1
/// Collective Defined Contribution Plans | Discussion Draft
Discussion Draft
Collective Defined
Contribution Plans
______________________________________________________
J. Mark Iwry
J. Mark Iwry is a nonresident senior fellow at Brookings and a visiting scholar at the Wharton School at the
University of Pennsylvania
David C. John
David C. John is a nonresident senior fellow at Brookings, deputy director of the Retirement Security
Project, and senior policy advisor at the AARP Public Policy Institute
Christopher Pulliam
Christopher Pulliam is a research analyst at Brookings
William G. Gale
William Gale the Arjay and Frances Fearing Miller Chair in Federal Economic Policy and senior fellow at
Brookings, Director of the Retirement Security Project, and Co-Director of the Urban-Brookings Tax Policy
Center
This report is available online at: brookings.edu/research/collective-defined-contribution-plans
The Brookings Economic Studies program analyzes current
and emerging economic issues facing the United States and the
world, focusing on ideas to achieve broad-based economic
growth, a strong labor market, sound fiscal and monetary
policy, and economic opportunity and social mobility. The
research aims to increase understanding of how the economy
works and what can be done to make it work better.
September 2021
2
/// Collective Defined Contribution Plans | Discussion Draft
Abstract
The long-term shift in the U.S. retirement system from defined benefit pension (DB) plans to retirement
saving accounts such as 401(k) plans and IRAs has transferred significant financial risks to workers, many
of whom are ill-equipped to handle the contingencies. Collective defined contribution (CDC) plans offer a
way to rethink risk sharing. CDCs permit employers to avoid the funding cost and volatility of guaranteed
DB benefits while providing savers and retirees DB-like professional investment management and
pooling, longevity risk pooling, and lifetime income. To be effective, however, CDC plans need to address
issues regarding expectations, equity, transition, and trust. If they can do so successfully, adding
particular CDC features to conventional DB plans or 401(k) plans in appropriate circumstances could
improve outcomes for workers, retirees, and employers. Looking beyond the conventional, traditional DB
and DC plan designs to explore a new, richer, and more nuanced array of risk-sharing and pooling
strategies is a welcome development that will help identify more optimal allocations of financial risks and
retirement benefits.
Acknowledgements
The authors thank Arnold Ventures for financial support and Grace Enda and Claire Haldeman for
research assistance.
Financial Disclosure
Iwry periodically provides, in some cases through J. Mark Iwry, PLLC, policy and legal advice to plan
sponsors and providers, government officials, academic institutions, other nonprofit organizations, trade
associations, fintechs, and other investment firms and financial institutions, regarding retirement and
savings policy, pension and retirement plans, and related issues. Iwry is a member of the American
Benefits Institute Board of Advisors, the Board of Advisors of the Pension Research Council at the
Wharton School, the Council of Scholar Advisors of the Georgetown University Center for Retirement
Initiatives, the Panel of Outside Scholars of the Boston College Center for Retirement Research, the CUNA
Mutual Safety Net Independent Advisory Board, a network of advisors to an investment firm, and the
Aspen Leadership Forum Advisory Board. He also periodically serves as an expert witness in federal court
litigation relating to retirement plans. The authors did not receive any financial support from any
organization or person for any views or positions expressed or advocated in this document. They are
currently not an officer, director, or board member of any organization that has compensated or otherwise
influenced them to write this paper or to express or advocate any views in this paper. Accordingly, the
views expressed here are solely those of the authors and should not be attributed to any other person or
any organization.
3
/// Collective Defined Contribution Plans | Discussion Draft
I. Introduction
Over the past four decades, the U.S. retirement system has largely shifted from defined benefit pension
(DB) plans to retirement saving accounts within the broader defined contribution (DC) category mainly
401(k) plans and to individual retirement accounts (IRAs). A key factor driving this change is
employers’ desire to avoid the risks associated with providing guaranteed pension benefits. This
guarantee a defining feature of DB plans can entail large funding obligations that can change
unpredictably and can wreak havoc on corporate balance sheets and budgets. But the flight from DB plans
to 401(k)s and IRAs did not make financial risks disappear; instead, it transferred the risks to individual
workers, many of whom are ill-equipped to handle the resulting contingencies.
Collective defined contribution (CDC) plans offer a way to rethink risk sharing between employers and
individuals and among savers and retirees. CDCs and other hybrid retirement plan formats combine DB
and DC elements in different ways. Variants already exist in several countries, are receiving serious
consideration in the United Kingdom, and have counterparts and close parallels in the United States.
1
In CDCs, employers avoid the funding volatility and investment risk of DB plans. Although CDCs are
technically DC plans, they provide some DB-like features for savers and retirees. Compared to 401(k)
plans, which feature individual accounts, participant-directed investing, and typically lump-sum payouts,
CDCs provide DB-style pooling of investments, professional investment management, and lifetime
retirement income. They reduce financial risks for individuals, relative to DC plans, but generally without
guaranteed benefits (Millard, Pitt-Watson, and Antonelli, 2021).
In this paper, we examine the opportunities and challenges associated with implementing CDCs in the
United States. We highlight the advantages of CDC plans as well as several issues that CDC plans must
confront, regarding expectations, equity, transition, and trust. We conclude that, under appropriate
circumstances and contingent on addressing those issues, adding particular CDC features to a 401(k) or a
conventional DB plan can improve outcomes for workers, retirees, and employers. More generally, we
emphasize that evaluations of CDCs depend greatly on the answers to two questions: “Compared to
what?” (e.g., traditional DB plans or 401(k) plans) and “From whose point of view?” (e.g., employees,
retirees, or employers).
Section II compares typical forms of DB and DC plans with a basic type of CDC plan. Section III describes
CDCs and similar plan designs in a number of countries, including the United States. Section IV discusses
the challenges relating to implementing CDC plans. Section V concludes.
