THE ORIGINS OF THE FTC: CONCENTRATION,
COOPERATION, CONTROL, AND COMPETITION
Marc Winerman*
Concentration and co-operation are conditions imperatively essential
for industrial advance; but if we allow concentration and co-operation
there must be control in order to protect the people, and adequate
control is only possible through the administrative commission. Hence
concentration, co-operation, and control are the key words for a scien-
tific solution of the mighty industrial problem which now confronts
this nation.
Theodore Roosevelt, quoting Charles Van Hise,
in accepting the 1912 Progressive Party nomination.
1
[Standard Oil Co. v. United States
2
] will be a signal for the voluntary
breaking up of all combinations in restraint of trade within the inhibi-
tion of the [Sherman Act].
William Howard Taft, September 18, 1911.
3
[T]he proper role of the government is to encourage not combination,
but co-operation.
Letter of Louis D. Brandeis, November 11, 1911.
4
I don’t want a smug lot of experts to sit down behind closed doors in
Washington and play providence to me.
Woodrow Wilson, September 17, 1912.
5
[A]n attempt was very properly made . . . to provide tribunals which
would distinctly determine what was fair and what was unfair competi-
* Attorney, Office of the General Counsel, Federal Trade Commission. The views
expressed herein are the author’s and do not necessarily represent the views of the
Commission or any Commissioner. The author thanks William Kovacic, James May, Bruce
Freedman, James Hurwitz, Theodore Gebhard, Hillary Greene, Robert Lande, Stephen
Calkins, Marilyn Kerst, and Tara Koslov for helpful comments. The author also acknowl-
edges the help of Elaine Sullivan, other staff of the Federal Trade Commission library,
and Tab Lewis of the National Archives.
1
Confession of Faith, Aug. 6, 1912 Theodore Roosevelt,17Works of Theodore
Roosevelt 254, 276 [hereinafter TRW].
2
221 U.S. 1 (1911).
3
Speech, Sept. 18, 1911, 22 Taft Addresses 51, 58 in Reel 568, William Howard Taft
Papers, Library of Congress.
4
Brandeis to Charles Richard Crane, Nov. 11, 1911, in 2 Letters of Louis Brandeis
511, 512 (Melvin I. Urofsky & David W. Levy eds.) [hereinafter LBL].
5
25 Papers of Woodrow Wilson 148, 154 (Arthur S. Link ed.) [hereinafter PWW].
1
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal2
tion; and to supply the business community, not merely with lawyers
in the Department of Justice who could cry, Stop!, but with men in
such tribunals as the Federal Trade Commission, who could say, Go
on, who could warn where things were going wrong and assist instead
of check.
Woodrow Wilson, October 5, 1916.
6
I. INTRODUCTION
From the Sherman Acts passage in 1890 through the passage of the
Federal Trade Commission and Clayton Acts in 1914, antitrust was a
movement that inspired public agitation, not the specialized enter-
prise that it later became.
7
Yet it took nearly a decade of this formative
period to establish that the Sherman Act prevented manufacturers from
joining price-xing cartels. When Theodore Roosevelt became President
in 1901, it remained unclear if the law even applied to mergers.
Roosevelt began a second phase of the formative period. He pro-
ceeded, in part, by litigation. Northern Securities Co. v. United States,
8
which
dissolved a J.P. Morgan holding company, held that the Sherman Act
did reach mergers. With Roosevelts prompting, 1903 became the year
when antitrust was institutionalized.
9
On February 14, Roosevelt secured
a Bureau of Corporations, the precursor to the Federal Trade Commis-
sion.
10
The day the Bureau opened its doors, February 25, he secured
the rst antitrust appropriation and, with it, the seeds of the Antitrust
Division.
11
The formative periods second phase entered its home stretch in 1911,
when William Howard Taft was President and Standard Oil announced
the rule of reason. It culminated in 1914, when Woodrow Wilson was
President and Congress passed the Federal Trade Commission and Clay-
ton Acts. This study examines the Presidents, advisers, and legislators,
part of a second golden age of American politics,
12
who grappled
6
38 PWW, supra note 5, at 336, 34041.
7
Richard Hofstadter, What Happened to the Antitrust Movement?, reprinted in The Paranoid
Style in American Politics and Other Essays 188 (1965).
8
193 U.S. 197 (1904).
9
Hans B. Thorelli, The Federal Antitrust Policy: Origination of an American
Tradition 560 (1954). See also William Letwin, Law and Economic Policy in America
ch. 6 (1965; Phoenix ed. 1981) (Sherman Act matured between late 1901 and 1904).
10
Act of Feb. 14, 1903, ch. 552, § 6, 32 Stat. 825.
11
Act of Feb. 25, 1903, ch. 755, 32 Stat. 854, 903; Report of the Commissioner of
Corporations 78 (1904).
12
John Milton Cooper, Jr., Pivotal Decades xvxvi (1990) (period second only to
that of the Founding Fathers).
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
2003] Origins of the FTC 3
with questions of whether and how, consistent with prosperity, business
opportunity, and global competitiveness, to control corporate growth.
Roosevelts role remained crucial throughout these years. The cases
brought by his administration made credible a law whose premises, as
then construed, he openly disdained. In place of litigation, Roosevelt
envisioned an expanded Bureau of Corporations that would rationalize
the economy, tame rather than dissolve the trusts, and accommodate
rather than challenge both concentration and interrm cooperation. All
this would take place under government auspices, and the governments
ultimate backstop would be direct price regulation.
Other participants in the national debate were in some sense respond-
ing to Roosevelt and, after 1911, to Standard Oil. The debate posed
fundamental questions. To what extent had business grown through
efciencies and to what extent through unfair competition? To the
extent growth reected efciencies, had businesses nonetheless become
so large as to undermine the competitive market? If so, how could the
government protect consumers and competitors? To the extent past
growth reected misconduct, should it be reversed? If so, how? Should
rms be forcibly dissolved or could the market reverse past growth once
future misconduct was stopped? Should Congress rene the denitions
of misconduct in the Sherman Act and, if so, what practices should it
proscribe? However precise the statutory standards, should Congress
entrust their application (in the rst instance) to courts or to an adminis-
trative agency? If Congress relied on an administrative agency, how
should the agency operate? Should it challenge conduct after-the-fact,
perhaps through administrative proceedings? Should it opine on pro-
posed conduct in advance, and should its advice provide a shield against
(at least) criminal prosecution? Various nuances and permutations were
possible in responding to these questions. Advocates might converge on
similar remedies after starting from very different premises, or diverge
on their remedial prescriptions after starting from similar premises. Many
routes led to a commission, moreover, albeit to potentially quite different
visions of a commission.
Though he was Roosevelts hand-picked successor, William Howard
Taft had a fundamental commitment to a judicially applied rule of
reason, and he promised dramatic deconcentration under that rule. For
Woodrow Wilsons adviser Louis Brandeis, the benchmark was the curse
of bigness.Brandeis denied the efciency of massive enterprise, sought
to promote smaller enterprises, and saw antitrust as key to that promo-
tion. Brandeis showed more enthusiasm than Taft, though less than
Roosevelt, for an administrative commission. Further, he focused more
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal4
than Roosevelt, Taft, or Wilson on specic antitrust issues, such as resale
price maintenance and interlocking directorates.
Wilson himself ran against both Roosevelt (heading a third party) and
Taft (the Republican) in 1912. The candidate reached out both to the
Democratstraditional agrarian base, which broadly distrusted combina-
tions, as well as to business interests. Wilson approved of concentration
that resulted from efciencies, but suggested that consolidations rarely
generated efciencies. Although he questioned business growth, how-
ever, Wilson resisted forced dissolutions; he trusted the market to reverse
past growth if future misconduct was stopped. To stop that misconduct,
he declared that Congress should enunciate precise standards, backed by
criminal sanctions targeting both rms and individuals within those rms.
Soon after the election, though, Wilson reversed course on the dissolu-
tion question. He made more substantial reversals in 1914. The House
of Representatives had taken up his antitrust initiative and his program
for criminally enforced denitions was proving problematic. After a
meeting with Brandeis and three future Commissioners, most signi-
cantly George Rublee, Wilson then retreated from a strong denitions
bill (the Clayton bill) and endorsed instead a strong commission bill.
He embraced a provision, which became Section 5 of the FTC Act,
authorizing the agency to issue administrative orders proscribing unfair
competition(soon changed to unfair methods of competition).
13
Wil-
son did not, however, embrace Roosevelt-style regulation. As the legisla-
tive package nally emerged, the Commission could enforce both Section
5s general prohibition and specic prohibitions that survived in the
Clayton Act. But it could neither set prices nor immunize conduct from
Sherman Act prosecutions, and Wilson even fought to require broad
judicial review of the agencys determinations.
Because the House had passed its bill for an investigatory commission
before Wilson embraced a prosecutorial agency, the principal debate
on Section 5 occurred in the Senate. Senators views were wide-ranging.
Some opposed Section 5 because they preferred the status quo. Some
strong antitrust advocates continued to prefer strict statutory standards
backed by criminal sanctions; distrusting the proposed commission, they
either opposed Section 5 or at best supported it half-heartedly. Those
who afrmatively embraced a commission, though, approved an agency
that could apply a exible standard that prohibited incipientlaw viola-
tions and that could reach where the Sherman Act did not.
Spokesmen for Section 5 converged from different directions. Demo-
crat Francis Newlands had earlier been open to Roosevelt-style regula-
13
15 U.S.C. § 45.
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
2003] Origins of the FTC 5
tion, while Republican Albert Cummins had earlier expressed an agrarian
disdain for trusts. Newlands and Cummins differed in other respects,
and Henry Hollis, another Democratic spokesman for the bill, differed
from both. Newlands would have transferred all antitrust enforcement
to a commission, operating under a general standard; Hollis did not go
that far, but considered Congresss effort to develop specicdenitions
in the Clayton bill to be fundamentally awed; Cummins deemed Section
5 merely one tooland not the most important toolfor Congress to
direct antitrust policy. The three also approached unfair competition
from different, if not necessarily incompatible, perspectives. Newlands
emphasized a moral basis of the standard, although he drew support
for his moral standard from law and economics. Hollis and Cummins
focused more directly on economics; for Hollis, unfair competition was
competition that succeeded for reasons other than efciency and, for
Cummins, Section 5 would protect the competitive force. The bills
advocates also differed on the subject of judicial review of agency determi-
nations. Cummins fought for narrow review, but the issue mattered less
to Newlands and even less to Hollis. (All three, moreover, accepted a
more fundamental weakness; the Commissions sole recourse when a
respondent violated its order was, and remained until 1938, to seek
an injunction).
Part II of this article describes the industrial backdrop to the formative
periods second phase. Part III discusses the principal judicial bench-
marks of the formative period. Part IV turns to Roosevelt, Taft, Brandeis
and Wilson, describing their differing ideas in 1912 and, for Roosevelt
and Taft, the ways they already had implemented their ideas during their
Presidencies. Part V describes Wilsons and the Democrats victories in
1912, the post-election antitrust package that the President-elect secured
while still Governor of New Jersey, and his appointment of a known
trustbuster as Attorney General. Part VI explores the 1914 legislative
process that culminated with the enactment of a federal antitrust pack-
age. Finally, Part VII describes the launching of the Commission, when
Wilson emphasized assistance to business (a function not even mentioned
in the statute) rather than the investigative functions highlighted in the
House or the prosecutorial functions highlighted in the Senate, and
selected a complement of Commissioners that reected distrust of law-
yers and economists alike. The Commissions early history would soon
play out against a new backdrop, as wartime mobilization would encour-
age, and to some extent legitimate, unprecedented coordination under
government auspices. That backdrop would mold future debates over
antitrust policy, as well.
The Commissions own powers would also be supplemented in later
decades. Nonetheless, there emerged in 1914 a Commission with a broad
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal6
and exible mandate, wide-ranging powers, and the ability, at its best,
to respond to the needs of changing times.
II. PRELUDE: CONSOLIDATIONS AND THE MERGER WAVE
During the early twentieth century, the United States enjoyed unprece-
dented prosperity accompanied by unprecedented corporate consolida-
tion. Competition policy moved toward center stage as the country sought
to preserve the benets of the one without the costs of the other.
The roots of consolidation led back into the nineteenth century. Stan-
dard Oil controlled substantial petroleum rening as early as 1880, and
the whiskey and sugar trusts were formed in 1887.
14
New Jersey became
the traitor statewhen it facilitated consolidations in 1889, most signi-
cantly by allowing corporations to own stock in other rms.
15
By 1890,
Congress was sufciently concerned with the problem of trusts
16
to
pass the Sherman Act, forbidding in Section 1 [e]very contract, combina-
tion in the form of trust or otherwise, or conspiracy, in restraint of trade
or commerce among the several States, or with foreign nations, and
making it illegal in Section 2 to monopolize, or combine or conspire
with any other person or persons, to monopolize any part of the trade
or commerce among the several States, or with foreign nations.
17
States
passed antitrust laws as well, and some enforced them vigorously.
18
Neither federal nor state law, however, deterred a merger wave that
crested from 1898 to 1902. During those years at least 303 rms disap-
peared annually through mergers; 1,208 disappeared in 1899.
19
Many
consolidations simultaneously united multiple rms; 136 united ve rms
14
Letwin, supra note 9, at 6970.
15
Herbert Hovenkamp, Enterprise and American Law: 18361937, at 25758 (1991);
Christopher Grandy, New Jersey Corporate Chartermongering, 18751929,49J. Econ. Hist.
677 (1989).
16
Trust originally meant an arrangement transferring stock in multiple corporations
to a common trustee. Hovenkamp, supra note 15, at 24951. Various bills and laws, though,
simply dened wrongful combinations as trusts. See, e.g., S. 1 as Amended by the Senate,
51st Cong., 1st Sess. (Mar. 25, 1890); Sess. Laws, N.J., ch. 13 (1913), reprinted in House
of Representatives Committee on the Judiciary, Laws on Trusts and Monopolies
229 (rev. ed. 1914) [hereinafter Laws].
17
15 U.S.C. §§ 1, 2.
18
James May, Antitrust Practice and Procedure in the Formative Era: The Constitutional and
Conceptual Reach of State Antitrust Law, 18801918, 135 U. Pa. L. Rev. 495, 498501 (1987)
[hereinafter May, Reach].
19
Ralph L. Nelson, Merger Movements in American Industry, 18951956, at 37
(1959). Only 69 or fewer rms had disappeared annually through consolidations in the
three years before 1898. Only once did the number exceed 200 between 1903 and 1919.
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
2003] Origins of the FTC 7
or more.
20
Consolidation piled on consolidation, as the American
Tobacco Company, for example, absorbed what once had been 250
rms.
21
Enterprise assumed massive scale. United States Steel, formed in
1901, was capitalized at $1.4 billion (over $25 billion in current dollars).
22
According to Naomi R. Lamoreaux, at least 72 consolidations led to the
formation of entities that controlled over 40 percent of an industry, and
42 to entities that controlled over 70 percent.
23
Finally, as highlighted
by Congressional hearings and a muckraking book that Brandeis subse-
quently wrote in 1913, a so-called money trust had organized consolida-
tions across multiple industries, and its representation on multiple boards
of directors was perceived to create cross-industry interconnections short
of merger.
24
III. EARLY SHERMAN ACT JURISPRUDENCE
A. First Phase Cases
By 1899, the Supreme Court had established that the Sherman Act
broadly prohibited price-xing cartels, but the laws application to other
forms of interrm cooperation, and more importantly its application to
business consolidations, remained in doubt.
25
20
Naomi R. Lamoreaux, The Great Merger Movement in American Business: 1895
1904, at 12 (1985). Six consolidations united 5 or more rms in 1897. During the
succeeding ve years, the numbers were 16, 63, 21, 19, and 17, respectively. The number
of such consolidations dropped to 5 in 1903 and 3 the following year. Id. at 2.
21
Control of Corporations, Persons, and Firms Engaged in Interstate Commerce, Report of the
Committee on Interstate Commerce, U.S. Senate, 62d Cong., pursuant to S. Res. 98. at 1203
[hereinafter 1911 Hearings] (Brandeis testimony). See also Thorelli, supra note 9, at 304.
22
See Thomas K. McCraw & Forest Reinhardt, Losing to Win: U.S. Steels Pricing, Investment
Decisions, and Market Share, 19011938, 49 J. Econ. Hist. 593, 593 (1989) (noting possible
excess capitalization of 40%); Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, Consumer
Price Index, All Urban Consumers (May 16, 2003), available at ftp.bls.gov/pub/special.
requests/cpi/cpiai.txt (more than 18-fold increase in the CPI-U since the index began
in 1913).
23
Lamoreaux, supra note 20, at 2.
24
See Louis Brandeis, Other People’s Money and How the Bankers Use It (1913).
25
Important studies of the cases and thought of this period, as well as the legislative
history of the 1890 Sherman Act that these cases construed, include May, Reach, supra
note 18; James May, Antitrust in the Formative Era: Political and Economic Theory in Constitutional
and Antitrust Analysis, 18801918,50Ohio St. L.J. 257, 293300 (1989) [hereinafter May,
Theory]; Robert Lande, Wealth Transfers as the Original and Primary Concern of Antitrust:
The Efficiency Interpretation Challenged, 34 Hastings L.J. 65 (1982); Letwin, supra note 9;
Hovenkamp, supra note 15; Thorelli, supra note 9; Rudolph J.R. Peritz, Competition
Policy in America, 18801992: History, Rhetoric, Law (1996); Martin J. Sklar,
The Corporate Reconstruction of American Capitalism, 18901916 (1988); Alan
J. Meese, Liberty and Antitrust in the Formative Era,79B.U. L. Rev. 1 (1999).
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal8
The 1895 decision in United States v. E.C. Knight Co.
