
the increasing cost of maintaining health with age) and an increasing function of Y, the
model predicts that suicide propensity rises with age and falls with income.
6
By modeling the valuation of the discounted benefits and costs of living, this
framework captures the essential element of an individual’s decision to commit suicide.
But with this formulation we cannot explain important aspects of the time series of
Japanese suicide.
First, despite the prolonged recession, per capita real GDP continued to grow in
Japan at an average rate of 1.1 percent a year during the 1990s, and labor’s share of
output peaked in the same period.
4
The observations are contradictory to the model,
because while male suicide rose, average income continued to rise and the income
distribution flattened during the 1990s.
Second, the simple model cannot account for the high suicide rate of middle-aged
males shown in Figure 3B. Lacking any explicit treatment of the link between
unemployment and lifetime income, the simple model fails to explain why the expected
utility of middle-aged males drops so precipitously in the face of worsening economic
conditions.
Third, some changes in social variables, such as the divorce rate, can be partly
explained by rising unemployment. By including social variables, we can test whether
their relationships to suicide are a simple reflection of the change of economic conditions.
To accommodate these aspects of suicidal behavior in Japan, we revise the standard
model. We also extend the setup to account for the indirect impact of unemployment on
suicide through the divorce rate, which is the most frequently mentioned social variable
in the literature.
4
According to Miyanaga (2002), labor’s share in Japan averaged 80.2 percent in 1990s—the highest
among any 10-year window from 1955 to 2000. Labor’s share during the whole sample period averages
76.8 percent.
7
In our revised model, relative income is measured as the distance to the social
mean income at time t. So the suicide rate is not a monotonically decreasing function of
the aggregate income level in time series analysis. It corresponds to the observation that
suicide rates have not necessarily been lower after the decades of rapid economic growth.
Relative income is an increasing function of human capital h, which is constant as long as
an individual is employed. It depreciates if he is unemployed, reflecting the fact that the
unemployed lose the opportunity to maintain human capital through on the job training.
During periods of economic transition driven by technological shocks or regime shifts,
the human capital of the unemployed depreciates faster. The diminished human capital
drives down the expected relative lifetime utility of unemployed individuals faster than
during a normal period.
The equation of discounted present value of an individual’s relative lifetime
utility at age α is;
RZ(α , RY(h)) =
ω
α
e
-r(m-α)
RU [RC(m, RY(h)) – RK(m)] P(m) dm (3)
where RY is relative income which is an increasing function of human capital. RU, RC
and RK are relative counterparts of U, C, and K in equation (1). Human capital declines
when an individual is unemployed. So h
m
= h
m-1
when employed and h
m
= ß h
m-1
when
unemployed ( 0 < ß < 1 ). ß is smaller when the economy is under rapid technological
transformation or regime shift.
The revised model provides the same basic insights into the suicide behavior as
the standard one. It assumes that individuals are more likely to commit suicide when
expected relative lifetime utility falls below a certain level. The suicide rate is related to
income and age. However, the revised model has a novel feature of clearly showing how
8
high unemployment rates lower the expected relative lifetime utility and increase suicide
rates, as seem by
+ + + +
Unemp
RZ
Δ
Δ
=
U
RZ
Δ
Δ
RC
U
Δ
Δ
RY
RC
Δ
Δ
h
RY
Δ
Δ
Unemp
h
Δ
Δ
< 0 . (4)
The unemployed come to have less human capital than individuals with jobs and
consequently have less relative lifetime utility. Hence, the propensity to commit suicide
will be positively related with the unemployment rate.
The model also can be used to show why the middle-aged group’s suicide rate has
been higher recently in Japan. During a period of economic transition, the technological
shocks quicken the depreciation of human capital for unemployed middle-aged
individuals, who tend to be slower than younger workers in adapting to new labor market
conditions. In a society like Japan, where labor markets are not flexible, the depreciation
of human capital is faster for those age groups that cannot easily find the same quality
jobs once they are unemployed.
5
However, ceteris paribus, the suicide rate increases with
age, just as it does in the standard model (2).
We further extend the model by including the divorce rate. Following Becker
(1974), we assume that marriage has mercenary value. A divorced individual has lower
relative utility and is more likely to commit suicide than a married one. According to the
literature, couples separate when the utility expected from remaining married falls below
5
The Japanese practice of lifetime employment is typically portrayed as providing job security to workers.