II. Typical retirement plan forms
Retirement plans generally come in three main types DB, DC, and hybrids. In this section, we compare
and contrast the typical features of basic DB, DC, and CDC plans, a certain type of hybrid. Table 1 provides
summary details.
Defined Benefit Plans
In the typical DB plan, eligible workers are automatically covered and do not make contributions.
Employers guarantee and pre-fund benefits, make investment choices, and bear the financial risks
associated with low asset returns or retirees living longer than anticipated. Benefits are based on
employees’ tenure with the company and a measure of average or final earnings. Benefits are offered and
often paid as an annuity with regular (typically monthly) income guaranteed for the lifetime of the retiree
and spouse, if any. Many DBs, however, allow participants to forgo this longevity risk protection and opt
1
These variants and hybrid plans include “defined ambition” (rather than defined benefit), “target benefit”, “collective money
purchase”, “variable DB”, “variable annuity”, “adjustable pension”, or “shared risk” plans and are discussed below.
4
/// Collective Defined Contribution Plans | Discussion Draft
for a lump sum payment instead. There are numerous qualifications and exceptions to this skeletal
description.
2
DB plans offer distinct advantages to employees and retirees. Individuals do not need to make decisions
about, or face the risks associated with, enrollment, contribution levels, investment allocations, and
portfolio rebalancing. The only real decisions a DB participant needs to make are when to retire and start
claiming benefits, and the form in which to take them. Age- or service-based incentives in DB plans,
reflecting employers’ workforce management priorities, are typically strong and can make choices easier.
DB participants benefit from having pooled and professionally managed investments that comply with
strict fiduciary standards.
Nevertheless, DBs have their drawbacks. Even when most widely used, they tended to exclude broad
swaths of the labor force. Because their benefit formulas tend to accumulate benefits on a “back-loaded”
basis, DB plans provide significantly smaller benefits to those, including many women, with interrupted
careers or with frequent job changes and are generally less portable. Private-sector DB plans, and to a
lesser degree government DB plans, often leave retirees exposed to inflation risk. DB participants may
also be exposed to some underfunding risk, although mitigated to a great extent by Pension Benefit
Guaranty Corporation (PBGC) pension benefit guarantees. For employers, DB sponsorship can entail
costly and potentially volatile pre-funding requirements, has a significant regulatory burden, and is seen
as complex and underappreciated by employees.
These drawbacks, combined with several other trends, led to a steady decline in DB plans. First, the
unionized sector and the manufacturing sector where the DB presence was substantial have steadily
shrunk. Second, women’s labor force participation rose. Third, DB costs rose as the ratio of retirees to
active workers increased over time.
Defined Contribution Plans
A DC plan maintains an individual account for each participant that sets the participant’s benefit as the
balance resulting from cumulative participant and employer contributions allocated to individual
accounts based on a stated allocation formula net of withdrawals and adjusted for the account’s
investment experience. The employee bears all investment risk. The prevalent DC plan design in the
United States is the 401(k) plan.
In 401(k) plans, employers do not face risks related to asset returns, inflation, or retiree longevity, and
typically face low funding costs often under 3 percent of payroll compared to DB plans. In addition,
401(k) employer matches of employee contributions tend to be relatively predictable and can be reduced
or suspended in a bad economic climate, thus avoiding funding volatility. Finally, 401(k) plans are simpler
to administer than DBs.
Participants also seem to like 401(k)s. For many workers, the appeal of owning growing account balances
seems to outweigh the less tangible, long-term promise of DB post-retirement income. Also, 401(k)s are
more accessible and portable than DBs during times of hardship and job changes.
Over time, as 401(k)s became the primary retirement for more and more people in the United States,
traditional 401(k)s evolved to more recent versions with automated features. Automatic provisions
essentially re-insert some DB-like features into 401(k)s. In a fully automated 401(k), workers are
automatically enrolled, their contributions automatically escalate over time, their accounts are
automatically invested in reasonable ways, and their accounts are rolled over upon job changes.
Participants in an automated 401(k) have full control over these decisions and can override the automatic
2
For example: Private-sector employees seldom contribute to their DB plans, although they often bear the cost of contributions by
receiving lower wages. State and local government plans (where DB remains prevalent) usually require employee as well as employer
contributions. Although employers bear the financial risk, most DB plan benefits are insured by the PBGC in the event of employer
insolvency with unfunded plan benefits.
5
/// Collective Defined Contribution Plans | Discussion Draft
settings if they so choose the rules are defaults not mandates. But participants do not have to make
these choices if they do not want to.
Although they benefit from professionally determined investment options, 401(k) participants don’t
benefit from the diversification gains from additional pooling available in DBs, often face retail pricing of
fees, and still bear the full risk of uncertain asset returns. In addition, 401(k) plans usually receive smaller
employer contributions and pay lump sums, potentially jeopardizing participants’ ability to generate
sufficient retirement income and protect themselves from longevity risk. These shortcomings provide
opportunities for plans like CDCs to maintain the benefits of automated 401(k)s and address their
weaknesses.
Collective Defined Contribution Plans
CDC plans aim to share financial risks in ways that emphasize the strengths and minimize the drawbacks
of DBs and DCs. CDC plans come in many variants; in this section, we focus on a typical CDC plan to
highlight the differences with standard DB and DC plans. In Section III we discuss the variety of hybrid
plans in the United States and other countries that include somewhat similar features.
As in DC plans, it is common for both plan sponsors and/or participating employees to contribute to a
CDC. As in a DB plan, employees generally do not have full 401(k)-style individual accounts (where the
benefit is framed as an account balance resulting from contributions (less withdrawals) and individual
investment returns); however, participants might be seen as having individual accounts in the narrower
sense that certain individual data, such as contributions by and on behalf of individual workers, are
tracked and reported to them. The contributions of an employer’s (or an industry’s) work force are pooled
and professionally managed. The fund managers target future annual benefit levels, but benefit amounts
are not guaranteed.