26
seriously under-
mined antitrust enforcement. By an 81 margin, the Court rejected a
challenge to the sugar trusts acquisitions of four Pennsylvania plants.
Although the trust obtained a 98 percent share of the national market,
the Court held that the Commerce Clause placed the transactions outside
federal law because they affected commerce only incidentally and not
directly. The trust was primarily engaged in manufacture, and [c]om-
merce succeeds to manufacture, and is not part of it.
27
Two years later, United States v. Trans-Missouri Freight Assn
28
became
the Courts rstcasetond a Sherman Act violation. The Court held
a railroad price-setting agreement unlawful. Speaking through Justice
Rufus Peckham, it declared that the law required free and open competi-
tionand forbade allcontracts in restraint of trade.
29
The majority also
articulated a rationale for the Sherman Act. Discussing combinations of
manufacturers, the Court found harmful those whose purpose . . . is to
control the production or manufacture of any particular article in the
market, and by such control dictate the price at which the article shall
be sold.
30
Even if a combination lowered prices, the Court explained,
danger lay in the power of the combination to raise it, and the result
in any event is unfortunate for the country, by depriving it of the services
of small but independent dealers . . . . (also termed small dealers and
worthy men).
31
Antitrust thus protected both consumers and competi-
tors from economic harm and, in protecting small dealers from economic
harm, simultaneously averted social harm.
32
Here, at least, the Court
reected a classical paradigm that, in James Mays words, deemed oppor-
tunity, efciency, competition, fair distribution, and political freedom to
be largely consistent and capable of vigorous implementation through
nondiscretionary judicial decisionmaking.
33
26
156 U.S. 1 (1895).
27
Id. at 12.
28
166 U.S. 290 (1897).
29
Id. at 328, 339.
30
Id. at 323. The Court also described combinations of manufacturers as having, for
this purpose, the same nature as combinations of railroads. Id. at 324.
31
Id. at 323, 324.
32
These social and industrial effects are similar to the two meanings that David W.
Barnes detects in references to what he calls entrepreneurial freedom: The rst would
protect small businesses in order to increase the freedom of individuals to be self-employed
and self-reliant and the second would protect small businesses in order to promote an
economic system that better satises consumer demands. David W. Barnes, Nonefciency
Goals in the Antitrust Law of Mergers,30Wm. & Mary L. Rev. 787, 841 (1989).
33
May, Theory, supra note 25, at 299 (emphasizing roots of the paradigm in both economic
and political thought). See also Hovenkamp, supra note 15 (emphasizing roots in economic
thought). Peckham here dismissed lower prices because of the threat that the combination
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
2003] Origins of the FTC 9
However, Trans-Missouri hardly suggested a settled state of law. First,
four Justices dissented in an opinion by Justice Edward White, who would
later author the Standard Oil decision. White argued that the Sherman
Act incorporated a common law meaning of restraint of trade, that
the common law allowed reasonable restraints, and that agreements to x
reasonable rates (including defendants agreement) were themselves
reasonable.
34
Second, qualifying the assertion that the Sherman Act pro-
hibited all contracts in restraint of trade, the Court acknowledged a
possible exception for covenants collateral to the sale of a business.
35
This raised the question of whether the law would reach the actual
contract to sell a businessthe core of merger activity. Third, the E.C.
Knight limits were undisturbed, since the Trans-Missouri defendants were
interstate railroads and reachable under a narrow reading of com-
merce. Indeed, drawing on E.C. Knight, the Court explained that a
violation resulted because the agreements direct, immediate and neces-
sary effect is to put a restraint on trade or commerce as described in
the act.
36
A year later, the Court further developed its directness test in three
decisions, all authored by Justice Peckham, that were delivered on the
same day. The only decision to nd a violation was another railroad
case. The 53 decision in United States v. Joint TrafcAssn
37
held unlawful
a railroad agreement whose natural and direct effect was to maintain
higher rates than otherwise would prevail.
38
Both Anderson v. United
States
39
and Hopkins v. United States,
40
in contrast, rejected challenges to
could later raise them. See Trans-Missouri Freight, 166 U.S. at 335 (prices might be lowered
to drive out rivals, in order that rates might thereafter be advanced). The decision
contains a more ambiguous reference to combinations that perhaps permanently reduce
prices by reducing the expense inseparable from the running of many different companies
for the same purpose. However, the Court went on to deem inevitable, if unfortunate,
the displacement of small dealers because of great industrial changes. Id. at 322. While
not entirely clear, the changes the Court deemed inevitable if unfortunate might include
all those based on efciencies.
34
Id. at 34357. White described the carrier agreement as securing fairness in their
dealings with each other, and tending to protect the public against improper discrimination
and sudden changes in rates. Id. at 357. See also Rudolph Peritz, The Rule of Reason in
Antitrust Law: Property Logic in Restraint of Competition,40Hastings L.J. 285, 31617 (1989)
(minority position grounded in the logic of property and a fair return on investment,
rather than competition).
35
Trans-Missouri Freight, 166 U.S. at 329 (such contracts might not be included within
the letter or spirit of the statute).
36
Id. at 34142.
37
171 U.S. 505 (1898).
38
Id. at 565.
39
171 U.S. 604 (1898).
40
171 U.S. 578 (1898).
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal10
association rules that governed livestock sales in Kansas City. None of
the rules was found to control price or output directly. The Court held
that some of the rules affected commerce that was not interstate, and
those that did affect interstate commerce had an effect that was remote,
small, and unintended.
41
Finally, the 1899 case of United States v. Addyston Pipe & Steel Co.
42
held
that the Sherman Act did reach a manufacturers cartel. The case came
to the Court with a prescient lower court opinion by William Howard
Taft, then a Circuit Court judge. Taft followed Whites Trans-Missouri
dissent in concluding that the statute incorporated common law limits
on restraint of trade, but, developing the Trans-Missouri majoritys
reference to constraints collateral to sales of property, Taft offered a
more nuanced view of the common law. The common law deemed a
restraint unreasonable if its sole object was to restrain prices, he wrote.
Even if those prices were reasonable, impropriety resulted from the
power to charge unreasonable prices. But if an agreement had a proper
purpose to which a restraint was ancillary for example, if it facilitated
sale of a business by limiting future competition by the sellerthe
restraint was lawful so long as it was no wider than needed. Taft essentially
distinguished naked restraints that were per se violations from ancillary
restraints that would be allowed only if reasonable.
43
However accurate Tafts reading of past law,
44
the Supreme Court did
not follow his lead. Its unanimous decision (like the circuit courts)
limited E.C. Knight, and applied the Sherman Act to a conspiracy among
manufacturers.
45
However, the Court found the pool illegal because its
41
In Anderson, cattle purchasers agreed to do business only with members of their
exchange, which was found to do no business of its own, not to meddle with prices, and
to be open to anyone following its rules. Anderson, 171 U.S. at 614. The Court held the
agreement was lawful even if it affected interstate commerce; seeking only transaction of
business upon a proper and fair basis, its effect on commerce was quite remote, not
intended and too small to be taken into account. Id. at 61819. In Hopkins, the Court
rejected most challenges to the practices of commission merchants on an exchange, relying
primarily on the E.C. Knight-like rationale that they were outside interstate commerce.
Hopkins, 171 U.S. at 597.
42
175 U.S. 211 (1899).
43
85 F. 271 at 27879, 28183, 293 (6th Cir. 1898).
44
Compare May, Theory, supra note 25, at 330 (a brilliant effort to extract analytically
coherent tendencies from the aggregate mass of nineteenth century American common
law precedent, despite understating toleration of nonancillary restraints), with
Hovenkamp, supra note 15, at 28687 (historically dubious, but facilitated laws develop-
ment), and Robert H. Bork, The Antitrust Paradox 26 (1978, 1993 ed.) (perhaps
the greatest antitrust decision ever).
45
The Court held that the Sherman Act reached independent manufacturers who agreed
to restrain interstate sales (even if it might not reach mergers of those same manufacturers).
Addyston Pipe, 175 U.S. at 23841.
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
2003] Origins of the FTC 11
direct and immediate effect was to destroy competition and raise prices
and, even under a directness test, it sidestepped Tafts conclusion that
an agreement would be unlawful if it xed reasonable prices.
46
B. Second Phase Cases
After Addyston Pipe (and though the decision left open an argument
that cartels could x reasonable prices), the Court reached a consensus
about price xing. Antitrust advocates during the rest of the formative
period might object that enforcement against cartels was inadequate
and ineffective,
47
but not about the substantive standards applied when
a cartel was challenged. The Court further showed its distaste for price
xing mere weeks before Standard Oil, when it condemned the vertical
restraints of resale price maintenance in Dr. Miles Medical Co. v. John D.
Park & Sons Co.
48
The Court ignited a separate controversy in Loewe v.
Lawlor,
49
a private action for treble damages that struck not at business
but at labor. The labor movements subsequent efforts to secure antitrust
exemptions bore fruit in the Clayton Act, but the labor story is peripheral
to the one told in this article.
50
The core antitrust concerns as Roosevelt took ofce, though, were
whether the law could deal with consolidations and the rms created by
past consolidations.
51
Consolidations implicated an owners right to sell
his business. With no merger case having reached the Court since E.C.
Knight, and with states unable to check corporate growth,
52
parties who
hesitated to cartelize may have even felt driven to the most extreme and
complete form of consolidation”—as when the Addyston Pipe defendants
merged after they lost in court.
53
46
Id. at 238 (nding the prices unreasonable), 247 (upholding the injunction, except
as applied to purely intrastate transactions).
47
1911 Hearings, supra note 21, at 182 (Samuel Untermeyer declaring that the country
was honeycombed with secret price-xing agreements).
48
220 U.S. 373 (1911).
49
208 U.S. 274 (1908).
50
See infra note 335 and accompanying text.
51
See John Bates Clark & John Maurice Clark, The Control of Trusts 4 (1912,
1914 reprint) (the public reconciled itself to pooling and contracts controlling prices,
though it did not make the payment altogether willingly. It was the appearance of
consolidations that were rmer and more complete that caused the menacing shadow of
general monopoly to deepen.).
52
See Charles McCurdy, The Knight Sugar Decision of 1895 and the Modernization of American
Corporate Law, 18691903,53Bus. Hist. Rev. 304 (1979) (arguing that states could have
used corporate law to prevent rms from joining out-of-state holding companies, but were
unwilling to drive away business); Hovenkamp, supra note 15, at 26264 (questioning
extent of states authority under corporate law).
53
See Federal Trade Commission, The Merger Movement: A Summary Report 89
(1948) (discussing Addyston Pipe); Tony Freyer, Regulating Big Business: Antitrust
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal12
1. Northern Securities Co. v. United States.
54
Northern Securities found that a holding company violated the Sherman
Act by taking control of two railroads that had previously competed.
However, the Court was split. Justice John Marshall Harlan, who had
been the sole dissenter in E.C. Knight and who would again become the
sole dissenter in Standard Oil, here spoke for a plurality of four Justices,
for whom the holding company was illegal for the simple reason that it
directly eliminated competition.
55
But Justice David Brewer, the critical
fth vote, relied on the nature of the railroad industry to nd the
consolidation unreasonable.
56
Finally, Justices White and Peckham
(authors of the Trans-Missouri decision and dissent) now united with two
other Justices in two dissents. The rst, by White, denied federal authority
to regulate ownership of stock in state-chartered rms.
57
The second,
by Oliver Wendell Holmes, Jr., literally and provocatively announced
that the Sherman Act says nothing about competition and did not
apply to fusions.
58
In 1904, four Justices thus deemed federal antitrust
irrelevant to mergers.
2. Standard Oil v. United States
59
and
United States v. American Tobacco Co.
60
The 1911 cases were decided by a dramatically changed Court. Taft
had been President only twenty-six months, but had named four new
Justices and elevated Justice White to Chief. On May 15, 1911, White
authored the Standard Oil decision that announced the rule of reason.
Two weeks later, White wrote the American Tobacco decision that reaf-
rmed it. Each decision was joined by all save Harlan.
Standard Oil declared that the Sherman Act proscribed only those
restraints that the common law made unenforceable, that the common
laws specics mattered less than its standard of reason, and that the
in Great Britain and America, 18801990, at 2635 (1992) (contrast to Britain, which
encouraged looser combinations). But see Alfred D. Chandler, Jr., The Visible Hand:
The Managerial Revolution in American Business 31544 (1977) (vertical integration
as basis for successful mergers); Sklar, supra note 25, at 15766 (noting large feasible
scale of American business, and intense, impersonal competition).
54
193 U.S. 197 (1904).
55
Id. at 33132.
56
Id. at 363 (under present conditions a single railroad is, if not a legal, largely a
practical, monopoly, and defendant holding company broadens and extends such
monopoly).
57
Id. at 36970.
58
Id. at 403, 410.
59
221 U.S. 1 (1911).
60
221 U.S. 106 (1911).
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
2003] Origins of the FTC 13
standard of reason condemned practices that led to the evils Taft had
identied in Addyston Pipe: the power to x price or to limit production
(or a related deterioration in quality).
61
In the language of freedom of
contract, the Act limited the freedom of contract by some to protect the
contractual freedom of others. A Sherman Act analysis would consider
whether conduct undermined this broadly understood right to contract,
but not whether the Act unreasonably undermined it;
62
White thus aban-
doned his prior view that cartels could x reasonable prices. Applying
the rule of reason, Standard Oil held that defendants 90 percent market
share, obtained after forty-one years of reorganizations, acquisitions,
unfair practices, and unfair methods of competition, justied a pre-
sumption of illegality. The facts reinforced the presumption.
63
3. The Reaction
The Standard Oil decision had been anxiously awaited, and its signi-
cance has been compared to such cases as Roe v. Wade.
64
Signaling business
satisfaction with the rule of reason, stock prices rose despite the Courts
dissolution order.
65
But William Jennings Bryan, three-time Democratic
Presidential nominee and spokesman for agrarian interests within the
party, declared The Trusts Have Won.
66
Five Senators, radical Demo-
crats and Republican insurgents, introduced bills to proscribe all con-
tracts, combinations and conspiracies in restraint of trade.
67
61
Standard Oil, 221 U.S. at 5152, 60. See also American Tobacco, 221 U.S. at 179 (law
forbade acts or contracts or agreements or combinations which operated to the prejudice
of the public interests by unduly restricting competition, or unduly obstructing the due
course of trade, or which, either because of their inherent nature or effect, or because
of the evident purpose of the acts, etc., injuriously restrained trade...).
62
Standard Oil, 221 U.S. at 62 (the freedom of the individual right to contract, when
not unduly or improperly exercised, was the most efcient means for the prevention of
monopoly ....[F]reedom to contract was the essence of freedom from undue restraint
on the right to contract), 69.
63
Id. at 4243, 75.
64
Asks Court to Hurry Antitrust Decision, N.Y. Times, May 13, 1911, at 1 (describing letter
that declared business at a standstill as it awaited the decision); Nathan Gaskill, The
Regulation of Competition 15 (1936) (startling conclusions aroused the country like
no decision since [Dred Scott v. Sandford, 60 U.S. 393 (1856)]; Peritz, supra note 25, at
61 (cases cultural signicance compared to Brown v. Board of Education, 347 U.S. 483
(1954), and Roe v. Wade, 410 U.S. 113 (1973)).
65
Business Likes Oil Decision, N.Y. Times, May 17, 1911, at 1; Decision Opens a New Era
Carnegie, N.Y. Times, May 17, 1911, at 6.
66
The Commoner, May 26, 1911, at 1. Bryan asked When did a court interpret a statute
against murder . . . on the theory that the legislature meant undue murder ...? Id. at
2. Though Whites decision was turgid, Bryan detected in it the triumphant strains of the
Battle Hymn of the Republic. William Jennings Bryan, The Reason, 194 N. Am. Rev. 10,
11 ( July 1911).
67
May Amend Sherman Law, N.Y. Times, May 16, 1911, at 4; S. 2158, S. 2370, S. 2374,
S. 2375, S. 2433, 62d Cong, 2d Sess. (1911), reprinted in 3 Bills and Debates in Congress
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal14
Critics often ignored the differences between Whites 1911 rule and
the rule he advanced in 1897; his authorship of both predisposed many
to equate them.
68
For example, Senator Cummins wrote in 1913 that the
Sherman Act had wisely incorporated common law limits on restraint of
trade. Properly understood, it reached such unreasonable restriction
of competition as impaired substantially, and to the public injury, the
freedom of trade or the freedom to trade,but not restrictions that left
the competitive force as an adequate protection to the people.
69
Cummins
equated the rule White sought in 1897 to the rule he announced in
Standard Oil, though, and said that both would allow not only a reason-
able interference with competition . . . which did not . . . constitute a
restraint of trade, but also a reasonable restraint of trade, that is, a
restraint the left the competitive force inadequately preserved.
70
Critics also cried judicial legislation. Harlan charged that his breth-
ren legislated by adopting the rule,
71
Cummins that they would legislate
in applying it. For Cummins, the law should allow some, but not great
latitude for difference of opinion upon . . an inquiry.
72
Standard Oil,
as he read it, would test each restraint by the economic standard which
the individual members of the court may happen to approve, and by
each Justices individual opinion as an economist or sociologist.