But because firms are not able to dismiss workers in response to a business downturn, companies are more
likely to have serious cost overruns and eventually go bankrupt, in which case it is very difficult for
workers to find another job at the same level. The paradoxical result is that workers may in fact wind up
with less security, not more as a result of the lifetime employment practice. It is worth noting that the
Japanese higher education system plays little role in retraining the jobless for alternative professions.
9
the utility expected from divorcing and possibly remarrying (Becker et. al. 1977). Weiss
and Willis (1997) show empirically that the expectation of earnings capacity formed at
the time of marriage does not influence divorce, but surprises concerning the partners’
earning capacity are important in explaining divorce. We consider the reduction of
human capital due to unemployment in Japan as a surprise in earning capacity that is
likely to end in divorce.
6
Then the enriched model becomes:
RZ(α , Y(h)) =
e
ω
α
-r(m-α)
RU [RC(m, RY(h)) – k(m) – Divorce(RY(h))] P(m) dm (5)
where
Divorce is a dummy variable that is positive and constant when human capital h is
below a certain level and zero otherwise. All other things are equal, divorced individuals
have smaller relative utility and are more likely to commit suicide than married
individuals. In the enriched model, unemployment influences relative utility through two
channels. One channel is through low relative consumption RC and the other channel is
through high probability of divorce.
+ + + +
Unemp
RZ
Δ
Δ
=
U
RZ
Δ
Δ
RC
U
Δ
Δ
RY
RC
Δ
Δ
h
RY
Δ
Δ
Unemp
h
Δ
Δ
+
+ +
U
RZ
Δ
Δ
Divorce
U
Δ
Δ
RY
Divorce
Δ
Δ
h
RY
Δ
Δ
Unemp
h
Δ
Δ
< 0 (6)
If the divorce channel in the second part of equation (6) dominates the relative
consumption channel in the first part, then the relationship between suicide and
6
We assume that high unemployment rates are positively correlated with divorce rates. Weiss and Willis
(1997) show that an unexpected increase in the husband’s earning capacity reduces the divorce hazard,
while an unexpected increase in the wife’s earning capacity raises the divorce hazard so that two effects
work in opposite directions. However, men traditionally have been the major bread earner in a typical
Japanese family and thus we expect the former effect to dominate. We take evidence of the positive
relationship between divorce and suicide rates from Durkheim (1897).
10
unemployment rates will be weaker in the regression analysis that includes divorce rates
as an explanatory variable than in the simple regression with only unemployment rates
7
.
IV. Empirical methodology and Data
A. Empirical methodology
One notable empirical contribution of the extended model is the redefining of
variables in terms of distance from the social mean or trend. It is standard practice
following Lucas (1977) to define the business cycle in terms of deviations from trend.
This convention is preferred by modern macroeconomists and is the one most frequently
employed in empirical macroeconomic studies. Recognizing the importance of de-
trending as well as the lack of consensus about the optimal technique, we operationalize
the cyclical components by employing three different filters.
First, we use a random-walk filter based on first differences of the relevant
variables. Second, we use the well-known Hodrick-Prescott (1997) filter with a
smoothing parameter of 100. Finally, we use a Band-pass filter to produce the
components that correspond to cycles of duration 2-8 years.
Since the filtered series tend to be stationary (Baxter and King 1999), we avoid
the complicated econometric problems that arise when variables with different levels of
integration are included in the same equation. It is worth noting that the trends are
defined operationally, i.e. the measurement procedure defines the concept (Prescott 2006).
In our analysis, we do not rigorously investigate the factors that influence the diverging
trends in Japan’s male and female suicide rates.
7
Using the data of twelve developed nations, Yang (1994) shows that the estimated coefficient on the
unemployment rate is likely to be less significant when the divorce rate is added to the regression. The
analysis however does not separate male and female suicides.
11
B. Econometric models
We concentrate on the de-trended suicide rates and unemployment rates to estimate
their relationship as derived from the model (4). The regressions we estimate take the
form:
Suicide
t
= α + β Unemployment
t
+ε
t.
(7)
Suicide
t
denotes de-trended suicides per 100,000 persons. For example, Suicide
t
= 2
means 2 suicides per 100,000 persons above the trend. Unemployment
t
denotes the de-
trended unemployment rate multiplied by 100. ε
t.
represents the myriad influences on
suicide beyond the influence of economic hardship.