For plan sponsors, CDCs avoid volatile funding costs by accepting fixed employer contributions correcting
this drawback of DB plans. For workers, CDCs (a) pay benefits in the form of periodic retirement income
(rather than lump sums), (b) pool longevity risk across participants; and (c) provide pooled, professional
investing, correcting these weaknesses of most DC plans.
Paying benefits in the form of periodic income such as an annuity and pooling longevity risk helps
people balance the risks associated with either over-consuming early in retirement, thereby risking
running out of funds later, or under-consuming early in retirement, thereby risking having a lower
standard-of-living than necessary. This pooling also enables people to confidently save for an average life
expectancy rather than needing to save for an extremely long one. In addition, CDC plans’ pooling of
investment and longevity risk and lack of guarantee of benefit amounts enables them to provide lifetime
retirement income in-house; they have the option but not the necessity of purchasing commercial
annuities. As a result, they can pay income while avoiding the regulatory, marketing, and profit-margin
costs of commercial annuities.
Pooled, professional investing reduces administrative fees relative to account balances. It increases
participants’ access to a wider range of asset classes, including those that might offer an illiquidity
premium, which are harder for an individual to invest in. It also helps spread a number of risks over time
and across workers, including smoothing routine asset volatility and the sequence-of-return risk and
timing risk associated with having to liquidate assets at a certain point. Some CDC plans, for example, use
reserve funds accumulated from surplus returns in good times to buffer losses during down markets.
Finally, professional investing helps workers avoid “amateur” mistakes such as overinvesting in the
employer’s stock or failing to rebalance.
For employers, one drawback of CDCs, relative to a DC, is the inability to reduce or suspend contributions
in an adverse economic climate. For workers, the key drawback is that benefit levels are not guaranteed:
employees bear the investment risk, in the form of potential benefit cuts or increased employee
contributions if the plan is doing poorly.
6
/// Collective Defined Contribution Plans | Discussion Draft
In addition to pooling among individuals and smoothing over time, these risks have been partially
addressed using a “defined ambition” (DA) design that distinguishes “base” and “ancillary” benefits. Base
benefits are not guaranteed but expected to be paid even under very conservative financial assumptions.
“Ancillary” benefits such as cost-of-living adjustments or basing benefits on final pay rather than less
generous career average pay are more explicitly contingent on the plan’s financial condition; if benefits
need to be reduced, they will be cut first.
Is this simply a pyrrhic victory for workers, though, as it reduces “risk” by reducing expected benefits? The
key question, we would suggest, is, “Compared to what?” Compared to a 401(k) plan without investment
or longevity risk pooling or lifetime income, for example, a CDC design would likely benefit participants.
And compared to an unsustainable DB plan, a CDC strategy can establish a systematic, orderly process
that helps workers and retirees manage uncertainty, set reasonable expectations, and plan for retirement.
It is calculated to work in a more professional, fair, and predictable fashion than ad hoc decisions to cut or
suspend benefits made under pressure by plan management or politicians in politically charged
circumstances.
III. Experience with CDCs and related plan designs
The CDC-type and related hybrid pension plans around the world exhibit an array of features.
Understanding how these plans work can help inform discussion of policy reforms in the U.S (Doonan
and Wiley, 2021).
Other Countries
3
Netherlands
The Netherlands has undertaken the largest and most sustained effort to implement a CDC or DA system
on a national basis. The Dutch experience over the past two decades shows how CDC plans can be
implemented at scale and how various challenges and complexities arise and can be addressed.
4
Employee participation is mandatory; employers must participate unless they can offer a better plan. Both
employers and employees make contributions. Dutch occupational-level plans, covering about 80 percent
of the workforce, are collectively bargained, extensively regulated, and professionally managed.
The plans usually target benefits based on an employee’s career average wage, but the actual benefits
depend on the plan’s financial status and therefore are not guaranteed. Participants bear all investment
risk through a combination of potential benefit cuts and increased employee contributions. To help
manage this risk, when the plan’s funding ratio falls below certain benchmarks, it must create a multi-
year recovery program that includes employee contribution increases and/or temporary limits or
elimination of cost-of-living adjustments (COLAs), or even cuts in nominal benefits. However, when
benefit cuts actually had to be made several years after the 2008-09 financial crisis, they came as an
unwelcome surprise to many participants. Those risks had not been adequately communicated or
understood, and trust in the system declined.
A key feature of the Dutch DA system has been uniform accruals. Each participant, regardless of age,
accrues the same benefit rights at the same contribution rate. From an actuarial perspective, this means
that younger participants pay more than they should and thus subsidize older participants, who pay less
than they should, yet protecting retirees from current cuts in their ongoing pension payments tends to
have greater political urgency than the need to adequately fund pensions for those whose retirement is
decades in the future. If the plan continues perpetually, and there is always an ample supply of younger
3
In addition to the CDC initiatives described below, Denmark also has implemented similar plan designs.
4
This summary is based on Bovenberg, Mehlkopf, and Nijman(2014), Gérard (2019), Van Popta and Steenbeek (2021), and
Westerhout, Ponds, and Zwanevald (2021).
7
/// Collective Defined Contribution Plans | Discussion Draft
workers to support older ones, these intergenerational inequities will even out over each worker’s lifetime.
But this points up a key vulnerability: the sustainability of the Dutch DA system and CDC plans like it
assumes mandatory participation, especially among younger workers, and perpetual existence of the
system.
The Dutch CDC/DA system has been controversial. In 2020, after years of debate about intergenerational
inequities, complexity, and participant perceptions and disappointed expectations, the Dutch government
proposed reforms. These reforms reportedly are strongly supported by the “social partners”, including
labor and employers, and are generally expected to become law (Hoekert, 2021).
The “New Pension Contract” would retain several key elements of the current system including
mandatory participation; monthly lifetime income without a guarantee of the exact amount; and
collective, professional asset management without direction from individual employees. But it would
make changes that move it closer to a DC model. The uniform accrual and contribution system would be
replaced by an “actuarially fair” system. Benefit rights would no longer be accrued; instead, the accrual or
accounting system would be based on units of value in accounts. The funding ratio would cease to be a
metric: instead, a reserve fund would be mandated to hedge against poor financial performance.