73
More
broadly, the perception was that the balance of power had shifted in
antitrust. Seven years after the Sherman Act passed, four Justices had
been willing to allow reasonable price-xing cartels. Seven years after
that, four Justices would have held that the Sherman Act had no applica-
tion to mergers. Although a bare majority had held in Northern Securities
that the law reached merger activity, seven more years had passed without
Relating to Trusts, 57th Cong., 2d Sess. to 63d Cong., 1st Sess., Inclusive, at
24112415. The insurgents included about ten Republican Senators [who] regularly
acted together on a whole range of national issues, meeting constantly to plan strategy
in private, openly defying the partys established leadership in public. James Holt,
Congressional Insurgents and the Party System, 19091916, at 23 (1967). They
largely represented a rural progressivism, rooted mainly in north-central agrarian states:
Wisconsin, Minnesota, Iowa, Kansas, Nebraska, and the Dakotas. Id. at 6, 9.
68
See Allyn Young, The Sherman Act and the New Anti-Trust Legislation: I,23J. Pol. Econ.
201, 204 (1915) (describing a very general impression that possibly even price agree-
ments were permissible, if the prices agreed upon were reasonable’”).
69
S. Rep. No. 1326, 62d Cong., 3d Sess. 2 (1913) [hereinafter Cummins Report] (noting
that common law was not always stated with exact accuracy). See also id. at 8 (nessing
question of how well prior decisions had accorded with his analysis).
70
Id. at 7, 9.
71
Standard Oil, 221 U.S. at 90.
72
Cummins Report, supra note 69, at 8.
73
Id. at 10, 11. For Nathan Gaskill, this was a Congressional declaration of war on the
Supreme Court. Gaskill, supra note 64, at 22.
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
2003] Origins of the FTC 15
systematic reversal of corporate growth. Now, antitrust plaintiffs seemed
to face a new hurdle.
Critics also condemned the remedies. Standard Oil and American
Tobacco shareholders each received shares in the rms successors.
74
Common ownership of the successors at least delayed the emergence
of effective competition.
75
The aggregate value of the oil trustss post-
dissolution stock soared,
76
so shareholders reaped a reward, while critics
like Brandeis deemed it offensive to even leave these rich breakers of
the laws of God and of man left in undisturbed enjoyment of all their
ill-gotten wealth.
77
To Roosevelt, the remedy made the Courts bitter
condemnation a farce.
78
IV. ROOSEVELT, TAFT, BRANDEIS, AND WILSON
The antitrust question was central to the 1912 Presidential race
between Roosevelt and Taft, who had already shaped antitrust policy,
and Wilson, whose turn was yet to come, with Wilson adviser Louis
Brandeis adding his own voice both publicly and privately. The four
were near-contemporaries, each born between 1856 and 1858. Each was
trained in law, though Roosevelt left law school and Wilson abandoned
its practice. Each brought a voice to the antitrust debate that would
resonate through 1914 and beyond.
A. Theodore Roosevelt
Roosevelts antitrust policy reected his broad activism. Born to wealth,
Roosevelt entered the disreputable world of New York politics after
graduating from Harvard. He was an adventurer, particularly in the face
of disappointment or tragedy.
79
His attainments were both scholarly and
74
Bureau of Corporations, Trust Laws and Unfair Competition 1621 (1915).
75
A contemporary observer, for example, said that formal dissolution was illusory as a
remedy, unless coupled with supervision which would prevent secret understandings from
taking the place of open combination .... Henry R. Seager, The New Anti-Trust Acts,30
Pol. Sci. Q. 448, 450 (1915).
76
See William E. Kovacic, Designing Antitrust Remedies for Dominant Firm Misconduct,31
Conn. L. Rev. 1285, 1299 (1999) (value increased 47% in a year, and nearly quadrupled
in six years).
77
1911 Hearings, supra note 21, at 1163.
78
Confession of Faith, supra note 1, at 254, 281 (remedy produced not one particle of
benet to the community at large; rather, prices went up to consumers, independent
competitors were placed in greater jeopardy than ever before, and the possessions of the
wrong-doers greatly appreciated in value).
79
He retreated west at age 25 when his wife and mother both died the day after his
daughters birth. He would undertake an African safari when he left ofce in 1909, and
charted an unexplored Brazilian river after the 1913 election.
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal16
political,
80
but the man of action predominated when he organized and
led the Rough Riders in the 1898 Spanish-American War. Roosevelts
fame in combat catapulted him to the New York governorship in 1899
and the Vice Presidency in 1901. When William McKinley was assassinated
seven months later, Roosevelt became Americas youngest President.
81
The Rough Riders included both Ivy Leaguers and cowboys, and Roose-
velt as President pursued what he deemed a conservative program to
resist class division.
82
He took pride in using every ounce of power there
was in the ofce . . . [I]n showing the strength of, or in giving strength
to, the executive, I was establishing a precedent of value.
83
1. The Skeptical Trust Buster
In antitrust, Roosevelts activism manifested itself in part through the
litigation that earned him the trustbuster sobriquet. McKinley had
brought three antitrust cases in more than four years. Roosevelt brought
forty-ve in less than eight.
84
His 1902 challenge to Northern Securities
announced a new turn in antitrust enforcement. His target was J.P.
Morgan, who, after spearheading the U.S. Steel megamerger, had worked
with his partner George Perkins to create the Northern Securities com-
pany.
85
Roosevelt also challenged the meat packers cartel (the beef
trust), Standard Oil, the American Tobacco Company, and DuPont (the
powder trust). He secured an appropriation earmarked for antitrust
80
Before 1898, Roosevelt held ofces as a New York City Police Commissioner, federal
Civil Service Commissioner, and Assistant Secretary of the Navy. With respect to his
scholarly attainments, compare John M. Blum, The Progressive Presidents 28 (1980)
(a historians sense of the past ...anamateur authority on military and naval tactics and
strategy . . . a creditable student of the biological sciences...) with Richard Hofstadter,
American Political Tradition 225 (1948) (a tissue of philistine conventionalities).
81
See generally Edmund Morris, The rise of Theodore Roosevelt (1979); David
Grubin & Geoffrey C. Ward, Theodore Roosevelt (PBS Home Video) (1997).
82
See, e.g., 1902 Annual Message to Congress, 15 Messages And Papers of the Presi-
dents (1917), 6709, 6711 [hereinafter Messages] (wise evolution a sure safeguard against
revolution). His response to a 1902 coal strike was revealing. His predecessors interven-
tions in labor disputes had all favored management. Roosevelt mediated and, when the
owners were intransigent, was prepared to seize the mines. Edmund Morris, Theodore
Rex 15569 (2001).
83
Roosevelt to George Otto Trevelyan, June 19, 1908, in 6 Letters of Theodore
Roosevelt 1085, 1087 (Elting Morrison ed.) [hereinafter TRL]. John Milton Cooper
termed Roosevelt a Dionysian artist of power, favoring the primacy of emotion in contrast
to Wilson, an Apollonian artist who favored the primacy of reason. John Milton Cooper,
The Warrior and the Priest 134 (1983).
84
United States, Federal Antitrust Laws 7182 (1926) [hereinafter Antitrust
Laws]. Although this source is useful to compare administrations, its raw numbers are
problematic. Parallel civil and criminal proceedings count twice, and at least two Roosevelt
cases challenged labor activity (items 39 and 40).
85
Letwin, supra note 9, at 18495.
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
2003] Origins of the FTC 17
enforcement, and created an antitrust unit within the Justice Department
in 1903.
86
But from the outset, Roosevelts cases were at least in part intended
to prove the governmentshis governmentsprimacy.
87
In 1899, he
deemed fear of trusts largely irrational.
88
In 1900, he declared attempts
to reverse concentration not one whit more intelligent than the medieval
bull against the comet.
89
In 1901, he said that much legislation directed
at the trusts would have been exceedingly mischievous had it not also
been entirely ineffective;he noted the need to confront global competi-
tion, and added that combination and concentration should be, not
prohibited, but supervised and within reasonable limits controlled.
90
2. The Bureau of Corporations
The rst step in implementing a new relationship between government
and business was a 1903 trust bill establishing a Department of Com-
merce and Labor, and within it a Bureau of Corporations.
91
As a rst
step, the Bureaus statutory authority was limited to collecting informa-
tion, using compulsory process as needed. The President could publicize
that information or base further legislative recommendations upon it.
92
The Bureau was soon buffeted, as William Kovacic noted with respect
to the Commission that succeeded it, by interactions with the President,
Congress, and the courts.
93
For example, though nothing in the law
creating the Bureau mentioned Congressional directives, its rst report,
86
1902 Message, 15 Messages, supra note 82, at 6712. Theodore P. Kovaleff, Introduction,
Symposium: In Commemoration of the 60th Anniversary of the Establishment of the Antitrust Division,
39 Antitrust Bull. 813, 814 (1994) (commemorating antitrusts elevation to status as
a division under an Assistant Attorney General). The units 5-year appropriation was
$500,000, and its average size was 5 lawyers under Roosevelt, rising to 18 under Wilson.
Temp. Nat. Econ. Comm., Investigation of Concentration of Economic Power,
Monograph No. 16, 76th Cong., 3d Sess. 23 (1940). Although U.S. Attorneys could
also bring cases, see, e.g., More Antitrust Workers, N.Y. Times, Sept. 20, 1913, at 5, and special
assistants were hired for specic cases, see, e.g., J.C. McReynolds, The New Preceptor for the
Trusts, N.Y. Times, Mar. 9, 1913, at 56, the Department handled massive litigation. The
Departments brief to the Supreme Court in the Standard Oil case, for example, was
1071 pages.
87
1905 Annual Message to Congress, supra note 82, at 6973, 697576 (moral effect
of the prosecutions). See also Letwin, supra note 9, at 183 (suits a way to shock voters
into recognizing the nature of the trust problem).
88
Roosevelt to Bellamy Storer, Sept. 11, 1899, 2 TRL, supra note 83, at 1068, 106869.
89
Annual Message, Jan. 30, 1900, in 15 TRW, supra note 1, at 30, 45.
90
1901 Annual Message to Congress, 15 Messages, supra note 82, at 6641, 664648.
91
Morris, Rex, supra note 82, at 196, 20607. See also 1901 Message, supra note 90, at 6649.
92
Act of Feb. 11, 1903, ch. 544, § 6, 32 Stat. 823.
93
See William E. Kovacic, The Federal Trade Commission and Congressional Oversight of
Antitrust Enforcement: A Historical Perspective,17Tulsa L.J. 587 (1982).
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal18
a study of the meat-packing industry, was directed by a House resolution.
94
Deputy Commissioner of Corporations Herbert Knox Smith doubted
the legality of the resolution, and also hesitated because the Justice
Department was already investigating the industry.
95
After the Bureau
obtained company documents, Roosevelt in fact directed the Bureau to
share les with Department litigators. The denouement was not happy.
The Bureaus dry report was widely criticized, and the court relied on
the information sharing to immunize individual defendants in the
litigation.
96
Subsequent Bureau studies were more successful. In particular, its
report on petroleum transportation found substantial rebating despite
existing anti-rebating law and recommended a legislative x that Con-
gress adopted.
97
The Bureau later completed a series of wide-ranging
reports, often in response to House or Senate resolutions.
98
3. The Bureau, Anti-Trust versus Unfair Competition,
and the 1908 Hepburn Bill
Pursuing Roosevelts vision of broader economic supervision, the
Bureau and the President soon recommended substantial expansion of
the agencys authority. For Roosevelt, the Sherman Act as then construed
was profoundly immoral, seeking to forbid honest men from doing
what must be done under modern business conditions . . . .
99
Afrma-
tiveprovisions should replace its prohibitions, and reasonable restraints
94
Report of the Commissioner of Corporations on the Beef Industry xviii (1905)
(resolution directing study). The FTC Act expressly provides for studies directed by Con-
gress. 15 U.S.C. § 46(d). See also 15 U.S.C. § 46a (1933 amendment requiring concurrent
resolution by both Houses).
95
Gerald Leinwand, A History of the United States Federal Bureau of Corpora-
tions (19031914) at 17374 (1962) (unpublished Ph.D. dissertation, New York Univer-
sity) (noting that the Secretary of Commerce and Labor directed the Bureau to proceed).
The Bureau had anticipated from the rst, though, that its information might be used in
litigation. Report of the Commissioner of Corporations 3536 (1904) (though the
Bureaus work was primarily directed to investigate business conditions as basis for
intelligent legislative action, evidence of illegality would be given to the President).
96
Arthur M. Johnson, Theodore Roosevelt and the Bureau of Corporations,45Miss. Valley
Hist. Rev. 571, 58083 (1959); United States v. Armour & Co., 142 F. 808 (N.D. Ill. 1906)
(nding Fifth Amendment immunity because defendants had provided information under
conditions amounting to compulsion); Letwin, supra note 9, at 24244.
97
See Report of the Commissioner of Corporations on the Transportation of
Petroleum xxvixxvii (1906); Johnson, supra note 96, at 58385.
98
Bureau reports included studies of the petroleum, tobacco, steel, and lumber indus-
tries, cotton exchanges, state taxation of corporations, water transportation, and water-
power development.
99
1907 Annual Message to Congress, 16 Messages, supra note 82, at 7070, 7074.
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
2003] Origins of the FTC 19
should be distinguished from unreasonable.
100
The Bureau of Corpora-
tions should regulate industry as the Interstate Commerce Commission
(ICC), created in 1887 and given authority to set maximum rates during
the Roosevelt years, regulated common carriers.
101
The Bureaus annual reports contributed to the development of
these plans. Its 1904 report distinguished anti-trust from unfair-
competition laws. The former futilely sought to maintain a condition
of competition; the latter accepted that combination was inevitable and
regulated methods of competition so that process would be attended
by as little injustice as may be.
102
To accomplish such regulation, Corpo-
rations Commissioner James R. Gareld suggested licensing or franchis-
ing corporations in interstate commerce (and considered, but found
serious impediments to, federal incorporation).
103
The Bureau continued
to advance such proposals in later years, albeit more tentatively after
Herbert Knox Smith succeeded Gareld as Commissioner.
104
These pro-
cedures, which in some variants would allow the government to deny
rms access to interstate commerce, were means that could be harnessed
to various ends. The Democrats in 1908 proposed registration as a way
to limit corporate size.
105
For the Bureau, such mechanisms were a way
to regulate, rather than dissipate, concentrated economic power.
In 1908, Roosevelt worked to develop an extensive regulatory plan
with Gareld, Smith, and the National Civic Federation (an association
of business, labor, and other leaders, including the ubiquitous Morgan
partner George Perkins).
106
The Federation sought procedures dramati-
cally to lessen antitrust exposure, including a rule of reason for all
transactions and advance approval for proposed transactions submitted
100
Special Message, April 27, 1908, in 16 Messages And Papers of the Presidents (1927
ed.), at 7189, 7194 (executive oversight should replace the occasional and necessarily
inadequate and one-sided action of the federal judiciary); Roosevelt to Seth Low, Apr.
1, 1908, 6 TRL, supra note 83, at 986, 987.
101
Most signicantly, the 1906 Hepburn Act (different from the 1908 Hepburn Bill,
discussed infra) empowered the ICC to replace existing rates, upon complaint, with reason-
able maxima. See generally Ari & Olive Hoogenboom, A History of the ICC: From
Panacea to Palliative 5152 (1976).
102
Report of the Commissioner of Corporations 4041 (1904).
103
Id. at 4647.
104
See Annual Report of the Commissioner of Corporations (1907) (publicity and
prompt efciency of . . . public opinionmight be an adequate substitute for licensing).
105
Their platform called for registration of corporations with a 25% market share and
a ban on those with a 50% share. Donald Bruce Johnson, Compiler, National Party
Platforms 144, 146 (1978 ed.).
106
See Sklar, supra note 25, at 205 n.35, 22885.
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal20
to the Bureau.
107
Roosevelt offered less carrot and more stick. The 1908
Hepburn bill provided for rms to voluntarily register and submit
contracts and consolidations to the Bureau.
108
The Bureau might disap-
prove a proposal (the statute did not mention approval), but even propos-
als that escaped disapproval might be challenged later; submitters,
however, would benet from a rule of reason in any subsequent chal-
lenge.
109
Perhaps most signicantly, though, existing arrangements by
registered rms would be immunized once a year had passed.
110
Despite
Roosevelts avowal that corporations would have to show they have a
right to exist,
111
the bill aroused intense opposition. Roosevelt soon
retreated.
112
4. Morgan, Perkins, and the Steel and Harvester Trusts
Roosevelt never precisely explained how his rule of reason would
distinguish good from bad. An important component may have been a
rms willingness to accept broad government oversight. His dealings
with Morgans good interests, which evolved through the ofces of
the Commissioner of Corporations, illustrate the nature and pitfalls of
the approach.
Morgan responded to the Northern Securities case by asking Roosevelt,
in the future, to resolve problems by sending your manto my man.
113
Roosevelt demurred at the time, but their relations soon improved.
Morgans U.S. Steel acted differently than other trusts, in part hoping to
forestall antitrust challenge.
114
By 1905, Roosevelt reached a gentlemens
107
NCF representatives wanted a rule of reason applied to all restraints of trade (and
that rule, like the rule in Whites Trans-Missouri dissent, likely would have allowed xing
of reasonable prices). They also sought blanket immunity for agreements submitted to
the Bureau that were not disapproved. Draft from Francis Lynde Stetson, Feb. 26, 1908,
James R. Gareld collection, Library of Congress, Box 128, File 45.