The unemployment-to-suicide channel shown in (6) is tested with the following
regressions.
Suicide
t
= α + β Unemployment
t
+ γ Divorce
t
+ ε
t.
(8)
Divorce
t
denotes de-trended divorces per 1,000 persons, so that Divorce
t
= 2 means 2
divorces per 1,000 persons above the trend. By comparing the regression results of (7)
and (8), we can determine whether the relationship between the divorce and suicide rates
is the mere reflection of economic factors, or whether the divorce rate contains
information about social anxiety not explained by the economic factors.
We extend our econometric model by adding three social variables that are
frequently examined in the suicide literature—the fertility rate, the female labor market
participation rate (FLP), and alcohol consumption.
8
Since the presence of children entails
8
Catholicism strongly disapproves of suicide, viewing it as sin, and this factor is sometimes examined as a
social variable. In Japan, Catholic believers represent only 0.34 percent of the total population and the ratio
has not changed since 1990 (Catholic Bishop’s Conference of Japan, 2005). In view of its size and stability,
we exclude these influences from our analysis as we focus on the cyclical fluctuation in aggregate suicide.
12
family and social ties, it increases social integration and may reduce the likelihood of
suicide. Fertility is, therefore, expected to be negatively related to suicide. Using panel
data, Neumayer (2003) reports a significantly negative relationship between suicide rates
and fertility rates in the U.S. states and Andrés (2006) reaches a similar conclusion for 15
European countries. However, to our knowledge no empirical research examines the
relationship with time series data.
Increased FLP can be associated with higher male suicide rates. Perhaps men feel
challenged in their role as head of the household and are less likely to be comforted by
female partners who also work outside the home (Stack, 1998). This is problematic for
men because they are more likely than women to rely solely on their spouses as their
confidant (McGrath et al., 1990). On the other hand, the association of FLP and female
suicide is not clear. Increased female participation in the labor force may strengthen
social ties with other workers and may help to reduce the female suicide rate. But women
are exposed to the stress of work life, and often face a double burden of outside
employment and unpaid housework. The net effect of a change in female labor
participation on male suicide depends on which of these two effects dominates. The
empirical results are mixed for both cross-sectional and panel data (Chuang and Huang
1997, Neumayer 2003 and Andrés 2005). Heavy alcohol consumption is also reported to
increase suicide rates in cross-sectional analysis (Markowitz et. al 2003, Andrés 2005 and
Brainerd 2001).
The extended econometric model including sociological variables is
Suicide
t
= α + β Unemployment
t
+ γ Divorce
t
+ δ SV
t
+ ε
t.
(9)
The majority of Japanese claim to be a believer of Shinto or Buddhism or both. However, as Shinto and
Buddhism do not have distinctive teachings on suicide and there are no reliable statistics available, we do
not examine the influence of religion in our analysis.
13
SV
t
denotes a vector of de-trended sociological variables, the elements of which are
fertility rates, FLP and alcohol consumption. We measure the fertility rate with average
births from a mother in her reproduction years (ages 15 49). FLP is measured by
(female labor force / female population 15 years old and over) x 100. Alcohol
consumption is measured by the net alcohol consumption per adult (age 15 and over).
A comparison of the estimated results of (7), (8) and (9) help us see how well the
enriched explains the suicide cycles in Japan.
C. Data
For this study, we use annual data from 1950 to 2003. Table 1 presents the
descriptive statistics of the variables in levels. To control for the influence of the
changing distribution of age groups on suicide rates, the age-adjusted suicide rates based
on the population of 1986 are used. Japan’s Ministry of Health, Labor and Welfare is the
primary source for statistics on suicide, unemployment and divorce. For unemployment
rates from 1950 to 1952, we use the estimates of the Statistical Information Institute for
Consulting and Analysis (www.sinfonica.or.jp
). Fertility rates and FLP come from the
Statistics Bureau of Japan. Alcohol consumption for 1961-2001 comes from World
Health Organization alcohol database (www.who.int). For 1950-1960 and 2002-2003, we
calculated alcohol consumption based on data from National Tax Agency of Japan.