Collective investment returns would be allocated differentially to participants based on a predefined set of
rules. New options would be available for benefit payments, including a lump sum of up to 10 percent of
retirement assets.
The history of the Dutch CDC program illustrates that CDCs have both advantages and potential pitfalls
and may help explain why one commenter opined that a “CDC” actually stood for “Complicated DC” plan
(Lundbergh, 2021).
Canada
The Canadian experience highlights the “compared to what” question noted above. After the financial
crisis of 2008-09, there was significant fear in the Canadian province of New Brunswick that public-sector
DB plans no longer appeared to be politically or financially viable. Faced with that reality, CDC plans were
seen as the preferable alternative to a pure DC approach.
5
As a result, several underfunded public and
private-sector DB plans in Canada moved or are moving to a new “shared risk” program somewhat similar
to the Netherlands’ DA approach. The Canadian “shared risk” model prescribes funding and risk
management goals (including financial stress tests and projected funding ratios) with pre-determined cuts
or increases in benefit payouts and increases or reductions in employer and employee contributions as
well as changes in asset allocations in response to changes in the plan’s financial condition. The plans
maintain an employer guarantee of “base benefits,” defined using career average salary. The difference
between benefits based on career average wages and final wages, together with post-retirement cost-of-
living increases, are classified as ancillary benefits that are not guaranteed but would be provided
depending on the plan’s financial condition.
United Kingdom
The United Kingdom is considering CDC plans, also known there as “Collective Money Purchase” (CMP)
plans.
6
Subject to extensive regulatory oversight to ensure financial soundness and appropriate plan
design, U.K. employers and employees would contribute to a fund that is professionally managed. Payouts
would be targeted to a specific benefit level but, to make employer costs predictable, would not be
guaranteed and would depend on the plan’s financial status. CDC plan benefits would be expected to be
designed to generally increase over time to keep up with inflation, although they would not be required to
5
From a 2013 government report, “Many in the public complained openly about the generosity of these [DB] schemes and the fact
that they have to pay extra taxes to cover pension deficits for benefits that they cannot afford for themselves” (Government of New
Brunswick, 2013, page 7). Further, a background report on pension reform from the New Brunswick government stated that,
financially, “many [DB] plans as they presently exist are not sustainable in the long term.” (Government of New Brunswick, 2012,
page 1). See also Munnell and Sass (2013).
6
Summary based on Department for Work & Pensions (2021), Thurley and McInnes (2021), and Eagle, Jadav, and Fadayel (2020).
8
/// Collective Defined Contribution Plans | Discussion Draft
match inflation every year. In addition, the value of a participant’s expected benefits over time would be
required to at least equal the contributions made by or for the participant.
This framework appears to draw lessons from the Dutch experience, addressing concerns about
intergenerational equity by seeking to prevent excessive cross-subsidization (in either direction) between
new participants and long-time participants and thus between past and future benefit accruals. For
similar reasons, benefit changes must be universal, with any cuts generally smoothed over three years.
United States
The United States has a variety of hybrid plan designs, both actual and proposed. This section describes
these plans, organizing them into three categories: longstanding DC plan designs that have collective
features; recently developed plan designs that are more DB-like with CDC features; and approaches that
use separate DB and DC plans.
Traditional DC-like plan designs with collective features
Money purchase pension plans were originally used as an alternative to DB plans to limit employers’ cost
and potential liability. Money purchase plans are typically funded by employer contributions, usually
made annually and based on a fixed formula (such as 10 percent of salary). Investments are pooled,
professionally managed, and allocated to each participant’s individual account. Benefits are based on
account balances, including both contributions and earnings, so participants bear the investment risk.
The default form of payouts must be an annuity, although the plans can also offer other payout
alternatives.
Target benefit plans are a variant of money purchase plans that closely resembles a CDC. Unlike other
money purchase plans, target benefit plans define a participant’s benefits as a targeted, not a guaranteed,
amount. The target benefit is the basis for determining how much the employer should contribute based
on reasonable actuarial assumptions (instead of contributing a fixed percentage of payroll). Since
participants’ actual benefits are still determined by the contributions and earnings allocated to their
individual account, they still bear the investment risk. This plan design traditionally has not been widely
used in the United States, although various CDC designs in the United States and abroad are now referred
to as “target benefit plans.
Profit-sharing plans are more flexible and subject to fewer requirements. Instead of defining required
annual employer contributions, profit-sharing plans allow employer contributions to be discretionary,
and payouts need not be offered as an annuity. Profit-sharing plans can include pooling and professional
direction of investments, but instead often incorporate 401(k) arrangements allowing employees to direct
their own investments.
Both profit-sharing and money purchase plans (including target benefit plans) traditionally provide
meaningful nonmatching employer contributions, such as 7 or 10 percent of salary, as would some other
CDC-type plans. It may be no accident that these traditional plan types, like private-sector DB plans, have
been largely succeeded by 401(k)s and IRAs in the United States, a change that reduces employers’ costs
and risks. Employers have little incentive to offer such larger contributions if employees show equal or
greater appreciation for an un-pooled 401(k) with smaller employer contributions.
During the 1990s and thereafter, a large share of U.S. DB pension plan sponsors converted to a DB-DC
hybrid known as a cash balance pension, and some employers adopted new cash balance plans. The cash
balance plan is presented to participants essentially as if it were a DC plan, but it is actually a DB with
both employer-guaranteed benefits and PBGC insurance. Each participant has an individual account, but
the accounts are notional and are credited with employer contributions equal to a specified percentage of
the employee’s pay that “grow” at a pre-determined interest rate. The employer guarantee of benefits is
effectively limited to the benefit produced by the notional employer contributions and interest credits.