108
H.R. 19745, 60th Cong., 1st Sess. (1908), reprinted in 2 Bills and Debates, supra
note 67, at 206668, §§ 1, 4. Roosevelt said that every combination or agreement not
. . . approved should be treated as in violation of the law and prosecuted accordingly.
Special Message, supra note 100, at 7193. The (effectively) mandatory submission require-
ment in some ways anticipated the premerger notication provisions of the 1975 Hart-
Scott-Rodino Act. 15 U.S.C. § 18a.
109
H.R. 19745, supra note 108, § 1.
110
Id. § 4. If a registration was not cancelled within a year after the registration was
made, the amnesty would become effective a year after the bill became law.
111
Special Message, supra note 100, at 7193.
112
Arthur M. Johnson, Antitrust Policy in Transition, 1908: Idea and Reality,48Miss.
Valley Hist. Rev. 425, 42833 (1961). Sklar concludes that Roosevelt quickly realized
that the bill would fail, but developed it to inuence future deliberations. Sklar, supra
note 25, at 231.
113
Cooper, supra note 83, at 83; Letwin, supra note 9, at 20204.
114
Knowing that the rm lived in a fragile glass house, its managers coddled their
competitors, forbore to build a modern administrative structure for their own company,
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
2003] Origins of the FTC 21
agreementwith U.S. Steels Elbert Gary at a meeting arranged by Com-
missioner Gareld. The arrangement, later extended to Morgans Inter-
national Harvester, gave the targets a chance to correct problems without
court orders.
115
To Roosevelt the arrangement represented mutual recognition of
parallel interests, with the government predominant.
116
Still, when the
Attorney General considered suing International Harvester, Commis-
sioner Smith detected a practical question because Morgan interests
supported the advanced policy of the administration. After meeting
with Perkins and Smith, Roosevelt directed the Attorney General to see
them and not to sue without Presidential clearance.
117
The biggest ashpoint, though, occurred during a 1907 nancial
panic. Lacking a central bank (Wilson would create that in 1914), Roose-
velt turned to Morgan, even giving him federal funds to deposit in banks
as needed.
118
Morgan then proposed that U.S. Steel acquire Tennessee
Coal & Iron (TC&I) from an investment rm that was teetering on
bankruptcy. Concerned about the Sherman Act, though, he secured
Roosevelts acquiescence. The acquisition stabilized the stock market,
and to that extent served the public well.
119
But it also served Morgan
well.
120
TC&I became a campaign issue in 1908 and 1912, the subject of
a 1909 confrontation with Congress and 1911 legislative hearings with
Roosevelt as star witness, and part of the Taft Administrations 1911 suit
took special pains to issue informative annual reports, and often made their corporate
records publicsometimes even including their own cost data. McCraw & Reinhardt,
supra note 22, at 618.
115
Robert H. Wiebe, The House of Morgan and the Executive,65Am. Hist. Rev. 49,
5253 (1959).
116
Id.at55.
117
Johnson, Bureau of Corporations, supra note 96, at 58990; Roosevelt to Charles Joseph
Bonaparte, Aug. 22, 1907, 5 TRL, supra note 83, at 763.
118
Jean Strouse, Morgan 57497 (1999).
119
Id. at 58488; John A. Garraty, Right-Hand Man: The Life of George W. Perkins
21014 (1957).
120
See United States v. United States Steel Corp., 223 F. 55, 14850 (D.N.J. 1915), affd,
251 U.S. 417 (1920). Strouse asserts that TC&I had been so unprotable and ineptly
managed that it was excluded when U.S. Steel was formed, and that the trusts Elbert
Gary even resisted the purchase in 1908; once the decision was made to proceed with the
acquisition, though Morgan took care not to make it a commercial sacrice. Strouse,
supra note 118, at 58485. McCraw and Reinhardt, supra note 22, at 604, nd that U.S.
Steels investment and pricing strategy consistently sought to stabilize the industry, even
to the detriment of its market share, and the acquisition consistent with this approach.
Gabriel Kolko concludes that the acquisition increased the steel trusts reserves by 40%
and that the trust paid no more than a quarter of what TC&I was worth. Gabriel Kolko,
The Triumph of Conservativism 117 (1963).
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal22
against U.S. Steel.
121
TC&I was an object lesson in the risks of Roosevelts
approach, during years when Roosevelt became further associated with
Morgan interests in the public eye through his developing ties to George
Perkins. By 1912, Perkins became Executive Chairman of Roosevelts
Progressive Party.
122
Roosevelt left ofce in 1909. In the ush of his 1904 victory, he had
pledged not to seek reelection.
123
He picked Taft to succeed him, fought
for Tafts election, then embarked on a year-long African safari.
5. The New Nationalism and the 1912 Campaign
Upon Roosevelts return, he was disillusioned with Taft. Republicans
were split between progressive insurgents(like Senator Cummins) and
an old guard,
124
and Taft seemed increasingly beholden to the latter.
In 1912, Tafts Administration challenged Roosevelt by its suit against
U.S. Steel, based in part on the TC&I takeover.
125
Roosevelt, in turn,
challenged Taft for their partys nomination. After Roosevelt decisively
won the delegates selected in primaries but Taft secured the nomination,
Roosevelt mounted a challenge in the general election.
126
We stand
at Armageddon, he told the Progressive Party convention.
127
He then
pursued a vigorous challenge, although it soon became clear that his
121
Roosevelt to William Jennings Bryan, Sept. 8, 1908, 6 TRL, supra note 83, at 1259,
126061; Roosevelt to Kermit Roosevelt, Jan. 23, 1909, id. at 1480, 1481 & n.2 (reporting
that he had told Congress to press for TC&I documents only if they were ready to impeach
him); Hearings before the Committee on Investigation of United States Steel Corporation, H. Rep.
No. 12, at 136992 (1911) (testimony). The Taft Administration also publicized charges
about Roosevelts role in aborting litigation against International Harvester. Roosevelt Held
Back Trust Suit, N.Y. Times, Apr. 25, 1912, at 1; Asserts Roosevelt Did Aid the Trust, N.Y.
Times, May 18, 1912, at 2.
122
As New York Governor, Roosevelt named Perkins to a Palisades Interstate Park Com-
mission. Roosevelt to Perkins, May 18, 1900, 2 TRL, supra note 83, at 1301. In 1900,
Perkins played an intermediary role in convincing Roosevelt to accept the Vice-Presidency.
Roosevelt sought Perkinss views on trust-related speeches. After 1910, Perkins devoted
both money and time to Roosevelts causes and, later, his Progressive Party, continuing
his interest in the party even after Roosevelts own interest waned. Garraty, supra note
119, at 8384, 22123, 272352.
123
There was as yet no constitutional limit on a Presidents tenure. There was a traditional
two-term limitation, but its application was somewhat unclear in Roosevelts case. Never
before had a President taken ofce on the death of a predecessor and then won election
in his own right (although Roosevelt had served all but seven months of William McKin-
leys term).
124
See supra note 67.
125
Taft insisted that he did not see in advance the U.S. Steel pleadings that challenged
TC&I. George Mowry concludes that Taft deliberately avoided reviewing the documents.
George E. Mowry, The Era of Theodore Roosevelt and the Birth of Modern
America 28990 (1958).
126
Arthur S. Link, Woodrow Wilson and the Progressive Era 14 (1954).
127
Confession of Faith, supra note 1.
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
2003] Origins of the FTC 23
chances were slim. The Democrats choice of the progressive Wilson
made it unlikely that Roosevelt could draw sufcient Democratic votes
to win.
128
The campaign reached a dizzying crescendo when a would-be
assassin shot Roosevelt on October 14. With a bullet lodged near his
lungs and blood staining his shirt, he delayed treatment and delivered
an extended oration.
129
Roosevelts New Nationalism included a challenge to the judiciary.
Roosevelt did not see judges as decision makers who could apply the
law without using discretion.
130
He horried conservatives and even many
of his supporters by advocating popular recall of state judges or, in a
more moderate variant articulated by George Rublee (the future archi-
tect of Section 5), of state court decisions that struck down laws as
violating the federal Constitution.
131
Roosevelt now deemed the Sherman Act rural toryism,as antiquated
as the intlocks of Washingtons Continental.He sought a commission
whose regulation we should not fear, if necessary, to bring to the point
of control of monopoly prices, just as in exceptional cases railway rates
are now regulated. Its broad mandate would protect not only consumers,
but also shareholders and workers.
132
At his most extreme, his most statist-tending,
133
Roosevelt pointed
approvingly to German law governing a fty-four-rm potash cartel. The
law set quantities, maximum prices, and labor conditions, all subject to
biannual judicial evaluation. Roosevelt saw a model that the United
128
Roosevelt wrote, ...Ithink it probable at present that Wilson will win....However,
win or lose, the ght had to be made, and it happened that no human being could make
it except myself. Roosevelt to Horace Planchet, Aug. 3, 1912, 7 TRL, supra note 83, at
591, 593.
129
See Leader and the Cause, Oct. 14, 1912, 17 TRW, supra note 1, at 320. A biographer
said the speech would have made a superb dying declaration, and one cannot help
suspecting he was disappointed that the cup of martyrdom passed him by.Cooper, supra
note 83, at 202.
130
In 1908, he wrote that decisions of the courts on economic and social questions
depend upon their economic and social philosophy and too often represented a long
outgrown philosophy, which was itself the product of primitive economic conditions.
Special Message, supra note 100, at 7204.
131
See The Recall of Judicial Decisions, Apr. 10, 1912, 17 TRW, supra note 1, at 190. According
to John Garraty, Roosevelts threat to the judiciary was so serious that Tafts antitrust
prosecutions were a petty annoyance in comparison. Garraty, supra note 119, at 255.
See also Gerald Gunther, Learned Hand 20925 (1994); Marc Eric McClure, Earnest
Endeavors: The Life and Public Work of George Rublee 112 (2000) (unpublished Ph.D.
dissertation, George Washington University) (book publication forthcoming).
132
Theodore Roosevelt, The Trusts, the People, and the Square Deal, 99 Outlook 649, 653,
655, 656 (Nov. 18, 1911).
133
See Sklar, supra note 25, at 35.
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal24
States, using the Bureau of Corporations, could adapt to manage rms
like Standard Oil and avoid corporate dissolutions.
134
Dissolutions would
merely lead to collusion among successor rms; the better answer was
to [d]emand the right to know what theyre doing; if theyre doing
wrong, hit them; if they continue to do wrong, clap a receivership on
them, keep it on until theyre straightened out, and restore them to a
chastened ownership—fine, growing concerns, but growing in the right
direction.
135
Here, at least, he argued that bad trusts could be chas-
tened rather than dissolved. With proper regulation, he could even
tolerate a rm like U.S. Steel if it were an absolute monopoly.
136
In accepting the Progressive nomination, Roosevelt said that antitrust
has occasionally done good, has usually accomplished nothing, has
generally left the worst conditions wholly unchanged, and has been
responsible for a considerable amount of downright and positive evil. He
would make antitrust genuinely . . . effective against every big concern
tending to monopoly or guilty of antisocial practices, but also would
also use a commission to supplement (or supersede) antitrust. Protecting
Americas global competitiveness, the commission would have complete
power to regulate and control all the great industrial concerns engaged
in interstate business. It could stop labor, shareholder, and competitive
abuses, the latter including the articial raising of prices, the articial
restriction on productivity, [and] the elimination of competition by
unfair or predatory practices.Firms that voluntarilyaccepted its regu-
lation and obeyed its orders in good faith would be shielded from anti-
trust prosecution. The commission could also interpret in advance, to
any honest man asking the interpretation, what he may do and what he
may not do in carrying on a legitimate business.
137
The candidate was more popular than these ideas. Many who rallied
around him were drawn by his charisma, political viability, and other
134
Nationalism and Special Privilege, 97 Outlook 145, 147 ( Jan. 28, 1911). If a rm had
the power to “fix prices of labor and commodities, the government should regulate it
as freely as . . . so-called natural monopolies . . . I do not believe in a system of law in
which the object of Governmental proceeding requires the dissolution of the corporation
or the conscation of its property, which may be ruinous to the public as well as the
corporation. The proceeding should be, in substance, to declare any corporation an
injurious monopoly, and when that declaration shall be denitely afrmed by the proper
body, . . . to subject the corporation to thoroughgoing Governmental control as to rates,
prices, and general conduct. The supervision and control would be the same as that
which is, and still more as that which will be, exercised by the Inter-State Commerce
Commission over our railroads. Id. at 147.
135
Roosevelt to William Jennings Bryan, Oct. 22, 1912, 7 TRL, supra note 83, at 629, 630.
136
Id.
137
Confession of Faith, supra note 1, at 27980.
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
2003] Origins of the FTC 25
positions, not his plans to deal with concentration.
138
Consider Herbert
Knox Smith. Smith had grown so wary of regulation that in 1911 he
dampened Senator Newlandss support for positive directory powers
over industrials
139
yet, having remained Corporations Commissioner
under Taft, he resigned to work for Roosevelt. The antitrust issue even led
to a platform battle within Roosevelts own Progressive Party. Roosevelt
resisted proposed language calling for legislation to strengthen the
Sherman law (although he then called for such strengthening in his
acceptance speech). Party activists revised the platform after the
election.
140
Perhaps recognizing a tepid response to price regulation, Roosevelt
mufed the theme. But his words were carefully measured. After the
attempted assassination, he said of government orders to set price: I
do not want now to provide that. I fancy the commission would be so
busy for a time in enforcing laws that it would not want to concern itself
with prices.
141
For Roosevelt, modern industry depended on efciencies that ren-
dered competition, at least in some markets, obsolete. The government
should domesticate rather than limit size, and price regulation was (at
a minimum) a backstop for such domestication. Interrm cooperation,
presumably including price-setting cartels, should be tolerated under
government auspices.
142
Roosevelt feared neither big business nor big
government, trusting the latter to tame the former.
138
Holt, supra note 67, at 5253.
139
A week after Standard Oil, Smith wrote Gareld that he had persuaded Newlands to
drop such power, the really dangerous feature of [Newlandss] proposed commission,
from proposed legislation. Herbert Knox Smith to James R. Gareld, May 23, 1911, James
R. Gareld Collection, Library of Congress, Box 120. See generally Sklar, supra note 25,
at 30009; S. Rep. No. 597, 63d Cong., 2d Sess. 2732 2829 (1914) (quoting Smiths
view that agency should only have authority to deny a registration, so that rm could
not identify itself as registered).
140
The disputed language called for strengthening the Sherman law by prohibiting
agreements to divide territory or limit output; refusing to sell to customers who buy from
business rivals; to sell below costs in certain areas while maintaining higher prices in other
places; using the power of transportation to aid or injure special business concerns, and
other unfair trade practices. It was rejected as needless amplication by Roosevelt,
included when the platform was read at the convention, deleted from the text distributed
by the press, and restored in December. John Gable, The Bull Moose Years 10003
(1978) ; Garrraty, supra note 119, at 26870, 288; Roosevelt to Amos Pinchot, Dec. 5,
1912, 7 TRL, supra note 83, at 661, 66568.
141
Political Talks Tire Roosevelt, N.Y. Times, Oct. 20, 1912, at 1, 2.
142
The Hepburn bill of 1908 presumably would have allowed price-setting agreements.
Roosevelt likely agreed with the ruinous competition argument that Justice White
accepted in Trans-Missouri Freight. See supra note 34 and accompanying text.
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal26
6. The Legacy of 1912
Wilson won the electoral college in a landslide, with 42 percent of
the popular vote. Roosevelt ran better than Taft, receiving 27 percent
of the vote to Tafts 23 percent.
143
The vote was inuenced by factors
extraneous to competition policy, though, and may have understated
Roosevelts personal popularity but overstated the popularity of his eco-
nomic plans.
144
The charismatic ex-President was only fty-four in 1912, young enough
that he was exploring the uncharted River of Doubt in Brazil as Congress
geared up for the antitrust debate.
145
Though he died in January 1919,
he remained so powerful a presence that, despite his prior apostasy, he
had become a serious contender for the 1920 Republican nomination.
146
Yet despite Roosevelts personal popularity, most politicians, including
most Commission advocates, distanced themselves from his economic
program. Roosevelts calls for price-setting authority drew a practical
line, and his embrace of the most massive rms a theoretical line, that
others would not cross.
Still, there were potential convergences between Roosevelt and those
would not cross these lines. A commission could serve goals other than
Roosevelts, to prevent or help reverse the growth of monopoly power,
rather than to regulate its use. Substantively, many could join his call to
ban unfair practices (although they might differ on the specics of
unfairness). For their own reasons, Brandeis to some extent shared
Roosevelts admiration of German cartels (and Roosevelt likely would
have joined Brandeis in supporting resale price maintenance), and Wil-
son shared Roosevelts reluctance to dissolve existing rms.
147
Conversely,
Charles Van Hise, whom Roosevelt quoted on behalf of concentration,
co-operation and control,
148
was prepared to presume that a rm with
a 40 percent market share unreasonably restrained trade.
149
There was
a spectrum of possibilities and, along that spectrum, there was much
143
Socialist Eugene Debs received 6%. See also supra Part V.A.
144
Roosevelt likely lost votes because of the traditional two-term limit, for example, and
his bolting from the Republicans. His vote also may have been affected by his aggressive
foreign policy.
145
Joseph S. Ornig, My Last Chance to Be A Boy: Theodore Roosevelts South
American Expedition of 19131914 (1994). Roosevelt returned in May 1914.
146
Cooper, supra note 83, at 259, 33233. Roosevelt returned to the Republican fold
in 1916. Id. at 30506. In 1917, he implored Wilson for a military command in World
War I. Id. at 32435.