Figure 4 shows the time series of three social variables. The fertility rate is
highest in 1950 at 3.65 children per woman and it has declined since reaching its lowest
point of 1.29 in 2003. The fertility rate tends to decline partly because the opportunity
cost of raising children becomes higher with increased female education. The sharp
14
decline in Japan’s fertility in the 1950s reflects the bust following the post Second World
War baby boom.
In the US, FLP rates have increased with little variation around the trend, rising
from 32.5 percent in 1950 to 59.6 percent in 2003. By contrast, Japan’s FLP rates first
declined from 56.7 percent in 1955 to 45.8 percent in 1976, then increased to 50.7
percent in 1991 declining to 48.3 percent in 2003. The massive migration of farming
families to the cities and rapid economic growth after the Second World War resulted in
an increase of full-time housewives, and consequently lowered FLP in the first part of our
sample. The recession after 1991 lowered the rate, although it is generally considered to
be countercyclical.
Japan’s alcohol consumption per capita increased from 1.4 liters in 1950 to 6.9
liters in 1990, the peak of the bubble economy. Since then, it has fluctuated around the
1990 level. Alcohol seems to be a normal good—with demand increasing with income
before 1990 in Japan. During the 1990s, the fluctuation of alcohol consumption does not
show a noticeable correlation with the rising suicide rate.
Table 2 presents the correlations of the de-trended variables using the random
walk filter. We have to sacrifice the beginning and ending three periods when applying
the band pass filter owing to construction of the weighted moving average. The data are
relatively poorly estimated with the HP filter during the beginning and ending periods. To
have the same period for all of the filters, we report the results using the de-trended data
for the period 1953-2000 after eliminating the beginning and ending three years. The
correlation coefficients of the de-trended variables are not significantly influenced by the
de-trending method used.
15
The de-trended female suicide rate is positively correlated with the de-trended
unemployment rate (0.38) and divorce rate (0.17), even though the correlation
coefficients are smaller than those of the male suicide rate with the unemployment rate
(0.62) and divorce rate (0.52). The divorce rate is positively correlated with the
unemployment rate as our model predicts (0.46). Alcohol consumption does not have a
positive relationship with either male (-0.03) or female suicide rates (-0.02). The fertility
rate has a negative relationship with the male (-0.10) and female (-0.30) suicide rates as
sociology theories predict. FLP is slightly countercyclical (-0.06) and has a positive
relationship with the male (0.25) and female suicide rate (0.24).
V. Empirical Results
OLS estimates of equation (7) with the male suicide rate (the first four rows of
TABLE 3) indicate that the effect of the unemployment rate on the suicide rate is more
pronounced when we focus on the cyclical components of the two variables. Equations
with de-trended variables have larger coefficients for unemployment than equations with
level variables. The coefficient with the random-walk filter indicates that a 1 percentage
point increase in Japan’s unemployment rate will result in 57.6 more male suicides per
million people in Japan—an overall increase of 3,592. The estimate using the HP filter is
the largest. A 1 percentage point increase in the unemployment rate corresponds to 71.4
more male suicides per million people, an increase of 4,452.
Introducing de-trended variables causes sweeping changes in the estimates of the
female suicide rate. When the variables are not de-trended, the coefficient of
unemployment rate is negative and insignificant. With de-trended variables (the first four
16
rows TABLE 4), the coefficients of the unemployment rate are all positive and significant
at the 1 percent level. The female suicide rate in Japan, however, still responds less than
the male suicide rate to the unemployment rate.
9
Based on estimates with the random-
walk filter, a 1 percentage point increase in the unemployment rate will result in 14 more
female suicides per million people, a total of 902 for the nation.
Taking the average of the three estimates, forecasted total suicides will increase
by 4,774 with a 1 percentage point increase in the unemployment rate over the trend. The
country now has a population of 128 million.
Divorce rates are an important social variable that has more explanatory power
than unemployment rates in some research (Yang 1994). Our model assumes that
marriage has mercenary value and divorce leads to a lower relative income that might
precipitate suicidal behavior. Divorce in our model occurs when couples encounter
unexpected negative income shocks. If divorce were mainly driven by economic factors
and the reduction of utility from divorce were to dominate the reduction from low income
in deciding suicide, the inclusion of divorce should weaken the effect of unemployment
in estimates of (8) compared with (7). Instead, the addition of a filtered divorce rate does
not significantly alter the coefficient of Unemployment. The coefficient of
Unemployment for the male suicide rate declined about 20 percent compared with the
simple regression, but the estimates are still significant at the 1 percent level.