The actual employer contributions are invested on a plan-wide, pooled basis, and not directed by
9
/// Collective Defined Contribution Plans | Discussion Draft
employees. Cash balance plans are required to offer lifetime annuity income as the default form of payout,
but many participants elect lump sum payouts instead.
The cash balance experience illustrates the transition risks associated with converting a traditional DB
plan to a hybrid format. For years, the conversions engendered litigation and bitter controversy because
they unexpectedly deprived mid-career DB participants of their anticipated major increases in late-career
benefit accruals provided by traditional, back-loaded DB plans.
DB-Like variable benefit plans, including proposed composites
Recent years have seen significant experimentation with hybrid plans, especially in the U.S. collectively
bargained and state and local government sectors (including, in particular, Maine and South Dakota). The
objective is to manage the shift from traditional DB plans to a plan design that shares risks with
participants in a more collective manner than the individualized 401(k). Labor unions have been
particularly creative in developing and advocating for hybrid pension plan designs that are sponsored and
funded by employers, sometimes have employee contributions, define targeted benefits in a DB-like
manner, invest collectively and professionally without employee involvement, and pool longevity risk to
provide lifetime retirement income. Like defined ambition and CDC plans, these variable benefit plans
protect employers from potentially volatile funding obligations. Although they have DB-like benefit
formulas, some do not guarantee benefits, while others include both a base guaranteed DB component
and a variable component.
The “Variable DB” plan design developed by the United Food and Commercial Workers (UFCW), for
example, combines traditional DB and CDC designs by guaranteeing a DB benefit as a base amount and
providing a potentially higher benefit depending on investment performance of the pension fund.
Investment risk is shared: employers bear the underfunding risk up to the base benefit amount while
employees bear the risk that the variable benefit will not exceed the base benefit. The plan seeks to limit
the employer’s DB funding cost and volatility by designing the guaranteed benefit to be manageable in
amount and by prescribing conservative funding rules to minimize the risk of underfunding that base
benefit.
7
The National Coordinating Committee for Multiemployer Plans, a broad-based association of major
business, union, and other stakeholder organizations in the multiemployer pension arena, has proposed a
hybrid plan solution to multiemployer plan underfunding (Defrehn and Shapiro, 2013).
8
Proposed
legislation, which would authorize so-called “composite” plans in the United States, passed the House of
Representatives in 2020, but was not been taken up by the Senate as it aroused considerable controversy,
including strong support and strong opposition within organized labor.
9
Composite plans would be neither DB nor DC. They would not have individual accounts. Assets would be
pooled and professionally invested. Employers would make fixed contributions negotiated between labor
and management, and benefits would be determined by the plan formula and paid as a life annuity.
Employees would bear the risk that adverse investment experience would necessitate benefit reductions.
A composite plan would not be considered fully funded until its projected funded ratio reached 120
percent, and if the plan fell below this benchmark, corrective actions, potentially including benefit
7
The Variable DB design was developed by a UFCW Union task force that concluded in 2006 that continued DB pensions were
unsustainable but rejected a shift to DC because of the extent of the risk that would impose on participants. Participants would
ultimately receive the greater of (i) a DB benefit floor of a specified dollar amount per month for each year of service, guaranteed by
the PBGC, and (ii) a variable or adjustable benefit that could fluctuate based on investment experience. The DB floor would be
determined using conservative interest rates and could be reset periodically as plan demographics changed. Additional investment
returns would accrue to the variable portion of the benefit up to a cap, and any higher returns would instead be set aside in a reserve
to maintain future floor benefits during market downturns. See Blitzstein (2016). This basic approach, which can be used by
multiemployer or single-employer plans, has been adopted thus far by a handful of union plans and by the State of Maine for local
government employees. Maine’s plan features employer and employee contributions that vary based on market performance
(subject to caps and floors) and variable COLAs.
8
The same report by this organization also included the variable DB plan as another promising, innovative hybrid plan design.
9
See GROW Act (2018) and The Heroes Act (2020).
10
/// Collective Defined Contribution Plans | Discussion Draft
reductions, would be required. Under the proposed legislation, the joint union-management board of
trustees that manages multiemployer plans would be granted broad powers to provide for benefit
reductions, but increased contributions would be required only if agreed to by both management and
labor.
10
If a plan was doing well, benefits could be increased only subject to extensive conditions and
limitations based on funded ratios and other matters. Because they would not be DB plans, composite
plans would not be insured by the PBGC.
The proposal lets current multiemployer DB plans transition to composite plans, with the original DB
remaining as a “legacy plan” that is still PBGC-insured. When employers switch from DB to composite,
participants would cease accruing new benefits under the legacy plan and begin accruing new benefits
under the composite plan. Employers would be required to continue funding the legacy plan, but at a
slower pace, with the goal of eventually achieving a 100 percent funding ratio. The proposed risk shift
from employers to employees would also include significant reduction of “withdrawal liability” for
employers that choose to stop participating in the multiemployer plan (Topoleski, 2020). One of the
reasons the composite proposal has aroused controversy is concern about whether it would unduly
weaken funding of the legacy DB plan another illustration of how new hybrids, including CDCs, can
raise significant transition issues and put a premium on effective plan governance.
Coordinated DB and DC plans
Instead of pursuing the best of DB and DC features by combining the two within a single collective DC or
hybrid plan, similar results can be achieved by using separate DB and DC plans. These can either be
coordinated for example, by giving participants the greater of the two types of benefits, as in a “floor-
offset” plan – or independent, by giving participants the sum of the two. Both the greater-of and the sum-
of designs permit pooled professional investment and retirement income with longevity risk pooled
among retirees.
11
A third option involving DB and DC plans gives employees the choice to participate in
either one but not both.
IV. Challenges for CDCs
As the discussion above demonstrates, CDC and hybrid plans have made in-roads into pension systems in
the United States and several other countries. Whether they can expand further depends on resolution of
several issues.