147
See infra text accompanying notes 212, 262.
148
See supra note 1.
149
Charles R. Van Hise, Concentration and Control 227 (1912, rev. 1914).
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
2003] Origins of the FTC 27
in Roosevelts program that others could accept. The challenge (and
opportunity) for the Democrats was to adapt his ideas to their own ends,
to associate with his progressivism while distancing themselves from its
most controversial ramications.
B. William Howard Taft
1. The Jurist as Reluctant President
Taft served before his Presidency as Solicitor General, circuit court
judge, Governor-general of the Philippines, and Secretary of War. After
his Presidency, he taught law at Yale (his alma mater) and, in 1921,
became Chief Justice. His Presidency was unsuccessful, his administrative
skills offset by political debacles.
150
He made no secret that he had not
wanted the job. Taft publicly called his 1908 candidacy a fall from the
respectable business of trying to administer justice.
151
He explained
his 1912 candidacy more poignantly. He responded to Roosevelts chal-
lenge, he said, because [e]ven a rat in a corner will ght.
152
It was the
law and the judicial role that he loved, and his faith in the courts and
their ability to implement the Standard Oil rule of reason was the key to
his view of antitrust policy.
2. President Taft and Antitrust
Tafts involvement with antitrust extended over four decades.
153
During
his Presidency, antitrust was emblematic of his problems. As Taft cap-
tured his own dilemma, he was in the remarkable position of being
charged with an attempt to destroy business by enforcing the anti-trust
statute and of having set up the Supreme Court to emasculate the statute
in the interests of the trusts.
154
As a judge, Tafts Addyston Pipe decision contained the seeds of later
antitrust jurisprudence. In 1906, while a member of Roosevelts cabinet,
Taft vaguely approved of federal action, where there was a probability
150
Robert H. Wiebe, Businessmen And Reform: A Study of the Progressive Move-
ment 68 (1963) ; Cooper, supra note 12, at 151.
151
Judith Icke Anderson, William Howard Taft: An Intimate History 111 (1981).
Both Roosevelt and Tafts wife were more anxious to see Taft President than he was.
152
Taft in Maryland Trails Roosevelt, N.Y. Times, May 5, 1912, at 1. See generally 2 Henry
Pringle, The Life and Times of William Howard Taft 78283 (1939).
153
He was Acting Attorney General for the governments rst antitrust case in 1890, United
States v. Jellico Mountain Coke and Coal Co., 43 F. 898 (M.D. Tenn. 1890). He participated in
the Supreme Courts antitrust decisions through the 1920s.
154
Taft Will Enforce Law to the Letter, N.Y. Times, Oct. 28, 1911, at 1.
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal28
of abuse, to assume control, not by way of initiation and administration
but by way of effective regulation.
155
As President, Taft pursued an active agenda of antitrust cases. His
targets included U.S. Steel, International Harvester, and the Motion
Picture Patent Company. Ending a dearth of prosecutions against trade
association rules after Hopkins and Anderson,
156
the administration chal-
lenged a rule of the Chicago Board of Trade.
157
Roosevelt had averaged
less than six antitrust cases per year; Taft averaged twenty.
158
Taft
brought fty-eight cases in just twenty-two months after Standard Oil.
159
More than a dutiful prosecutor, Taft called the Sherman Act agood
law that ought to be enforced.
160
He staunchly defended Standard Oil,
a case decided by a Court he had shaped by naming four Justices and
elevating White to Chief. After initial hesitation, Taft decided that the
rule of reason the Court announced in 1909 was more like his own
Addyston Pipe test than it was like the rule of reason White had advocated
in Trans-Missouri.
161
This rule, Taft said, incorporated a common law so
155
William Howard Taft, Four Aspects of Civic Duty 12 (1906). Taft, who declared
the topic too complex to explore at that time, explained that he still approved the laissez
faire doctrine that the least interference by legislation with the operation of natural laws
was, in the end, the best for the public”—but only if the doctrine is not carried to such
an extreme as really to interfere with the public welfare. Id. at 1112.
156
See supra text accompanying notes 3941.
157
The rule, which required after-hour sales to be at the same price as the last pre-close
sale, was later upheld in a decision by Justice Brandeis. Board of Trade of the City of
Chicago v. United States, 246 U.S. 231 (1918).
158
See Antitrust Laws, supra note 84, at 83105. This counts as separate cases several
parallel civil and criminal cases, and also includes at least four prosecutions of labor
activities (items 38, 41, 42, and 75).
159
Id. at 88105 (noting 18 cases after the 1912 election); Sklar, supra note 25, at 376.
Senator James Reed had a jaded view of these numbers. [T]here are now pending 46
cases, whereas we are told that there are over a thousand trusts and monopolies in the
United States....There ought to be 400 cases. 51 Cong. Rec. 14,51920 (1914). The
increased enforcement after Standard Oil might have been an attempt to prove Standard
Oil was compatible with vigorous enforcement, as William Jennings Bryan charged that the
rule of reason undermined antitrust and Roosevelt that antitrust undermined the economy.
160
Pringle, supra note 152, at 656.
161
1911 Annual Message to CongressPart 1, Messages and Papers of the Presidents
7644, 764546. Tafts early reactions to Standard Oil were captured by two headlines. On
May 16, focusing on the verdict, the New York Times called the President please[d].
Standard Oil Must Dissolve in a Month, Only Unreasonable Restraints of Trade Forbidden, N.Y.
Times, May 16, 1911, at 1. The next day, focusing on the rule of reason, it headlined a
different message. President Disappointed, N.Y. Times, May 17, 1911, at 1. Before Standard
Oil, White had equated the Courts directness test to his own ancillary restraints test and
criticized Whites 1897 rule of reason. Special Message ( Jan. 7, 1910), 17 Messages, supra,
at 7441, 745254. Cf. Cline v. Frink Dairy Co., 274 U.S. 445 (1927) (Taft, C.J.) (state law
allowing xing of prices if they were reasonablethe result White advocated in 1897
was unconstitutionally vague).
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
2003] Origins of the FTC 29
clear that courts would need no discretion to apply it.
162
There was
neither judicial legislation in declaring the rule, nor would there be in
applying it.
Believing the law sound and clear and responding to twenty years of
lawlessness,
163
Taft had little sympathy for violators. He privately called
Wall Street, as an aggregation, . . . the biggest ass that I have ever run
across.
164
In the ush of Standard Oil, Taft (unlike Roosevelt or Wilson)
embraced corporate restructuring. In September 1911, four months after
the decision, he called it a signal for the voluntary breaking up of all
combinations in restraint of trade within the inhibition of the statute,
and hoped it would lead to a complete revulsion of feeling on the part
of the business men of the country and to a clear understanding by
them of the limitations that must be imposed by them upon any business
combinations made by them in the future.
165
Tafts speech acknowl-
edged that some consolidations produced efciencies, but, in language
he may not have delivered, the printed text promised wholesale reorgani-
zations, by litigation if needed, within eighteen months.
166
President Taft also called for national incorporation, but his calls were
equivocal. In 1910, he deemed it a way to prevent harms, rather than
correct them after the fact, when correction would burden employees,
stockholders, and business condence.
167
Taft also saw federal incorpora-
tion as a way to protect business from undue state interference.
168
162
1911 Message, supra note 161, at 7646.
163
Taft Will Enforce Law to the Letter, supra note 154.
164
Pringle, supra note 152, at 655. As to an indicted executive, He violated the law
and has to pay the penalty for it. That is all! Id. at 656. Despite such comments, the only
defendants incarcerated on Tafts watch were members of a longshoremans association,
each conned for four hours. U.S. v. Haines (S.D. Fla. 1911), cited in Antitrust Laws,
supra note 84, at 9394; Richard A. Posner, A Statistical Study of Antitrust Enforcement,13
J.L. Econ. 365, 391 (1970) (all Sherman Act imprisonments until the 1920s were in labor
cases, and all until the 1960s were in cases involving labor or violence).
165
Sept. 18, 1911 Speech, supra note 3, at 5859.
166
Id. at 59. The printed text says: if Congress shall continue needed appropriations,
every trust of any size that violates the statute will, before the end of this administration
in 1913, be brought into court to meet and acquiesce in a degree of disintegration by
which competition between its parts shall be restored and preserved under the persuasive
and restrictive inuence of a permanent and continuing injunction. However, a line
appears above this passage and a series of xs through it. Further, no such remark appears
in a Wall Street Journal report or a New York Times report that quoted much of the speech.
Trust Decisions Defended by Taft, N.Y. Times, Sept. 19, 1911, at 5; Taft Opposed to Any Amendment
of Sherman Anti-trust Law, Wall St. J., Sept. 19, 1911, at 1.
167
1910 Special Message, supra note 161, at 745558. See also Sept. 18, 1911 Speech,
supra note 3, at 60 (describing federal incorporation as a way, if constitutional issues could
be resolved, to free rms from the constant fear of prosecution).
168
1910 Special Message, supra note 161, at 7456. See also Stanley I. Kutler, Chief Justice
Taft, National Regulation, and the Commerce Power, 51 J. Am. Hist. 651 (1965) (tracing
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal30
However, while the grant of a corporate charter presumably would consti-
tute approval of the chartered rms structure, Taft rejected Roosevelts
plans that an agency be empowered to approve subsequent conduct in
advance.
169
Further, shortly after he proposed national incorporation,
he declared that he had merely suggested it, and it was not a party
matter because it fell outside the 1908 platform.
170
There were other indicia of Tafts preference for judicial resolution
of disputes. The Bureau of Corporations, the framework for Roosevelts
regulatory plans, suffered leaner years under Taft, and for Commissioner
Smith the years were particularly lean.
171
Taft also showed his preference
for limiting administrative agencies by obtaining a Commerce Court,
created by the 1910 Mann-Elkins Act. That law generally strengthened
the ICC, but Taft insisted that it create a specialized court to hear appeals
from ICC decisions, succeeding over strenuous opposition by Senator
Cummins and others who feared that the court often would rule against
the agency. Those fears would be vindicated, and the court was abolished
in 1913.
172
Tafts efforts on behalf of the Court showed, despite his
nominal support of national incorporation, his continued hesitancy
about administrative decision making.
3. 1912 and Beyond
Although he defeated Roosevelt for the Republican nomination, Taft
entered the general election campaign demoralized and rarely gave
speeches.
173
Also, his ambiguous support of administrative regulation
Tafts support of broad federal powers from Addyston Pipe to decisions he authored as
Chief Justice).
169
1911 Message, supra note 161, at 7655 (consultations would offer [a rm] as great
security against successful prosecutions . . . as would be practical or wise).
170
Speech, Feb. 12, 1910, Presidential Addresses and State Papers of William
Howard Taft 568, 582 (1911). His private pronouncements sometimes (but not always)
evinced a lack of interest. James C. German, Jr., The Taft Administration and the Sherman
Antitrust Act, 54 Mid-America 172, 18384 (1972).
171
Wiebe, House of Morgan, supra note 115, at 58. Wiebe concludes that the Secretary of
Commerce bypassed Smith to press investigations of Morgans U.S. Steel and International
Harvester, working directly with Smiths subordinates, and that Smith wielded no
power. Id.
172
Shortly before the Mann-Elkins Act, the Supreme Court began to accord more defer-
ence to the ICC. See generally Robert L. Rabin, Federal Regulation in Historical Perspective,38
Stanford L. Rev. 1189, 123334 (noting that the once beleaguered agency was suddenly
granted the respect it had long sought, particularly in the pivotal case of ICC v. Illinois
Central Railroad Co., 215 U.S. 452 (1910)). With a former ICC Chairman as Chief Judge,
the Commerce Court was a brake on the ICC; it frequently reversed agency rulings, though
its own rulings often were reversed in turn by the Supreme Court. Elizabeth Sanders,
The Roots of Reform 20309 (1999); Hoogenboom & Hoogenboom, supra note 101,
at 61, 64, 6668.
173
See Pringle, supra note 152, at 81542.
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
2003] Origins of the FTC 31
now took a new twist. The Republicans gave him a platform that called
for a trade commission with enforcement authority.
174
Later years showed the extent to which Tafts more fundamental com-
mitment was to the judicial process and not to the structural remedies
he endorsed as President.
175
Unlike progressives who distrusted Lochner-
era courts, Taft said in 1911, I love Judges and I love courts. They are
my ideals on earth that typify what we shall meet afterward in Heaven
under a just God.
176
He admitted in 1911 that courts were slow and
their penalties lax in antitrust cases,
177
but in a series of 1914 articles,
later collected in a book, he defended the Courts decisions under the
rule of reason and dismissed the need for new antitrust laws.
178
Perhaps Tafts enthusiasm for dissolution in September 1911 began
to wane when the remedial talks in American Tobacco proved problematic,
and the order issued in November drew heavy criticism.
179
By 1914, Taft
would discern in the complexities of dissolutions a reason to prefer
judicial resolution of antitrust questions; the courts’“elastic and many-
sided remedies could squeeze the unlawfulness out of a trust and retain
for the benet of society those features of it that great business energy
and genius have created and that can be continued entirely within the
law.
180
Taft also shifted gears in defending United States v. Terminal
174
In the enforcement and administration of Federal Laws governing interstate com-
merce and enterprises impressed with a public use engaged therein, there is much that
may be committed to a Federal trade commission, thus placing in the hands of an adminis-
trative board many of the functions now necessarily exercised by the courts. This will
promote promptness in the administration of the law and avoid delays and technicalities
incident to court procedure. Johnson, Platforms, supra note 105, at 183, 184.
175
See Sklar, supra note 25, at 35 (focusing on Tafts preference for a judicial mechanism
to associate him with a minimalist regulatory corporate liberalism on the center-right).
176
Taft Again Defends the Supreme Court, N.Y. Times, Oct. 7, 1911, at 6.
177
Sept. 18, 1911 Speech, supra note 3, at 59. See also Taft, Four Aspects, supra note
155, at 5253 (antitrust defendants can secure the most acute counsel and make every
possible point that the looseness of the present criminal procedure affords).
178
William Howard Taft, The Anti-Trust Act and the Supreme Court (1914).
The articles appeared weekly in the New York Times between May 17 and June 14, 1914.
Taft defended the rule of reason as so clear that any one who gives it sincere attention
can understand. Id. at 5. He called the Court as progressive as possible, said those
who denied it speak in ignorance, and declared that Standard Oil brought out the
condemnation of everybody of demagogic tendencies prominent in politics. Id. at 5, 42, 94.
179
Taft defended the order, calling it the most effective for its purpose in the history
of American law. 1911 Annual Message, Part 1, supra note 161, at 7649. See generally id.
at 764751; Taft, Anti-Trust Act, supra note 178, at 11825. However, the tobacco
dissolution proved more complex than that of Standard Oil, which had been so structured
that component entities could simply be broken off the holding company. Attorney General
George Wickersham was particularly frustrated with the process. See German, supra note
170, at 17884.
180
Taft, Anti-trust Act, supra note 178, at 11718.
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal32
Railroad Assn of St. Louis.
181
The Court rejected his administrations
request to dissolve a joint venture by which some railroads passing
through St. Louis controlled all Mississippi River crossings, imposing
instead a strong conduct remedy that required defendant to treat every
railroad equally. Although his administration had sought structural relief,
Taft cited the case to show how the remedial processes of equity can
effect exactly the right result.
182
Tafts fundamental commitment was to enforcing the Sherman Act
under a rule of reason. As noted above, a classical paradigm assumed
that opportunity, efciency, competition, fair distribution, and political
freedom were largely consistent and capable of vigorous implementa-
tion through nondiscretionary judicial decision making.
183
When the
growth of large-scale corporations produced an anomaly by seeming to
create tension between efciency and other values, including opportu-
nity, many politicians (far more than the economists of the day) clung
to the hope that antitrust could still accommodate all these goals without
necessitating trade-offs.
184
Roosevelt did not. He deemed large-scale busi-
ness, even to the extent of monopoly, a natural product of economic
evolution, and he embraced a new paradigm less dependent upon a
competitive market. Taft held to the old. Though he acknowledged that
modern production would increase corporate size, he thought that much
existing growth could be reversed without sacricing efciency. More
fundamentally, and although he muddied the message with his half-
hearted support of national incorporation, Taft trusted the courts as
Roosevelt had not. He afrmed that questions of economic concentra-
tion could be resolved by non-discretionary judicial decision making, as
courts interpreted the Sherman Act under a common law that Taft
himself had helped to explicate.
C. Louis D. Brandeis
1. Peoples Attorney and Presidents Adviser
As Roosevelt touted the virtues of (controlled) trusts, Louis Brandeis
was an advocate for a small-business community that could not protect
181
224 U.S. 383 (1912).
182
Taft, Anti-trust Act, supra note 178, at 101. Senator James Reed had a different
view of the case, condemning the decision for allowing the survival of a miserable monop-
oly whose extortionate rates had stied growth on the citys western bank. 51 Cong.
Rec. 15,865 (1914).
183
May, Theory, supra note 25, at 299.
184
May points out that politicians acted like scientists who, confronting anomalous data,
seek to integrate it into their existing paradigm. Id. at 294. See also Thomas S. Kuhn, The
Structure of Scientific Revolutions ch. 6 (2d ed. 1970).
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
2003] Origins of the FTC 33
itself from unfair practices.
185
Brandeis was born in Kentucky. His immi-
grant father was a successful small businessman, although the family
relocated to Germany for three years during an economic downturn.
Returning to America, Brandeis attended Harvard Law School, graduat-
ing rst in his class in 1877.