For the female suicide rate, the inclusion of Divorce does not alter the coefficient
of Unemployment. However, the impacts of Divorce on Suicide show distinctive gender
differences. The
Divorce coefficient is positive and significant for Male Suicide, but it is
9
Brainerd (2001) posits that women are more protected from macroeconomic instability in the societies
where women’s non-market work is valued more highly than men’s.
17
mixed and insignificant for Female suicide in the equations using the three different de-
trending methods. R
2
increases about 26 percent for the three filtered variables for the
male suicide rate, but R
2
does not change very much for the female suicide rate. These
findings parallel results for the former Soviet Union countries (Brainerd 2001) and for the
U.S. (Cutler et al, 2000). They also suggest that the mercenary value of marriage is larger
for males than females and factors other than economic hardship also matter
10
.
Including social variables does not alter the size and significance of the
coefficients of the unemployment and divorce rates for both male and female suicide. The
increases in R
2
are moderate on average 0.053 for males and 0.076 for females. Fertility
is negatively correlated with the suicide rate for both males and females. The coefficient
is significant at the 1 percent level for two out of three de-trending methods regarding the
female suicide rate, but it is significant at the 10 percent level for only one de-trending
method regarding the male rate. The hypothesis that the presence of children, with
promotion of family and social ties, reduces the suicide rate is weakly supported, and the
relationship is more distinct for females than males.
FLP has a positive coefficient for both the male and female suicide rates. The
relationship of
FLP with suicide also shows a gender differential. The coefficient is
significant for all de-trending methods regarding males, but only one for females. The
findings also support the hypothesis that loss of social support due to female participation
in the labor market leads to an increase in male suicide. For females, the double burden of
outside work and housework may be bigger than the benefit of having social ties in work,
but the relation is not robustly significant. Our results coincide with Stack (1987)—at the
10
The utility loss of the mercenary value of marriage via divorce is equivalent in sociological terms to
individual trauma and the lack of social control.
18
aggregate level, the overall FLP affects the male but not the female suicide rate in the
U.S. It is worth noting that even though the coefficient is significant, the impact of FLP
on the male suicide rate is smaller than the unemployment effect. A one standard
deviation increase in the Band-Pass filtered Unemployment variable will be associated
with an increase of 7,131 male suicides, whereas a one standard deviation increase in
FLP will be associated with an increase of only 678 male suicides.
The coefficients on Alcohol are positive but insignificant for males, and mixed
and insignificant for females. However, our results should not be interpreted as saying
that there is no relationship between alcohol abuse and suicidal behavior at the micro
level. The relationship between alcohol consumption and suicide may not be linear. A
recent study by Akechi et al. (2006) using Japanese cohort data shows that the
relationship is U-shaped. Those who do not drink at all commit suicide more than those
who drink occasionally. These results indicate that our time-series data, which aggregate
the cross-sectional distribution of individual alcohol consumption, may not have enough
information to determine the relationship between alcohol abuse and the suicidal
behavior of individuals.
In sum, our initial estimates of the coefficients of the unemployment rate and
divorce rate do not change significantly after controlling for social variables. We may
conclude from these results that the reduction of relative consumption is the major
channel by which relative utility falls and consequently leads individuals to commit
suicide.
11
The divorce cycle is partly correlated to a society’s unemployment cycle, even
11
We explored the effect of using real per capita GDP in the place of the unemployment rate. The
coefficients are robustly significant in all equations estimated, but less significant than those of the
unemployment rate. A simple comparison of correlation coefficients also shows that real per capita GDP is
less correlated with suicide than is unemployment.
19
though non-economic factors influence divorce rates. Our previous results derived from
a simple regression approach (7), thus seem to be reasonable estimates of the relationship
between the unemployment and suicide rates in Japan.
VI. Concluding Remarks
In this paper, we tried to extend the research on the economics of suicide in two
ways. First, we revised the standard economic model to analyze the cyclical relationship
between the suicide rate and the unemployment rate. Our model suggests that the recent
surge of middle-aged male suicides in Japan is related to the inflexible labor market that
leads the human capital of the unemployed to depreciate rapidly during periods of
technological shocks and regime shifts. The revised model clearly links the
unemployment and suicide rates and focuses on relative utility rather than the absolute
level. The relative terms conceptually correspond to cyclical components of the variables.