First, can participants understand and accept the partial nature of the benefit guarantee? The “defined”
retirement income features of DB and DC plans are clear: in a DB, a specified monthly dollar amount for
life starting at a specified age; in a typical DC, no such guaranteed or targeted monthly retirement income.
Participants in a CDC with benefits that are targeted but not guaranteed might eventually develop
expectations beyond those that are justified by the plan’s terms. The distinction between defined
“ambition” and defined “benefit” is clear in principle, but as a practical matter, may be hard for
participants to live with and for plan sponsors to sustain over the longer term especially when plan
provisions are complex, potentially nuanced, and ultimately subject to the plan management’s exercise of
discretion. Especially if investment returns are strong for some years, participants might naturally tune
out a plan’s qualifications and caveats and to come to expect and rely on benefits (especially those already
in the process of being paid) being at least equal to those that were targeted. Accordingly, the success of
CDC plans is heavily dependent on accurate and effective plan communications to shape clear and
realistic participant expectations.
Experience could well shed light on whether, and, if so, how, CDC plan design could mitigate the risk of
participant “expectation creep.” For example, in contrast to a purely variable CDC, might a binary CDC
structure with a guaranteed DB benefit and a separate variable targeted benefit naturally reinforce
10
See Internal Revenue Code section 439(a)(2)(B)(i), as proposed to be added by the GROW Act.
11
Another hybrid plan design in the United States. is the “DB-k” plan that combines a DB plan and a 401(k) arrangement, but these
are very rarely used. See IRC section 414(x).
11
/// Collective Defined Contribution Plans | Discussion Draft
accurate participant expectations through a clear and consistent demarcation between the guaranteed and
nonguaranteed components (such as a guaranteed benefit versus a targeted but nonguaranteed COLA)?
The risk of “expectation creep” or misunderstanding presents a particular problem in the litigious U.S.
market. In recent years, the U.S. plan sponsor community has become shell shocked by widespread
litigation challenging retirement plan practices and costs. In this environment, employers and their
counsel can be expected to ask whether the efficiencies of CDCs are worth the risk of setting benefit
“targets” that might not be met or well understood by employees. They may fear exposing themselves to
class actions claiming that benefit cuts could have been avoided, that employees were not adequately
warned that cuts might occur, and that particular cohorts were unfairly disadvantaged by transitions to
CDC or other exercises of discretion by CDC plan sponsors. A pure DC model looks clear and simple by
comparison, particularly as Americans seem to have less expectation than others that retirement plans
should and will provide lifetime income.
Second, can CDC plans be designed to meet intergenerational equity considerations? CDCs need to
mediate between different generations of workers, new and old members, and employees versus retirees.
Disparities in treatment actual or perceived, equitable or not follow from the inevitable changes over
time in business cycles, investment returns of various asset classes, interest rates, wage levels, and other
factors. These variables affect various plan types and designs. For example, because CDC plans pool
contributions and payouts for workers of different ages, fund managers’ decisions at a particular time to
increase payouts or increase required employee contributions tend to benefit current retirees (who are
receiving payouts but not contributing) at the expense of current workers (who are contributing but not
receiving payouts). In addition, as noted above, in a system where each worker contributes the same
amount, as in the Netherlands, younger participants pay more than they should from an actuarial
perspective while older participants pay less. For these and other reasons, CDCs have given rise to inter-
generational tensions and challenging sustainability problems.
Third, can transition effects be managed appropriately at the plan level? Where a CDC or variable DB
starts as an existing DB plan as composite plans would transition is critical. As noted, conversions of
traditional U.S. DBs to hybrid cash balance plans created major transition problems. In addition, the
“composite” proposal discussed above, for example, has raised concerns about whether employer funding
of participants’ existing DB benefits would be unduly weakened by relaxation of existing funding
standards for the DB legacy component while adding a composite component competing for a single pool
of assets and funding source. An additional concern is that transitions, such as the cash balance
conversions, almost inevitably generate disparities in treatment of participants by age.
Fourth, can transition effects be managed appropriately at the retirement system level? For several
reasons, CDCs and similar designs may prove more likely to be adopted as replacements for existing DBs
than for 401(k)s. First, employers have already shifted most financial risks associated with retirement
plans to employees and retirees through 401(k)s and IRAs. Second, it may be easier to persuade
employers with DB plans who face higher costs and risks than those with 401(k)s that CDCs can help
reduce their costs and risks.
Among employers with 401(k)s, the realistic prospect may be incremental addition of selected collective
strategies or features. These might include help in converting account balances to regular income in
retirement or partial annuitization; enhanced participant access to lifetime income through managed
payout or systematic withdrawal funds; tontine-like mortality credit pooling; or more collective
professional investment including the broader use of institutional or collective approaches.
12
Fifth, is there enough trust and convergence of interests between labor and management to keep CDCs
financially sustainable and otherwise protective of participants? On an ongoing basis, CDCs’ shift of risk
from employers to participants and added flexibility to reduce benefits have raised questions about
whether they provide too much discretion to make changes adverse to participants without sufficient
guard rails or protections. The more adjustments a plan makes or has discretion to make that result in
12
In recent papers, we have explored issues raised by DC plans’ use of commercial annuities, managed payout and systematic
withdrawal funds, and tontine-like mortality credit pooling, See Iwry et al. (2019), Iwry et al. (2020), and John et al. (2019).
12
/// Collective Defined Contribution Plans | Discussion Draft
differential treatment in the pursuit of equity among different classes of participant groups, the greater
the scope for misunderstanding, disagreement, mistrust, and blame. The actuarial calculations and
judgments involved in ensuring CDC financial soundness and sustainability (even with respect to
nonguaranteed benefits) are not naturally transparent or easy for nonexperts to understand. These
concerns lead directly to a heightened need, in variable and adjustable benefit plans, for sound plan
management, governance, and safeguards (Frank 2018 and Ambachtsheer, 2020). The need or authority
to exercise discretion in these plan designs calls for a high degree of transparency and honest brokering
on the part of plan management and often regulatory authorities and policy makers.