186
He had practiced law for thirty-ve years
when he met Wilson in 1912, and his career then extended twenty-seven
more years, all but four on the Supreme Court. He began to represent
public causes in the 1890s, moving to national triumphs before the ICC
and Supreme Court after 1908.
187
Entering the antitrust debate after
Standard Oil, Brandeis helped draft legislation for progressive Republican
Robert La Follette, and testied for three days before a Senate committee
about the bill and antitrust.
188
Brandeis supported La Follettes bid for the 1912 Republican nomina-
tion, and his subsequent endorsement of Wilson was itself newsworthy.
189
Scott James concludes that Wilson responded to Brandeis in order to
appeal to progressive supporters of La Follette and former Democratic
nominee William Jennings Bryan.
190
Whatever Wilsons motives, he met
Brandeis for three hours on August 28, after which they held a joint
press conference.
191
They met again on September 27, after which Wilson
telegraphed Brandeis for advice on how to better spike the enemy
guns.
192
Brandeis spoke and wrote on Wilsons behalf, and gave Wilson
185
Interstate Trade Commission, Hearings Before the Comm. on Interstate and Foreign Commerce,
House of Representatives, 63d Cong., 2d Sess. (1914), at 98.
186
Phillipa Strum, Louis D. Brandeis, Justice for the People 114 (1984).
187
His Brandeis Briefconvinced the Supreme Court to uphold a law limiting the hours
women could work. Muller v. Oregon, 208 U.S. 412 (1908). The Court earlier had struck
down a New York law limiting bakershours, see Lochner v. New York, 198 U.S. 45 (1905),
but Brandeis cited state and foreign laws, and evidence from social and economic studies,
to persuade the Court that Oregons law was within the states police power (and thus
did not unconstitutionally restrict liberty of contract). Brandeiss reputation grew when
he joined a challenge to the Taft Administrations conservation policy (the Ballinger-
Pinchot affair), and in 1910 convinced the ICC to deny a general railroad rate increase
on the basis that railroads could use scientic management to lower costs. Strum,
Justice, supra note 186, at 13345, 16066.
188
Brandeis to Wilson, Sept. 30, 1912, 25 PWW, supra note 5, at 289; 1911 Hearings,
supra note 21, at 1146.
189
Brandeis for Wilson, N.Y. Times, July 11, 1912, at 1.
190
See Scott James, Presidents, Parties and the State: A Party System Perspective
on Democratic Regulatory Choice, 18841936, at 15859 (2000). Brandeis continued
to advise La Follette in 1913. Brandeis to La Follette, May 27, 1913, 3 LBL, supra note 4,
at 10002. La Follette sought Brandeis as a running mate when he ran a third-party
Presidential campaign in 1924. Strum, supra note 186, at 157.
191
Gov. Wilson Agrees with Mr. Brandeis, N.Y. Times, Aug. 29, 1912, at 3 (calling Brandeis
a lawyer-economist).
192
Telegram, Wilson to Brandeis, Sept. 27, 1912, 25 PWW, supra note 5, at 272.
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal34
a tactical opening and live ammunition.
193
Wilson adopted his rallying
cry that competition, not monopoly, should be regulated. But though
Wilson would seek Brandeiss counsel, consider naming him Attorney
General, offer him a seat on the FTC,
194
and eventually nominate him to
the Supreme Court, Wilson never fully embraced Brandeiss philosophy.
Brandeis had an aversion to big business that Wilson did not fully share,
and Wilson had a distrust of experts that Brandeis did not fully share.
2. Brandeis and Competition
Though Brandeis advocated smaller scale in business, he knew that
some businesses required substantial scale. He conceded in 1911 that a
rm could control considerably more than 10 percent of any market,
irrespective of absolute size, with perfect safety.
195
Yet, by supplement-
ing and interpreting the antitrust law, and creating presumptions to bias
its application, Brandeis sought to redress a balance that, to his eyes,
unduly favored large enterprise.
196
He tried to recapture, to the extent
possible, a past in which business was dominated by smaller merchants
like his father.
Brandeis backed his preference with economic arguments. The econ-
omies of monopoly are supercial and delusive, he wrote, and [t]he
efciency of monopoly is at best temporary.
197
The failure of some
trusts proved the inefciency of all.
198
Size dulled the competitive edge,
193
Cooper, supra note 83, at 194 (tactical opening); Strum, supra note 186, at 199202
(speeches, as well as articles and unsigned editorials that appeared in Colliers).
194
1929 Interview, Ray Stannard Baker collection, Library of Congress, Reel 72.
195
1911 Hearings, supra note 21, at 1175 (10% gure). Also, despite his sympathy for
small retail shops, Brandeis praised the owners of Filenes, a large Boston department
store, as great merchants. Louis Brandeis, Business A Profession 10 (1912), reprinted in
Louis Brandeis, BusinessA Profession (1914) (noting, for example, the stores pro-
gram for worker participation in management). See also Gerald Berk, Neither Markets Nor
Administration: Brandeis and the Antitrust Reforms of 1914,8Stud. Am. Pol. Dev. 24, 3335
(1994) (noting in particular work on public utilities regulation after 1903).
196
Cf. New State Ice Co. v. Liebmann, 285 U.S. 262, 31011 (1932) (Brandeis, J., dissent-
ing) (describing need for legislative experimentation in the elds of social and eco-
nomic science).
197
Louis Brandeis, Shall We Abandon the Policy of Competition? (Feb. 1912), reprinted in
Louis Brandeis, The Curse of Bigness 104, 105 (1934). See also 1911 Hearings, supra
note 21, at 114751; Louis D. Brandeis, The Democracy of Business, 2 Nations Business
31, 32 (Feb. 16, 1914) (limit of efciency is reached at a fairly early stage); To Prevent
Discrimination in Prices and to Provide for Publicity of Prices to Dealers and the Public, Hearings
Before the Committee on Interstate and Foreign Commerce, House of Representatives, 63d Cong.,
2d and 3d Sess. 41 [hereinafter 1915 Hearings] (department stores quickly passed point
of efciency).
198
1911 Hearings, supra note 21, at 1148. This aspect of Brandeiss thought is at the
root of a critique by Thomas McCraw. Thomas McCraw, Prophets of Regulation
95101 (1984).
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
2003] Origins of the FTC 35
blunting innovation and resulting in inferior goods; Brandeis blamed
U.S. Steel for inadequate products that hurt America in global markets.
199
He discounted any efciencies that huge rms did obtain because he
denied they led to reduced consumer prices.
200
Monopolies were articial
and unnatural; corporate dissolutions removed a cancer from the body
industrial.
201
Brandeiss concerns further extended to social efciency.
202
He
believed that competition policy should encompass individuals as produc-
ers as well as consumers. Brandeis aimed another attack at the steel trust
for eighty-four-hour work weeks, and for subjecting employees to alifeso
inhuman as to make our former Negro slavery innitely preferable . . .
203
[T]he right to life guaranteed by our Constitution is now being inter-
preted according to demands of social justice and of democracy as the
right to live, and not merely to exist. In order to live men must have
the opportunity of developing their faculties; and they must live under
conditions in which their faculties may develop naturally and health-
fully.
204
Defending resale price maintenance in 1915, he said:
The public interest is made up of a number of things. . . . [T]he
consumer . . . should get a good article at the lowest price that he
reasonably can, consistently with good quality and good business. . . .
But there is another interest that the public has,...theinterest of the
rest of the public, the dealer and his clerks and the producer and his
employees. We are all part of the public and we must nd a rule of
law that permits a business practice which is consistent with the welfare
of all the people.
205
Even more broadly, an efcient rm might be too large to be tolerated
among the people who desire to be free.
206
Brandeiss opposition to
199
1911 Hearings, supra note 21, at 115051. See also Louis Brandeis, Competition (1913),
reprinted in Brandeis, Curse, supra note 197, at 112, 118. Brandeis singled out U.S. Steel
because of its association with Roosevelt and Perkins. Perkins had testied immediately
before Brandeis in the 1911 hearings, and much of Brandeiss testimony was a rebuttal.
200
1911 Hearings, supra note 21, at 1157.
201
Competition, supra note 199, at 116.
202
1911 Hearings, supra note 21, at 1151.
203
Louis Brandeis, Big Business and Industrial Liberty (1912), reprinted in Brandeis, Curse,
supra note 197, at 38.
204
Louis Brandeis, Efciency and Social Ideals (1914), reprinted in Brandeis, Curse, supra
note 197, at 51.
205
1915 Hearings, supra note 197, at 1011. Cf. Board of Trade of the City of Chicago
v. United States, 246 U.S. 231 (1918) (Brandeis, J.) (using multifaceted analysis to identify
benets of a trading rule found to have no appreciable effect on volume or price).
206
1911 Hearings, supra note 21, at 1174. Cf. Louis K. Liggett Co. v. Lee, 288 U.S. 517,
568 (1933) (Brandeis, J., dissenting) (targeted state tax might reect not merely attempt
to preserve competition, but the view that the chain store, by furthering the concentration
of wealth and of power and by promoting absentee ownership, is thwarting American
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal36
concentrated economic power led to his special concern that with the
money trust of nanciers with wide-ranging corporate interests.
207
When asked, Brandeis had positive words for German cartels. Even
when a cartel set prices and limited output of unnished goods (the
cartel at issue left manufacturers free to turn as much product into
nished goods as they chose), it left smaller enterprises absolutely inde-
pendent as to internal management. The cartel leaves competition
freethat is, you have competition in production.
208
Their shared admi-
ration for German cartels was one area where the views of Brandeis and
Roosevelt, for differing reasons, converged. Despite these words of praise,
though, Brandeis was uncertain that cartels advanced German prosperity
and, when asked if he supported horizontal agreements to divide markets
and x prices in the United States, he seemed to require more than a
competition in production. Brandeis in 1911 conceded only that a
state of affairs might arise under which it might be necessary, in order
to preserve competition, to allow some kind of trade agreements.
209
Brandeis was more enthusiastic about other types of trade agreements,
agreements that did not divide markets or set prices. He was at the
vanguard of the associational movement that would ourish in the
1920s,
210
although in 1913 he called only for studies to determine when
trade agreements restrained competition reasonably, when they
restrained it unreasonably, and when they restrained it not at all.
211
Here, as elsewhere, Brandeis sought to construe, bias, or supplement
the antitrust laws in ways favorable to smaller businesses. Thus, while
lawmakers in 1914 were more inclined to proscribe conduct rather than
to legalize conduct already proscribed by law, Brandeis argued that
Congress should reverse Dr. Miles and allow resale price maintenance
(so long as the seller of trademarked goods neither controlled markets
nor made agreements with its competitors); he asserted that the practice
ideals; that it is making impossible equality of opportunity; that it is converting independent
tradesmen into clerks; and that it is sapping the resources, the vigor and the hope of the
smaller cities and towns).
207
See supra note 24.
208
1911 Hearings, supra note 21, at 1182. Cf. John Bates Clark, The Philosophy
of Wealth 214 (1886) (railroad pools encourage competition by which rms strive
for efciency).
209
1911 Hearings, supra note 21, at 124950. See also Berk, supra note 195, at 4346.
210
See generally Robert F. Himmelberg, The Origins of the National Recovery
Administration, Business, Government and the Trade Association Issue 1921
1933 (1976).
211
Brandeis to William Cox Redeld, May 27, 1913, 3 LBL, supra note 4, at 102. See also
American Column & Lumber Co. v. United States, 257 U.S. 377, 414 (1921) (Brandeis,
J., dissenting) (plan disseminating information about completed sales should be permitted
so long as the participants were not coerced, because the essence of restraint is power).
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
2003] Origins of the FTC 37
would benet not only small retailers, but consumers and manufacturers
as well.
212
To further protect smaller businesses, Brandeis proposed in
1911 to bias litigation against huge enterprise; under his proposal, a
restraint of trade would be presumed illegal when a rm controlled 40
percent of a market.
213
He also proposed to create a bureau of industrial
research, which would extend to smaller businesses the benets of
research and development that larger enterprises could themselves
afford.
214
3. Regulatory Procedures
Although Brandeis distrusted a Roosevelt-style commission, he shared
with Roosevelt (but neither with Wilson nor with many of the Senates
most vocal opponents of the trusts
215
) a comfort with expert decision
making. Brandeis resisted when Senator Cummins sought, during 1911
testimony, to elicit an endorsement of a commission empowered to
approve business plans in advance. However, he then seemed primarily
concerned that an agency was not yet ready to assume the task; after an
agency had rst acquired a large volume of information, daily added
to, in respect to each of the important industries in the country, it
might be a comparatively simple thing for the commission to pass quickly
upon a question as to whether a given combination is legal or illegal.
216
Having practiced before the ICC and other agencies, Brandeis was at
ease with administrative procedures.
217
Further, Brandeis saw specicuse
212
See Brandeis to Robert La Follette, May 27, 1913 3 LBL, supra note 4, at 100, 101;
1915 Hearings, supra note 197, at 12, 26; McCraw, supra note 198, at 331 n.47 (citing
1912 testimony); Louis Brandeis, Competition that Kills (1913), reprinted in Brandeis, Busi-
ness, supra note 195, at 243. With the stated conditions met, Brandeis said that the market
would adequately protect consumers because manufacturers who charged too much would
lose prots. Price maintenance redressed an imbalance against smaller manufacturers,
whose larger competitors could set resale prices by establishing exclusive agencies; it
protected mom and pop retail shops from chain store discounting; and it protected
consumers who could buy goods with an assurance of reliable quality.
213
S. 3276, 61st Cong., 1st Sess. (1911), reprinted in 3 Bills and Debates, supra note
67, at 2415, 2416. See also 1911 Hearings, supra note 21, at 1175. Standard Oil had applied
such a presumption where the defendant had a 90% market share. Standard Oil, 221 U.S.
at 33, 75.
214
1911 Hearings, supra note 21, at 1169. See also Brandeis to Franklin Knight Lane, Dec.
12, 1913, 3 LBL, supra note 4, at 218, 219.
215
See supra text accompanying notes 417447.
216
1911 Hearings, supra note 21, at 126970. Brandeis had second thoughts when he
discussed non-binding advance advice before the FTC in 1915. He then declared that
the Commission, despite the best of intent, would inevitably be hoodwinked by businesses
seeking approval of a specic transaction. Statement of Louis Brandeis Before the Federal Trade
Commission at 5 (Apr. 30, 1915) (available in FTC library).
217
Also, though Brandeis very much cared about workers, he broke with unions in his
willingness to entrust them to experts who employed scientic management. Unions
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal38
for a commission. A purely investigatory commission, for example, could
obtain information about when trade agreements properly regulated
competition, and that information could be used to determine which
agreements should be allowed. Brandeis wrote in January 1913:
The question, Shall we regulate competition or regulate monopoly?
assumes that there will be some regulation, and it is clear that in order
to regulate either . . . an administrative board of some kind, and with
fairly broad powers, must be created to supplement the powers of the
courts in dealing with this subject.
The only fundamental difference as between the New Partys program
and that of its opponent relates to the economic policy to be enforced.
All other differences are differences in degree or of emphasis.
218
Because Brandeis denied that the largest rms were efcient, he saw
no need to sacrice other goals, including opportunity, competition,
fair distribution, and political freedom, for the sake of efciency. He
continued to believe, consistent with the classical paradigm, that these
goals could be pursued in tandem.
219
Brandeis would have subordinated
efciency to other goals had it been necessary, but he denied the need
would arise. However, the classical vision also encompassed a trust in
judicial decision making, an important aspect of Tafts thought that
Brandeis did not share. Despite their opposing views on the merits of
size, Brandeis was closer to Roosevelt than to Taft (or Wilson) in his
skepticism about the courts. His views on this score would prove impor-
tant at a critical juncture in 1914.
D. Woodrow Wilson
The FTC was created to Wilsons specications. When he proposed
an investigatory commission in January 1914, the House adopted his
proposal. When he endorsed a prosecutorial commission in June, the
Senate bill and nal law embraced that proposal. When he later empha-
sized the agencys assistive functions, his selection of Commissioners
reected that orientation.
This section explores Wilsons views, through the 1912 campaign, on
Presidential leadership, economics, concentration, trusts, and experts
all of which impacted the 1914 legislation. It examines the consistency
feared that scientic management might be used to justify lower wages. Strum, supra note
186, at 165.
218
Brandeis, Competition, supra note 199, at 113. Brandeis also wrote that judicial mecha-
nisms must be supplemented by other adequate machinery to be administered by a
federal board or commission. Louis Brandeis, The Solution of the Trust Problem (1913),
reprinted in Brandeis, Curse, supra note 197, at 129, 130.
219
See supra text accompanying notes 183184.
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
2003] Origins of the FTC 39
of the core assumptions that were at the heart of his antitrust program
through January 1914: antitrust violations could and should be dened
clearly; responsible individuals should be harshly punished for corporate
transgressions; and authority should be kept away from experts. It
explores as well his skepticism about corporate dissolutions and the
faith in potential competition on which, at least in 1912, he predicated
that skepticism.
1. Moralist, Political Scientist, and Politician
Wilson, the son and grandson of ministers, graduated from Princeton
and the University of Virginia Law School, practiced law briey, and
earned a doctorate in political science from Johns Hopkins. In 1902, he
became president of Princeton, then better known for the lineage of its
students than the education they received, and gained national renown
as an academic reformer. Wilson began to address political issues, and
emerged in 1905 as a spokesman for conservative Democrats. He was
elected governor of New Jersey in 1910 (succeeding progressive Republi-
can and future FTC Commissioner John Franklin Fort). Though nomi-
nated by a machine opposed to reform, Wilson quickly emerged as a
progressive. Capping his meteoric rise, he was President two years later.