Second, we used three different filters to de-trend Japanese time series. By filtering out
long-term trends from the variables, we are able to illustrate the cyclical relationship
between suicide and unemployment more clearly.
12
Unlike previous research, which
often failed to trace the response of the female suicide rate to economic hardship, our
study indicates that the female suicide rate is also significantly influenced by the
unemployment rate in Japan, even though women are more protected than men from
macroeconomic fluctuations. The results are robust when we include the divorce rate and
three other social variables in the equation. The impacts of social variables show gender
differentials.
Fertility is more clearly related to female suicide, whereas the negative
12
When variables are stationary (as with some U.S. data), the filtered time series approach does not
generally improve estimation.
20
impact of FLP is more distinctive with male suicide. With our aggregate time series data,
we could not find any significant relationship between alcohol consumption and the
suicide rate in Japan.
We conjecture that 4,774 more Japanese will commit fatal suicide anually3 if de-
trended unemployment rises 1 percentage point. Such an acute response of people to
unemployment may be one reason why the Japanese government has been reluctant to
adopt drastic reform measures that could lead to a temporary surge of unemployment
rates during the sustained economic recession that began more than a decade ago.
The theories and empirical results in this paper suggest that government policy to
prevent the depreciation of human capital of the unemployed would help to remedy the
hazard of suicide. Retraining programs for jobless salarymen, tax breaks to encourage the
establishment of temporary agencies, and tax breaks to encourage corporations to hire
temporary workers are policies worth considering in this context.
21
References
Akechi, T., M. Iwasaki, Y. Uchitomi and S. Tsugane. “Alcohol Consumption and Suicide
among Middle-aged Men in Japan.”
British Journal of Psychiatry, 188, 2006, 231-236.
Andrés, A. R. “Income Inequality, Unemployment, and Suicide: A Panel Data Analysis
of 15 European Countries.”
Applied Economics, 37, 2005, 439-451.
Baxter, M., R. G. King. 1999, “Measuring Business Cycles: Approximate Band-Pass
Filters for Economic Time Series.” Review of Economics and Statistics, 81, 1999, 575-
593.
Becker, G. Human Capital: A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis with Special Reference
to Education
. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1964.
Becker, G. “A Theory of Marriage.” in
Economics of the Family, edited by T. W. Schultz.
Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1974.
Becker, G. “An Economic Analysis of Marital Instability.” Journal of Political Economy,
85, 1977, 1141-1188.
Brainerd, E. “Economic Reform and Mortality in the Former Soviet Union: A Study of
the Suicide Epidemic in the 1990s.” European Economic Review 45, 2001, 1007-1019.
Catholic Bishops’ Conference of Japan, Statistics of the Catholic Church in Japan 2005,
Japan, 2006.
Chatterji, P., D. Dave, R. Kaestner, and S. Markowitz. “Alcohol Abuse and Suicide
Attempts among Youth.” Economics and Human Biology, 2, 2004, 159-180.
Chuang, H. and W. Huang. “Economic and Social Correlates of Regional Suicide Rates:
A Pooled Cross-Section and Time-Series Analysis.”
Journal of Socio-Economics, 26,
277-289.
Durkheim, L. J. Le Suicide. 1897 [translated by Spaulding, J. A., Simpson G. 1951
Suicide. Free Press, New York]
Cutler, D. M., E. L. Glaeser, K. E. Norberg. “Explaining the Rise in Youth Suicide.”
NBER Working Paper 7713, 2000.
Gerdtham, U., M. Johannesson. “A Note on the Effect of Unemployment on Mortality.”
Journal of Health Economics, 22, 2003, 505-518.
Hamermesh, D. S., N. M. Soss. “An Economic Theory of Suicide.”
Journal of Political
Economy
, 82, 1974, 83-98.
22
Hodrick, R. J., E. C. Prescott. “Post-war U.S. business cycles: an empirical
investigation.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 29, 1997, 1-16.
Huang, W. “Region, Culture, Economic and Sociological Correlates of Suicide Rates: A
Cross-National Analysis.” Applied Economics Letters, 3, 1996, 779-782.