Finally, CDCs raise a variety of questions about the tradeoff between pooling and portability when an
employee changes jobs well before retirement. For the most part, DC savings are relatively easy to move
between employer plans. Moving and consolidating DB benefits easily and without loss of value, however,
can be more challenging, and U.S. CDCs are more likely to be DB-like in this respect. If so, when a
participant leaves the employ of the plan sponsor, the CDC presumably would disclose their accrued
target lifetime retirement benefit as well as the lump sum amount available (which could be a refund of
their previous contributions to the plan, with or without interest or earnings) if they cashed out (and
thereby forfeited the retirement income benefit). Following the U.S. DB model, if the former employee left
the benefit in the plan, retirement income might not become available until they reached an early
retirement age such as 55 or 60. If instead they chose the lump sum, they could roll it over tax-free to
another plan or IRA. If a new employee wished to roll over a benefit from another plan into their new
employer’s CDC, the process would depend on that plan’s rules. Those might allow the funds to be
allocated to a separate, rollover account within the CDC plan or used to buy service credits in the CDC
(which might also be offered as an option for others to convert other retirement savings to additional
retirement income from the plan at retirement).
V. Conclusion
While they face significant issues, CDCs and similar approaches that transcend a strict adherence to
traditional DB or 401(k) plan designs can help improve retirement security in appropriate circumstances.
Where a traditional DB plan is well funded by a strong plan sponsor, for example, in the public sector or
in collectively bargained settings, CDCs and similar variable designs might provide some helpful flexibility
such as adjustable COLAs, but could also unnecessarily add complexity, new kinds of uncertainty,
intergenerational equity issues, and potentially unclear expectations for employees and retirees. In the
many situations, however, where the driver of change is the DB sponsor’s unwillingness or inability to
continue bearing costly and volatile investment and funding risks, maintaining an existing DB in its
current form may not be an option. When the alternative is a 401(k) plan, a better solution could be either
to modify the DB to add CDC features and flexibility or to add CDC features to the 401(k), including more
investment pooling and professional investment management, pooling of longevity risk among retirees,
and facilitating the payment of retirement income.
A CDC is also an option for an employer that currently offers a 401(k) but wants to provide a retirement
benefit with better features without the potential expense of a DB. A CDC could provide both higher
benefits and retirement income, rather than forcing new retirees to either incur the cost of a commercial
annuity or determine for themselves how to invest and at what pace to draw down the typical end-of-
career 401(k) lump sum payment.
Looking beyond the conventional, traditional DB and DC plan designs to explore a new, richer, and more
nuanced array of risk-sharing and pooling strategies is a welcome development that will help identify
more optimal allocations of financial risks and retirement benefits.
13
/// Collective Defined Contribution Plans | Discussion Draft
Table 1: Summary Comparison of Basic DB, 401(k), and CDC Plan Designs
Regular 401(k)
Auto 401(k)
CDC
Enrollment
Eligible employees
participate only if they
sign up
Eligible employees
participate unless
they opt out
Usually, no
employee initiative
required to
participate
Contributions
By employees (and in
most plans, employers)
By employees (and
in most plans,
employers)
By employers and
often employees
Contributions
pooled
Occasionally, but
usually not pooled
13
Occasionally, but
usually not pooled
Yes
Investment
Employees choose
among employer-
defined options
Employers set
default investment
choice, but
employees can also
choose among
employer- defined
options
Employers/
financial managers
manage on behalf
of employees
Allocation of risk
Individual participant
bears investment and
longevity risk
Individual
participant bears
investment and
longevity risk
Employees/
retirees collectively
share investment
and longevity risk
Determination of
benefits
Benefit depends solely
on contributions to
participant’s individual
account +/- investment
experience, less
withdrawals
Benefit depends
solely on
contributions to
participant’s
individual account
+/- investment
experience, less
withdrawals
Plan terms
determine targeted
but nonguaranteed,
variable monthly
pension benefit
Form of benefits
Usually, lump sum
Usually, lump sum
Lifetime income,
usually variable
Employer Funding
requirements
No but employer might
make defined
contributions
No but employer
might make
defined
contributions
Not like DB, but
employer
contributions
required based on
plan terms
13
An exception is 401(k)s that use investment pools instead of mutual funds.
14
/// Collective Defined Contribution Plans | Discussion Draft
References
Ambachtsheer, K. 2020. “Governance in Asset Owner Organizations: Still Room for
Improvement.” The Ambachtsheer Letter. KPA Advisory Services LTD. https://kpa-
advisory.com/the-ambachtsheer-letter/view/governance-in-asset-owner-organizations-
still-room-for-improvement
Blitzstein, D.S. 2016. “United States Pension Benefit Plan Design Innovation: Labor Unions as
Agents of Change.” In O.S. Mitchell & R.C. Shea (Eds.), Reimagining Pensions: The
Next 40 Years. Oxford University Press.
https://repository.upenn.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1093&context=prc_papers
Bovenberg, L., Mehlkopf, R., and Nijman, T. 2014. “The Promise of Defined Ambition Plans:
Lessons for the United States.” In O.S. Mitchell & R.C. Shea (Eds.), Reimagining
Pensions: The Next 40 Years. Oxford University Press.
https://repository.upenn.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1098&context=prc_papers
Defrehn, R.G. and Shapiro, J. 2013. “Solutions Not Bailouts: A Comprehensive Plan from
business and Labor to Safeguard Multiemployer Retirement Security, Protect Taxpayers
and Spur Economic Growth.” A Report on the Proceedings, Findings and
Recommendations of the Retirement Security Review Commission. National
Coordinating Committee for Multiemployer Plans. https://nccmp.org/wp-
content/uploads/2017/07/SolutionsNotBailouts.pdf
Department for Work & Pensions. 2021. “The Occupational Pension Schemes (Collective
Money Purchase Schemes) Regulations 2021.” Open Consultation. GOV.UK.
https://www.gov.uk/government/consultations/the-occupational-pension-schemes-
collective-money-purchase-schemes-regulations-2021/the-occupational-pension-
schemes-collective-money-purchase-schemes-regulations-2021
Doonan, D. and Wiley, E. 2021. “The Hybrid Handbook: Not All Hybrids are Created Equal.”