220
Wilson was for decades, according to John Milton Cooper, Americas
nest political scientist.
221
As a scholar, Wilson admired the British system,
where a prime minister exercised power through his party in Parlia-
ment.
222
He applauded the growth in Presidential power under Roosevelt,
afrming that a President should initiate legislation and lead his party.
223
When he became President himself, he would implement his theories
with remarkable success.
2. Wilson on Economics, Economists, and Experts
Wilson studied economics under Richard Ely, and analyzed the history
of American economic thought as part of a projected book that Ely
planned to co-author.
224
Since political economy was then ensconced
in the same departments as political science, Wilson taught the subject
220
See generally August Heckscher, Woodrow Wilson (1991).
221
Cooper, supra note 83, at 54.
222
Woodrow Wilson, Congressional Government (1885). Wilson then found Ameri-
can politics wanting because power had devolved to unaccountable Congressional com-
mittees.
223
Woodrow Wilson, Constitutional Government in The United States (1908),
reprinted in 18 PWW, supra note 5, at 69, 115 (nding admirable that the Presidentsofce
was then anything he has the sagacity and force to make it).
224
4 PWW, supra note 5, at 62829 and 63163 (editorial note and Wilson draft). With
respect to Elys work, see, e.g., Thorelli, supra note 9, at 12325, 31415.
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal40
as late as 1892, and he served on the rst council of the American
Economic Association.
225
He wrote John Bates Clark in 1886 that Clarks
recent work, which included a chapter on The Economic Role of the
Church, had fertilized [his] own thought.
226
Wilson, like the young Ely, preferred a culturally based, inductive new
schooleconomics in place of a deductively based classical economics.
227
He appeared unreceptive when a new deductive economics, a neo-
classical economics based on marginal utility theory, emerged.
228
Wil-
sons distaste for deductive economics was part of a broader dismay at
extending scientic models, and particularly deductive models from the
physical sciences, to other disciplines.
229
Indeed, whereas Roosevelt and
Brandeis expected science to validate their (conicting) views, Wilsons
skepticism towards the social sciences had deep roots. In 1896, he saw
a certain degeneracyin the scientic spirit. Surveying the work of the
noxious, intoxicating gas which has somehow got into the lungs of the
rest of us, he would tremble to see social reform led by men who had
breathed it: I should fear nothing better than utter destruction from a
revolution conceived and led in the scientic spirit.
230
225
See, e.g., 5 PWW, supra note 5, at 602 (noting lectures, 18881891); William Diamond,
Economic Thought of Woodrow Wilson 38 n.1 (1943).
226
Wilson to John Bates Clark, Aug. 26, 1887, 5 PWW, supra note 5, at 564; Clark, supra
note 208.
227
Wilson described economics in 1891 notes as not a science of absolute truths, but
of historical conditions and stages of development; of social conditions (from the economic
point of view) their cause and cure. Woodrow Wilson Collection, Library of Congress,
Reel 489. Deductive economic models were like statutes and constitutions. Studying each
furnishes crude body colors but not the “finer luminous and atmospheric effects; a
complete economics must account for how a mans wife affects his trade, how his children
stiffen his prudence [and] how his prejudices condition his enterprise. On the Study of
Politics (1886), 5 PWW, supra note 5, at 395, 40304.
228
Alfred Marshall published his seminal work in 1890. Alfred Marshall, Principles
of Economics (1st ed. 1890). The earlier work by Clark that Wilson praised, supra text
accompanying note 226, did include explorations in marginal utility theory; however,
Diamond notes that Wilsons praise focused exclusively on Clarks view of morality and
reform. See Diamond, supra note 225, at 34. Aside from philosophical predispositions,
Wilson likely followed developments in economics less closely once his career advanced
sufciently that he could focus on his primary interest in political science rather than a
distinctly secondary interest in political economy.
229
Wilson wrote that the Constitution was based on a Newtonian model of balanced
forces, but had proved adaptable to a proper model based on the cooperation that takes
place in organic life. Constitutional Government, supra note 223, at 10405. See also
Woodrow Wilson, The New Freedom 18 (1913) (Society is a living organism and must
obey the laws of life, not of mechanics; it must develop.).
230
Princeton in the Nations Service, Oct. 21, 1896, 10 PWW, supra note 5, at 11, 2930. A
draft of that speech added [we] deem the newest theory of society the likeliest ....
[Science] has made the legislator condent that he can create and the philosopher sure
that God cannot. Id. at 29.
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
2003] Origins of the FTC 41
3. Wilson on Concentration and Trust: 19051911
Until 1905, Wilson rarely discussed such political controversies as the
treatment of trusts.
231
Then the ministers son, emerging in national
politics as a foe of Bryans agrarian populism within the Democratic
party, declared, We cant abolish the trusts. We must moralize them.
232
In 1907, he invoked the trio of economics, morality, and law on which
Senator Newlands, in particular, would later rely in 1914. In Wilsons view:
Our thinkers, whether in the eld of morals or the eld of economics,
have before them nothing less than the task of translating law and
morals into the terms of modern business; and inasmuch as morals
cannot be corporate, but must be individual . . . that task in simple
terms comes to this: to nd the individual amidst modern circumstances
and bring him face to face once more with a clearly dened per-
sonal responsibility.
***
The law, both civil and criminal, can clearly enough characterize transac-
tions, can clearly enough determine what their consequences shall be
to the individuals who engage in them in a responsible capacity. New
denitions in that eld are not beyond the knowledge of modern
lawyers or the skill of modern lawmakers, if they will accept the advice
of disinterested lawyers. We shall never moralize society by ning or
even dissolving corporations; we shall only inconvenience it. We shall
moralize it only when we make up our minds as to what transactions
are reprehensible, and bring those transactions home to individuals
with the full penalty of the law.
233
New standards presumably would entail new constraints because mod-
ern business has brought into use transactions novel to our older practice
and almost unknown to our present legal denitions, which are in contra-
vention both of good morals and sound business.
234
Further, while
economic changes necessitated the reformulation of law, morality, and
notions of sound business practice, the moralist had a seat at the table
in developing that reformulation. While Wilson said that certain practices
are to be desired in the interest alike of efciency and economy,
235
he
commented soon after (albeit in a sermon) that [t]he tendency to be
231
In a rare comment, Wilson wrote in 1898 that socialists erred in thinking that it was
competition that kills.The killer was such unfair competition as the use of child labor;
the state could equalize competition by forbidding such practices. Woodrow Wilson,
The State 632, 63536 (1898).
232
Speech, Feb. 27, 1905, 16 PWW, supra note 5, at 14. See also Speech, Apr. 13, 1906,
id. at 358, 361 ([n]o doubt the great corporations have come to stay; no doubt a certain
degree of monopoly is inseparable from their size and accumulated might; but they may,
by scrutiny and regulation, be freed from the spirit of monopoly).
233
Politics (1907), 17 PWW, supra note 5, at 309, 32223, 325.
234
Credo, Aug. 6, 1907, 17 PWW, supra note 5, at 335, 336.
235
Law or Personal Power, Apr. 13, 1908, 18 PWW, supra note 5, at 263, 265.
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal42
practical will not conquer the tendency to be moral . . . . The moralist
will dictate both to the lawyer and to the man of business.
236
Whatever the roles of moralist, economist, and lawyer in developing
standards, Wilson rejected broad Roosevelt-style regulation as a means
to implement them. Wilson distinguished regulation mandating conduct
from regulation prohibiting it: the latter was regulation of the transac-
tionand proper, and the former direct administrative regulationand
socialist. The answer to unrighteous corporate behavior was not to
substitute the wrong of tyranny for the wrong of private oppression,
butagain the essential themesto pass clear laws and punish individual
transgressors.
237
Wilson added another theme in 1910, as he asked an
audience if it wanted big business to benecently take care of you, or
do you want to take care of yourselves? Are you wards or are you men?
. . . Are you old enough to take care of yourselves?
238
Wilson as governor did secure one of the most thoroughgoing [public
utilities laws] in the nation.
239
Except for public utilities regulation,
though, the governor did little to address questions of concentration.
He drafted platform language calling for repeal of New Jerseys notorious
corporate laws,
240
but did not actually try to change them until 1913. In
discussing trusts, Wilson continued to focus on denitions and personal
liability.
241
He attacked Tafts prosecutions for hav[ing] everyone guess-
ing, since you cannot conduct sound business upon a test of guess-
ing.
242
And Wilson continued to oppose corporate dissolutions. He
declared in 1910 that they would throw great undertakings out of gear,
and, unlike Brandeis, Wilson thought shareholders to be worth protect-
236
Baccalaureate Address, June 7, 1908, id. at 323, 33031. But see Sklar, supra note 25,
at 413 (detecting a trinity in which law and morals would work their way in the world to
suit the naturally, perhaps preternaturally, evolving requirements of modern business:
father (economy), son (law), holy spirit (morals).).
237
The Government and Business, Mar. 14, 1908, 18 PWW, supra note 5, at 35, 3839,
4243, 50. See also Clark, supra note 51, at 96 (ways in which a trust can crush an efcient
competitor are nearly all now well known).
238
Speech, Nov. 4, 1910, 21 PWW, supra note 5, at 543, 551.
239
Editors comments, id. at 578, 580 n.4. The New Jersey commission could investigate,
evaluate corporate property, x rates, establish standards of service for electric companies,
require railroads to establish junction points and intersections with other lines, and pre-
approve issuances of stocks and bonds. Id. See also Speeches, Jan. 17, 1911, 22 PWW, supra
note 5, at 345, 349, and Feb. 28, 1911, id. at 456, 461.
240
Draft Platform, Aug. 9, 1910, 21 PWW, supra note 5, at 43, 45; supra note 15 (New
Jersey laws).
241
See, e.g., The Lawyer and the Community, Aug. 31, 1910, 21 PWW, supra note 5, at 64, 71.
242
Wilson Says Taft Disturbs Business, N.Y. Times, Oct. 12, 1911, at 18.
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
2003] Origins of the FTC 43
ing.
243
When the Supreme Court decided Standard Oil, Wilson deemed
it wrong to wreak vengeance by destroying the machines, rather than
punish nanciers who took joy rides in corporations.
244
4. The 1912 Campaign
a. Substantive Views
Wilsons tone changed in 1912. The Democratic platform reected
the agrarian populism of William Jennings Bryan, a populism that
opposed any rule of reason,
245
and Wilson was tied to both the platform
and Bryan: the future Secretary of State had made his peace with Wilson
and thereby facilitated Wilsons nomination, and Wilson needed the
votes of Bryans supporters.
246
The platform began with a then-traditional
rallying cry: A private monopoly is indefensible and intolerable.
247
It
called for laws on price discrimination, holding companies, and inter-
locking directorates (thus providing a blueprint for the Clayton Act), as
well as legislation to directly limit corporate size (a provision that John
Bates Clark singled out for particular praise). Further, it nearly
demanded reversal of the rule of reason.
248
In accepting the nomination, Wilson deemed trusts another chapter
in the natural history of power and of governing classes. The next
chapter will set us free again.
249
He interwove antitrust with banking
reform, tariff reform, and labor unrest to attack a privileged few, forming
trusts and vast confederacies . . . of banks, railways, express companies,
243
The Lawyer and the Community, supra note 241, at 71. Brandeis saw shareholders as
investors seeking to maximize their return, and deemed immoral the idea of such persons
being innocent in the sense of not letting them take the consequences of their acts....
1911 Hearings, supra note 21, at 1177.
244
Speech, May 17, 1911, 23 PWW, supra note 5, at 59.
245
See, e.g., supra note 66 and accompanying text.
246
Heckscher, supra note 220, at 242, 24748, 250. See supra text accompanying note
232 (Wilsons emergence in 1905 as a foe of Bryan).
247
See Johnson, supra note 105, at 112, 114 (1900), 130, 132 (1904), 144, 146 (1908),
168, 169 (1912) (Democratic platforms).
248
The platform provided: We favor the declaration by law of the conditions upon
which corporations shall be permitted to engage in interstate trade, including, among
others, the prevention of holding companies, of interlocking directors, of stock watering,
of discrimination in price, and the control by any one corporation of so large a proportion
of any industry as to make it a menace to competitive conditions ....Weregret that the
Sherman anti-trust law has received a judicial construction depriving it of much of its
efciency and we favor the enactment of legislation which will restore to the statute the
strength of which it has been deprived by such interpretation. Id. at 168, 169. See also
John Bates Clark, The Parties and the Supreme Issue,73Independent 891, 894 (Oct. 17, 1912).
249
Speech Accepting the Democratic Presidential Nomination, Aug. 7, 1912, 25 PWW,
supra note 5, at 3, 11.
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal44
insurance companies, manufacturing corporations, mining corpora-
tions, power and development companies, and all the rest of the
circle....
250
Their efforts produced economies [u]p to a certain point
(but only up to a certain point), and they produced prosperity, if
by prosperity you mean vast wealth no matter how distributed.
251
His
automotive metaphor soon changed. Firms were no longer benign vehi-
cles in which greedy executives took joy rides, but cars of Juggernaut
in which no man should take a joy rideand which no commission
should license.
252
Wilson proclaimed, I have seen these giants close their
hands upon the workingmen of this country already, and I have seen
the blood come through their ngers.
253
Despite this strident tone, though, Wilson elsewhere modulated his
message. After promising to set us free from trusts, his acceptance
speech declared, in very un-Brandeis-like terms:
I am not one of those who think that competition can be established
by law against the drift of a world-wide economic tendency; neither am
I one of those who believe that business done on a grand scale by a
single organization . . . is necessarily dangerous to the liberties, even
the economic liberties, of a great people like our own, full of intelligence
and indomitable energy.
254
After Wilson met Brandeis on August 28, he took from his adviser
specic terms (regulating competition versus regulating monopoly)
and examples.
255
But Wilson had, in Neils Thorsens words, a capacity
for comprehending and absorbing new ideas, new methods, and even
new areas of scholarship [that] was strikingly matched by his ability to
adapt them to his original political loyalties and dispositions.
256
Despite
Wilsons borrowing, the seeds of regulating competition (as Wilson
understood it) had been in his acceptance speech.
257
The remedies he
espoused after he met Brandeis were those he had long espoused: per-
250
Id. at 12.
251
Id. at 9, 10.
252
Speech, Sept. 2, 1912, id. at 69, 74.
253
Speech, Oct. 7, 1912, id. at 369, 373.
254
Acceptance Speech, Aug. 7, 1912, id. at 4, 11.
255
Compare Speech, Sept. 20, 1912, id. at 198, 20708, and 1911 Hearings, supra note
21, at 1161 (Wilsons and Brandeiss discussions of tying clauses used by United Shoes
Machinery Co.).
256
Niels Thorsen, The Political Thought of Woodrow Wilson, 18751910, at
188 (1988).
257
Acceptance speech, Aug. 7, 1912, 25 PWW, supra note 5, at 4, 11 (competition
can in large measure be revived by changing the laws and forbidding the practices that
killed it).
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
2003] Origins of the FTC 45
sonal penalties (a theme from which Brandeis distanced himself) and
clear laws.
258
Further, unlike Brandeis, Wilson declared himself for big business,
and . . . against the trusts.
259
I am not jealous of any process of growth,
no matter how huge the result, provided the result was obtained by the
processes of growth which are processes of efciency, of economy, of
intelligence, and of invention.
260
On the other hand, he condemned
business that had not grown big but been made big.
261
He thus
seemed to assume that mergers rarely generated efciencies and, by
1912, a condemnation of rms made big reached broadly.
However, Wilson also continued to oppose dissolution proceedings.
He hesitated to tamper directly with business structure and said that
potential competition made such tampering unnecessary.
262
Despite his
skepticism about classical economics and deductive science, Wilson
hoped to promote antitrusts various goals in tandem, and to do so with
relatively limited government intervention; he would simply free the
pygmies of small business to redress market distortion, and thereby
restore a balance between opportunity (at least to the extent of disciplin-
ing market behavior), efciency, competition, fair distribution, and polit-
ical freedom.
b. The Role of a Commission
A commission was, at best, peripheral to Wilsons 1912 vision, and a
Roosevelt-style commission, which he attributed to George Perkins and
258
For example, Wilson said there had been disclosed all the processes by which monop-
oly is established and competition prevented, and declared himself not desirous of
putting everyone in jail,since selected specimens will do.Speech, Oct. 28, 1912, in John
Wells Davidson, Crossroads of Freedom 484, 491 (1956) ; N.Y. Times, Aug. 29, 1912,
reprinted in 25 PWW, supra note 5, at 56, 58 (Brandeiss view).
259
Speech, Sept. 17, 1912, 25 PWW, supra note 5, at 148, 152.
260
Speech, Sept. 18, 1912, id. at 164, 168.
261
Speech, Sept. 17, 1912, id. at 148, 152. See also Speeches, Sept. 18, 1912, id. at 164,
167 (trusts will crush competitor as long as his market is local ...,andwhen his market
becomes general then he may be taken in or bought out) and Sept. 20, 1912, id. at
203, 20607.
262
Wilson said: [I]t hasnt seemed to make much difference whether [trusts were]
dissolved . . . that is to say, nominally dissolved. But I would be perfectly willing to let
them go without dissolution; because if we can make competition fair and prevent the
giants from killing the pygmies, then I am perfectly willing to let the brains of the pygmies
compete with the brains of the giants....Trusts cant stand competition, let me tell you.