Lee, S. and A. Kleinman. “Suicide as Resistance in Chinese Society.” In: EJ Perry and M.
Selden. Eds. Chinese Society: Change, Conflict and Resistance. London Routledge, 2000,
221-240.
Lucas, R. E. “Understanding Business Cycles.” Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series
on Public Policy
, 5, 1977, 7-29.
Marcotte, D. E. “The Economics of Suicide, Revisited.”
Southern Economic Journal, 69,
628-643.
Markowitz, S., P. Chatterji, and R. Kaestner. “Estimating the Impact of Alcohol Policies
on Youth Suicides.”
Journal of Mental Health Policy and Economics, 6, 2003, 37-43.
Mathur, V. K., Freeman, and D. G. Freeman. “A Theoretical Model of Adolescent
Suicide and Some Evidence from US data.” Health Economics, 11, 695-708.
McGrath, E., G. P. Keita, B. Strictland, and N. F. Russo. Women and Depression,
Washington: American Psychological Association, 1990.
Miyanaga, W. “Labor’s Share and the Adjustment of Wages and Employment.” Research
Report no. 27 Development Bank of Japan, 2002.
Neumayer, E. “Socioeconomc Factors and Suicide Rates at large-unit Aggregate Levels:
A Comment.” Urban Studies, 40, 2769-2776.
Newey, W. K., and K. D. West. “A simple, positive semi-definite, heteroskedasticity and
autocorrelation consistent covariance matrix.” Econometrica, 55, 1987, 703-705.
Platt, S. “Unemployment and Suicidal Behavior: A review of the literature.”
Social
Science and Medicine
, 19, 1984, 93-115.
Prescott, E. “Nobel Lecture: The Transformation of Macroeconomic Policy and
Research.” Journal of Political Economy, 114, 2006, 203-235.
Ruhm, C. J. “Are Recessions Good for Your Health?” Quarterly Journal of Economics,
115, 2000, 617-650.
Stack, S. “The Effect of Female Participation in the Labor Force on Suicide: A Time
Series Analysis.”
Sociological Forum, 2, 1997, 257-277.
23
_______. “The Relationship of Female Labor Force Participation to Suicide: A
Comparative Analysis.” Archives of Suicide Research, 4, 1998, 249-261.
Vigderhous, G., G. Fishman. “The Impact of Unemployment and Familial Integration on
Changing Suicide Rates in the U.S.A., 1920-1969.” Social Psychiatry, 13, 1978, 239-248.
Weiss, Y., R. Willis. “Match Quality, New Information , and Marital Dissolution.”
Journal of Labor Economics, 15, 1997, s293-s329.
Yang, B. “The Economy and Suicide: A Time-Series Study of the U.S.A.” American
Journal of Economics and Sociology
, 51, 1992, 87-99.
_______. “The Social Impact of Unemployment.” Applied Economics Letters, 1, 1994,
223-226.
24
5
10
15
20
25
30
35
40
1980 1984 1988 1992 1996 2000
Suicides per 100,000 persons
FIGURE 1
Male Suicide Rates in Five Industrialized Countries
Source WHO Mortality database
Japan
Spain
U.K.
U.S.A.
Canada
10
15
20
25
30
35
40
1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
Suicides per 100,000 persons
Unemployment Rate (%)
FIGURE 2
Suicide rates, Unemployment rates and Divorce rates in Japan
Unemployment Rate
Male Suicide
Female Suicide
Divorce Rate
Divorces per 1,000 persons
25
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
10-14 15-19 20-24 25-29 30-34 35-39 40-44 45-49 50-54 55-59 60-64 65-69 70-74 75-79 80-84 85+
1988
1993
1998
2003
FIGURE 3A
Female Suicide by Age
Suicides per 100,000 females
0
20
40
60
80
100
120
10-14 15-19 20-24 25-29 30-34 35-39 40-44 45-49 50-54 55-59 60-64 65-69 70-74 75-79 80-84 85+
1988
1993
1998
2003
FIGURE 3B
Male Suicide by Age
Suicides per 100,000 males
26
Variable
Male
Suicide
Female
Suicide
Unemploy-
ment Rate
Divorce
Rate
Fertility
Rate
FLP
**
Alcohol
Consumption
Unit
suicide/
100,000
suicide/
100,000
percent
divorce/
1,000
b
irth/
1000
*
percent liter
Mean 24.09 14.02 2.33 1.22 1.90 50.24 5.21
Std. Dev. 5.56 2.25 1.08 0.43 0.47 2.72 1.86
Maximum 37.49 20.59 5.38 2.30 3.65 56.70 8.08
Minimum 16.14 10.78 1.13 0.73 1.29 45.70 1.40
*
1000 women with age between 15-49.