National Institute on Retirement Security. https://www.nirsonline.org/wp-
content/uploads/2021/05/Hybrid-Handbook-F8.pdf
Eagle, S., Jadav, S., and Fadayel, L. 2020. “CDC – A New Type of Pension Provision Coming to
the UK.” Willis Towers Watson. https://www.willistowerswatson.com/en-
GB/Insights/2020/09/collective-defined-contribution-a-new-type-of-pension-provision-
coming-to-the-UK
Frank, R. 2018. “Collective DC: Let’s Not Go Dutch.” IPE Magazine.
https://www.ipe.com/collective-dc-lets-not-go-dutch/10023436.article
Gérard, M. 2019. “Reform Options for Mature Defined Benefit Pension Plans: The Case of the
Netherlands.” International Monetary Fund.
https://www.elibrary.imf.org/view/journals/001/2019/022/article-A001-en.xml
Government of New Brunswick. 2012. “Pension Reform Background Document.”
https://www2.gnb.ca/content/dam/gnb/Corporate/pdf/Pension/Backgrounder_pension.pdf
Government of New Brunswick. 2013. “Rebuilding New Brunswick: The Case for Pension
Reform.” http://leg-horizon.gnb.ca/e-
repository/monographs/31000000047551/31000000047551.pdf
GROW Act. 2018. H.R. 4997. 115
th
Congress. https://www.congress.gov/bill/115th-
congress/house-bill/4997
Hoekert, W. 2021. “Netherlands: Pension Reforms Postponed for Up to One Year.” Willis
Towers Watson. https://www.willistowerswatson.com/en-
US/Insights/2021/05/netherlands-pension-reforms-postponed-for-up-to-one-year
15
/// Collective Defined Contribution Plans | Discussion Draft
Iwry, J.M., Gale, W.G., John, D.C., and Johnson, V. 2019. “When Income is the Outcome:
Reducing Regulatory Obstacles to Annuities in 401(k) Plans.” Brookings Institution.
https://www.brookings.edu/wp-
content/uploads/2019/07/ES_201907_IwryGaleJohnJohnson.pdf
Iwry, J.M., Haldeman, C., Gale, W.G., and John, D.C. 2020. “Retirement Tontines: Using a
Classical Finance Mechanism as an Alternative Source of Retirement Income.”
Brookings Institution. https://www.brookings.edu/wp-
content/uploads/2020/10/Retirement-Security-Project-Tontines-Oct-2020.pdf
John, D.C., Gale, W.G., Iwry, J.M., and Krupkin, A. 2019. “From Saving to Spending: A
Proposal to Convert Retirement Account Balances into Automatic and Flexible Income.”
Brookings Institution. https://www.brookings.edu/wp-
content/uploads/2019/07/ES_201907_JohnGaleIwryKrupkin.pdf
Lundbergh, S. 2021. “Miracles and Mirages of CDC.” LinkedIn Blog.
https://www.linkedin.com/pulse/miracles-mirages-cdc-stefan-lundbergh/
Millard, C.E.F., Pitt-Watson, D., and Antonelli, A.M. 2021. “Securing a Reliable Income in
Retirement: An Examination of the Benefits and Challenges of Pooled Funding and Risk-
Sharing in Collective Defined Contribution (CDC) Plans.” Center for Retirement
Initiatives, McCourt School of Public Policy, Georgetown University.
https://cri.georgetown.edu/wp-content/uploads/2021/04/policy-report-21-03.pdf
Munnell, A.H. and Sass, S.A. 2013. “New Brunswick’s New Shared Risk Pension Plan.” Center
for Retirement Research at Boston College. https://publicplansdata.org/wp-
content/uploads/2014/06/slp_33.pdf
The Heroes Act. 2020. H.R. 6800. 116
th
Congress. https://www.congress.gov/bill/116th-
congress/house-bill/6800
Thurley, D. and McInnes, R. 2021. “Pension Schemes Bill 2019-21.” Briefing Paper Number
CBP-8693. House of Commons Library.
https://researchbriefings.files.parliament.uk/documents/CBP-8693/CBP-8693.pdf
Topoleski, J.J. 2020. “Proposed Multiemployer Composite Plans: Background and Analysis.”
Congressional Research Service. R44722.
https://crsreports.congress.gov/product/pdf/R/R44722
Van Popta, B. and Steenbeek, O. 2021. “Transition to a New Pension Contract in the
Netherlands: Lessons from Abroad.” Netspar Industry Series. Network for Studies on
Pensions, Aging and Retirement.
https://www.netspar.nl/assets/uploads/P20210625_Netspar_Occasional_paper_03-
2021.pdf
Westerhout, E., Ponds, E., and Zwanevald, P. 2021. “Completing Dutch Pension Reform.”
Netspar Industry Series. Network for Studies on Pension, Aging and Retirement.
https://www.netspar.nl/assets/uploads/P20210812_Netspar-Design-Paper-179-WEB.pdf
16
/// Collective Defined Contribution Plans | Discussion Draft
The Brookings Economic Studies program
analyzes current and emerging economic issues
facing the United States and the world, focusing
on ideas to achieve broad-based economic
growth, a strong labor market, sound fiscal and
monetary policy, and economic opportunity and
social mobility. The research aims to increase
understanding of how the economy works and
what can be done to make it work better.
Questions about the research? Email [email protected].
Be sure to include the title of this paper in your inquiry.
© 2021 The Brookings Institution | 1775 Massachusetts Ave., NW, Washington, DC 20036 | 202.797.6000