**
FLP is the female labor force participation rate.
TABLE 1
Descriptive Statistics
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000
0
2
4
6
8
10
Ul tRt(%)
Fi 1 S i id t l t t d di t i J
Female Labor Participation
Male Suicide
Fertility
Alcohol
Consumption
FIGURE 4
Male Suicide and Social Variables in Japan
Suicides per 100,000 persons
FLP (%)
Births per female pop (15-49)
Lliters
p
er
p
ers
o
n
(
15+
)
27
De-trended
Variable
Male Suicide
Female
Suicide
Unemploy-
ment
Divorce Fertility FLP
Female Suicide 0.76
Unemployment 0.62 0.38
Divorce 0.52 0.17 0.46
Fertility -0.10 -0.30 -0.05 0.23
FLP 0.25 0.24 -0.06 -0.12 -0.22
Alcohol -0.03 -0.02 -0.11 -0.24 0.00 0.20
*
Random Walk filtered series (1953-2000)
TABLE 2
Correlation Coefficients of De-trended Variables
*
28
De-trending Method
Unemploy-
ment
Divorce Fertility FLP Alcohol
R
2
Level
2.19
***
(3.48) 0.13
Random Walk
5.76
***
(4.26) 0.38
Hodrick-Prescott
7.14
***
(7.84) 0.55
Band-Pass
5.31
***
(4.22) 0.32
Random Walk
4.51
***
(3.50)
12.64
*
(1.81) 0.46
Hodrick-Prescott
6.04
***
(7.00)
12.70
***
(3.58) 0.62
Band-Pass
4.11
***
(3.71)
22.71
***
(4.52) 0.50
Random Walk
4.34
***
(4.00)
15.99
*
(2.93)
-1.53
*
(1.83)
0.67
***
(4.29)
0.40
(0.61) 0.56
Hodrick-Prescott
5.94
***
(7.84)
11.96
***
(3.07)
-0.69
(0.35)
0.45
**
(2.02)
0.19
(0.27) 0.65
Band-Pass
4.43
***
(4.44)
21.98
***
(4.53)
-0.89
(1.03)
0.47
*
(1.79)
0.05
(0.09) 0.53
TABLE 3
Newey-West heteroskedasticity-autocorrelation consistent t statistics in parenthesis. A *** indicates
significance at the 1% level. A ** indicates significance at the 5% level. A * indicates significance at the
10% level.
Estimates of Male Suicide in Japan
Eq. (7)
Eq. (8)
Eq. (9)
29
De-trending Method
Unemploy-
ment
Divorce Fertility FLP Alcohol
R
2
Level
-1.85
***
(4.45) 0.12
Random Walk
1.40
***
(3.00) 0.14
Hodrick-Prescott
2.06
***
(4.26) 0.23
Band-Pass
1.08
***
(3.14) 0.10
Random Walk
1.41
***
(2.84)
-0.06
(0.02) 0.14
Hodrick-Prescott
2.20
***
(4.31)
-1.62
(0.85) 0.23
Band-Pass
0.95
***
(2.92)
2.34
(1.08) 0.11
Random Walk
1.21
***
(2.81)
1.84
(0.81)
-1.66
***
(4.68)
0.20
*
(2.14)
-0.01
(0.02) 0.27
Hodrick-Prescott
2.13
***
(4.33)
-1.74
(0.86)
-0.57
(0.50)
0.18
(0.98)
0.01
(0.02) 0.26
Band-Pass
0.97
***
(2.77)
2.59
(1.30)
-1.28
***
(3.13)
0.12
(1.29)
-0.10
(0.41) 0.18
TABLE 4
Newey-West heteroskedasticity-autocorrelation consistent t statistics in parenthesis. A *** indicates
significance at the 1% level. A ** indicates significance at the 5% level. A * indicates significance at the
10% level.
Estimates of Female Suicide in Japan
Eq. (7)
Eq. (8)
Eq. (9)