Speech, Sept. 26, 912, id. at 257, 26566. Wilson did see a need in to disentangle and
gently, but rmly and persistently, dissect, a colossal community of interest. Wilson,
New Freedom, supra note 229, at 189. However, this passage referred to the money trust,
see supra note 24, a series of boards of directors . . . more formidable than any conceivable
single combination that dare appear in the open. Id. Wilson feared the result when all
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal46
U.S. Steels Elbert Gary, was in Wilsons view dangerous.
263
Under that
plan, Wilson charged, monopolies would be adopted and regulatedin
a consummation of the partnership between monopoly and govern-
ment. Nor would business stop at partnership. Once the government
regulates monopoly, then monopoly will have to see to it that it regulates
the government.
264
Consistent with his earlier skepticism of scientic models, Wilson
decried government by a smug lot of experts.
265
He chided the so-
called economic experts around whom he had spent his life.
266
God
forbid that in a democratic country we should resign the task and give
the government over to experts. What are we for if we are to be scienti-
cally taken care of by a small number of gentlemen who are the only
men who understand the job?
267
The antitrust violations he intended
to outlaw would not be identied by experts employing deduction.
Rather, we have been having trials and investigations by Congress, and
we know the processes of unrestricted competition by which these men
have accomplished the setting up of their monopolies. And if we dont
know how to stop them, then the lawyers of this country have lost their
ingenuity and their intelligence.
268
But Wilson hedged his bets. He said on September 25: We want to
see the law administered; we are not afraid of commissions. . . . We may
have to have special tribunals, special processes, . . . But I am absolutely
opposed to leaving it to the choice of those tribunals what the processes
of law shall be and the means of remedy.
269
Two days later, after meeting
with Brandeis, he approved (in a particularly opaque passage) a commis-
sion that did not exercise the power of the government through the
trusts but was rather the instrument of a free government, a government
free to serve the interests of the people and quickly responsive to the
opinions of the people, with no intermediaries to interpret the interests
the combinations are combined and this nal combination is not disclosed by any process
of incorporation of law, but is merely an identity of personnel, or of interest... Id.
263
Speech, Sept. 17, 1912, 25 PWW, supra note 5, at 158, 160.
264
Speech, Sept. 2, 1912, id. at 69, 73.
265
Speech, Sept. 17, 1912, id. at 148, 154. See also id. at 151 (beware of commissions of
experts, who dont see anything except what is under their microscope, under their eye).
266
Speech, Sept. 4, 1912, id. at 98, 103.
267
Speech, Sept. 2, 1912, id. at 69, 78.
268
Speech, Sept. 17, 1912, id. at 158, 159.
269
Speech, Sept. 25, 1912, id. at 245, 251.
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
2003] Origins of the FTC 47
of business and to check the rise of new industries and the entrance
into the eld of initiative of the individual himself.
270
c. The Challenge for Wilson
As a candidate, Wilsons condemnations of trusts were modulated by
a substantial caveat. Trusts were bad, big business good. And, though
Wilson apparently saw the trust problem as widespread (since he implied
that many large enterprises were trusts), his 1912 program contem-
plated that antitrust, supplemented by tariff and banking reform, could
remedy the problem. Once future misconduct was deterred by clearly
dening violations and personally sanctioning corporate ofcers, past
misconduct could be remedied, without resort to dissolutions, as poten-
tial competitors entered the market. Fully sharing neither Roosevelts
conviction that size correlated to efciency nor Brandeiss conviction
that it did not, Wilson was torn, in John Morton Blums words, between
an ambivalent fear at once of big business and of regulating it.
271
d. The Challenge of Wilson
Within months, Wilson would retreat from his assertions that dissolu-
tions were unnecessary. Events of 1914 would then undermine his con-
dence that clear prohibitions were possible, or at least politically feasible.
He would nally accept a prosecutorial commission, although he to some
degree anticipated that acceptance in 1912. A challenge of explaining
these changes is that Wilson had many sides. Among his personae, he
was a shrewd politician whose periodic reorientations, however sincerely
motivated, added to his political luster and his partys viability.
272
How-
ever, he was also a moralist for whom principled compromise depended
270
Speech, Sept. 27, 1912, Davidson, supra note 258, at 284, 28687. See also Brandeis
to Wilson, Sept. 30, 1912, 25 PWW, supra note 5, at 289, 293 (Brandeis text noting,
We need for the enforcement of the Sherman law and regulation of competition an
administrative Board with broad powers; Wilson edits changing the rst words to We
probably need).
271
John Morton Blum, Woodrow Wilson and the Politics of Morality 20 (1956).
272
Wilsons move leftward in 1910 had added to his viability in 1912. His modulated
progressivism of 1912 positioned the Democrats as a party of responsible reform. He
would move rightward as he completed his New Freedom package with antitrust reforms
in 1914; he had already obtained a succession of other reforms, the economy was in
recession, and he needed to quell business concerns. See infra note 334 and accompanying
text. Still later, as the 1916 election approached, Wilson lurched back to the left; he
nominated Brandeis to the Supreme Court and embraced a child labor act, a farm loan
act, and a workmens compensation law for federal employees, although he also courted
business by securing a tariff commission and advancing legislation, which eventually
emerged as the Webb-Pomerene Act of 1918, to permit export cartels. See Arthur
S. Link, Wilson: Confusion and Crises 19151916, at 31962 (1964); Sanders, supra
note 172, at 36786.
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal48
on knowing and disclosing whither you are bound
273
but who some-
times failed his own standard.
274
Congresss inability to develop clear and comprehensive denitions
of antitrust violations in 1914 would deny Wilson a bearing that told
him whither he was bound. Did he then abandon his principles in
embracing a regulatory commission? The analysis below concludes that
his retreat was expedient and ambivalent, but not unprincipled. However,
its ambivalence would have an impact on both the framing of the 1914
legislation and, later, the makeup of the Commission.
V. THE 1912 ELECTION AND THE PRESIDENT-ELECT
A. Election Results and Party Alignment
The 1912 election was an electoral college landslide, as Wilson carried
forty of forty-eight states. The Democrats widened their House majority
(they had taken control of the chamber in 1910) to 290127, and took
control of the Senate with a 5144 majority.
275
But the silver lining barely
covered some clouds. Wilson received 42 percent of the popular vote,
a respectable showing in a race with a signicant third party (and a non-
trivial fourth party), but his support was under 39 percent outside the
Democrats’“Solid South.
276
Further, the Democratssuccess depended
in part on the Republicans ssion when Roosevelt left his party. The
Democrats traditionally were the minority party,
277
and when the Republi-
273
Speech, Nov. 2, 1909, 19 PWW, supra note 5, at 471, 47677 (address at a seminary
explaining: The individuals who have the vigor to lead must content themselves with a
slackened pace and go only so fast as they can be followed”—although that is not inconsis-
tent with telling the world in very plain terms whither it is bound and what the ultimate
and complete truth of the matter, as it seems to them, is. You cannot make any progress
unless you know whither you are bound.).
274
As Governor, for example, Wilson split from the New Jersey machine. As President,
he allowed his lieutenants to reward that very machine with patronage when he needed
to strengthen his party for Congressional elections. Arthur S. Link, Woodrow Wilson and the
Democratic Party, reprinted in The Higher Realism of Woodrow Wilson 60, 6970 (1971).
275
George B. Galloway, History of the House of Representatives 368 (2d ed.
1976); Robert C. Byrd, 4 The Senate : 17891989, at 418 (1994). One Senate seat was
held by Progressive Miles Poindexter, on a two-year sabbatical from the Republicans.
Eighteen seats in the House were held by third parties, mostly Progressives.
276
Roosevelt received 27% of the vote, Taft 23%, and Socialist Eugene Debs 6%. Scott
James nds that Wilson received 58% of the vote in fteen Southern states, and fewer
than 39% in the Northeast, the Midwest, and the South. James, supra note 190, at 135.
277
Only one other Democrat (Grover Cleveland) had been elected President since the
Civil War. Democrats had controlled the Senate for only four years in that time and,
though they had a better record in the House, the Republicans had controlled that
chamber, as well, from 1896 to 1910.
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
2003] Origins of the FTC 49
cans reunited they in fact recovered the House, Senate, and Presidency
between 1916 and 1920.
278
Still, in 1912, the Democrats held a strong hand. Further, they rein-
forced their numerical strength with a caucus that formed a nearly united
front on Wilsons four key initiatives in 1913 and 1914, including the
FTC and Clayton Acts.
279
Using the caucus, and seeking to build a rm
base for his party, Wilson emulated the British system he had long
admired and led the nation by leading his party.
280
With the signicant
exception of the FTC Act, the Democrats generally spurned help from
progressive Republicans and received little.
281
B. New Jerseys Seven Sisters
In moves that presaged his Presidential plans, Wilson turned quickly
to antitrustwhile still Governor of New Jersey. Stung by Roosevelts
attacks on the states laws,
282
Wilson called for new corporate and antitrust
laws on January 14, 1913. With the Presidential transition then on March
4, Wilson secured seven bills, the Seven Sisters, on February 19.
283
278
The Democrats House majority would drop from 163 to 38 in 1914, and the party
returned to minority status in 1916. See Galloway, supra note 275, at 368. Direct election
of Senators would buoy the Democrats to a 5-seat gain in 1914. See Byrd, supra note 275,
at 418; Jay S. Bybee, Ulysses at the Mast: Democracy, Federalism, and the Sirens Song of the
Seventeenth Amendment,91Nw. U. L. Rev. 500, 552 (1997) (prior method of electing
Senators by state legislatures generally favored Republicans). However, the Republicans
made inroads in 1916 and recovered the Senate in 1918. Wilson himself barely survived
the Republicans reunication in 1916, with a 277254 electoral college victory over former
Justice (and future Chief Justice) Charles Evan Hughes. By 1920, the Democrats lost the
Presidential vote in every state north of Virginia and every state west of Texas. Cooper,
supra note 12, at 253, 371.
279
James, supra note 190, at 14143. Under caucus rules, a two-thirds vote by a caucus
of the Democrats serving in the House or Senate bound all the Democrats in that chamber,
with limited exceptions, on the subsequent oor vote. Wilder H. Haines, The Congressional
Caucus of Today,9Am. Pol. Sci. Rev. 696, 69697 (1915); George H. Haynes, The Senate
of the United States 476 (1938).
280
See supra text accompanying note 223.
281
Among non-Democratic Senators, only Republican Robert La Follette and Progressive
Miles Poindexter supported Wilsons rst major initiative, the tariff bill. Although opposi-
tion to Tafts tariff program had been a major dispute between progressives and Old
Guard Republicans, progressive Republicans, who had sought greater tariff reductions
under Taft, now attacked Wilsons tariff reductions for disproportionately affecting farmers.
Holt, supra note 67, at 8991. Wilson also had little Republican support on the banking
bill, his second major initiative. Id. at 10812. See also infra notes 549, 563, and accompanying
text (discussing Clayton bill).
282
Governor Wilson and the Trusts, Nov. 2, 1912, 17 TRW, supra note 1, at 341. See also
supra text accompanying note 15 (New Jersey laws).
283
See Joseph F. Mahoney, Backsliding Convert: Woodrow Wilson and the Seven Sisters,18
Am. Q. 71, 7378 (1966). The bills were Chapters 1319 of the New Jersey Session Laws
(1913), reprinted in Laws, supra note 16, at 22935.
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal50
The President-elect did not turn to Brandeis, but rather to New Jersey
jurists.
284
Those jurists drew heavily on existing state laws, largely from
agrarian states with strong antitrust movements. One of the Sisters pro-
hibited most new stock acquisitions by corporations, although it allowed
corporations to retain previously acquired stock.
285
Another prohibited
intrastate price discrimination with an improper intent or effect, though
allowing price differences based on grade, quality, transportation costs
and (more unusually) quantity.
286
Yet another, seemingly a frontal attack
on both the rule of reason and the Supreme Courts earlier directness
test, criminalized any agreement whose participants directly or indirectly
preclude a free and unrestricted competition among themselves, or any
purchasers or consumers, in the sale or transportation of any article or
commodity, either by pooling, withholding from the market or selling
at a xed price, or in any manner by which the price might be affected.
287
Free and unrestricted competitionlanguage was not novel; similar text
appeared in other states laws, and Senator John Sherman had sought
such language in the bill that ultimately bore his name.
288
The Supreme
Court had upheld such laws, while suggesting that they might be over-
broad in some applications.
289
Whatever the precedent, though, the New
Jersey language was particularly strong in rejecting any agreement by
which prices might directly or indirectly be affected, and its language
seems hard to reconcile with Wilsons calls for clarity. And, when Wilson
prepared to turn to federal antitrust legislation, he sent the Seven Sisters
to Congressman Henry Clayton as a model.
290
C. The McReynolds Appointment
Wilson may have reconsidered his opposition to corporate dissolutions
before the 1912 election, in response to a letter written on behalf of
284
Arthur S. Link, Wilson: New Freedom 34 (1956).
285
Session Laws, N.J., ch. 18 (1913). The Sisters did not prohibit mergers through asset
acquisitions, but regulated the issuance of bonds to nance such acquisitions. Id. ch. 17.
286
Id. ch. 15. See also infra notes 324, 326, and accompanying text (discussing state price
discrimination laws).
287
Session Laws, N.J., ch. 13 (1913).
288
State laws include, for example, Kansas L. 1897, ch. 265, reprinted in Laws, supra note
16, at 122; Arizona L. 1912, ch. 73, § 1, reprinted in id. at 45, 46. Kansas law still retains
such language. Kan. Stat. Ann. § 50-112 (2001). See also SC Code Ann. § 39-3-10 (2001);
Tenn. Code Ann. § 47-25-101 (2001); Ohio Stat. § 1331.01 (2001). Shermans bills include
S.1 as Reported by the Senate Committee on Finance, 51st Cong., 1st Sess. ( Jan. 14, 1890).
289
Smiley v. Kansas, 196 U.S. 447, 45657 (1905); National Cotton Oil Co. v. Texas, 197
U.S. 115 (1905).
290
Wilson to Henry Clayton, Oct. 20, 1913, 28 PWW, supra note 5, at 420.
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
2003] Origins of the FTC 51
John Bates Clark.
291
Whenever Wilsons views changed, though, he did
not publicly signal his retreat until he chose James McReynolds as Attor-
ney General. McReynolds had been the governments lead attorney in
American Tobacco, but resigned to protest Tafts acquiescence to the disso-
lution plan.
292
McReynolds soon justied his trustbuster reputation. He
proposed a graduated excise tax targeting the successor rms under
the tobacco decree (a proposal from which Wilson quickly distanced
himself), and announced his opposition to dissolutions that left successor
rms under common ownership.
293
The McReynolds appointment
showed that Wilson was now reconciled to dissolution proceedings.
294
VI. FEDERAL ANTITRUST LEGISLATION
Wilson took ofce on March 4, 1913. Congress went into session on
April 7, 1913, and remained in continual session for eighteen months,
adjourning three weeks before midterm elections.
295
During that re-
markable period, the political scientist-turned-President sequentially
addressed a series of initiatives. He broke a century-old precedent by
addressing Congress personally, and he made a personal address at the
start of each initiative.
296
291
Prompted by reports of Wilsons views, Benjamin Anderson, Jr. wrote Wilson on
behalf of himself and Clark. Clark, though Republican, had endorsed Wilson. Anderson
explained that Clark had trusted potential competition in 1901, but now thought that
nothing could regulate competition short of actual competition, on a considerable scale,
and in all important markets;only dynamite could break an existing trust. Anderson to
Wilson, Oct. 5, 1912, 25 PWW, supra note 5, at 420, 421. The letter said that Clark had
endorsed Wilson in the belief that Wilson would pursue effective antitrust remedies. See
Clark, supra note 248, at 894.
292
According to a press report, McReynolds had wanted a receiver appointed to sell
parts of American Tobaccos business. When defendants counsel objected that a receivers
sale would be conscation, McReynolds replied: Since when has property illegally and
criminally acquired come to have any rights?See, e.g., J.C. McReynolds, the New Preceptor for
the Trusts, N.Y. Times, Mar. 9, 1913, at 56. See also Link, New Freedom, supra note 284,
at 11617 (Wilson appointed McReynolds knowing only that he had the reputation of
a bitter foe of monopoly).
293
To Hit Tobacco Trust by Taxing, N.Y. Times, June 4, 1913, at 1; Wilson Passed on Tobacco
Tax Plan, N.Y. Times, June 7, 1913, at 1; MReynolds to Ask Real Dissolutions, N.Y. Times,
Dec. 10, 1913, at 5.
294
Wilson also rebuffed U.S. Steels attempt, soon after he took ofce, to settle the
pending case in a way that would leave the rm intact. Link, New Freedom, supra note
284, at 419. Fewer antitrust cases would in fact be initiated under Wilson than under Taft.
Tafts last twelve months in ofce had witnessed 28 new cases. Perhaps reecting the time
to start new litigation or perhaps reecting the weight of the litigation bequeathed by
Taft, Wilsons rst year witnessed only 13 new cases, and his second year only 10. Antitrust
Laws, supra note 84, at 10613.
295
James Miller Leake, Four Years of Congress,11Am. Pol. Sci. Rev. 252, 254 (1917).
296
Link, New Freedom, supra note 284, at 15253.
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal52
Wilson rst secured tariff reform. He called tariff protection the soil
in which trade combinations and combinations of manufacturers most
readily grew, and most rankly; domestic competition could be more
readily suppressed when a tariff shield limited foreign competition.
297
Then, with key input from Brandeis, he obtained a banking law that
created the Federal Reserve Board.
298
This, he said, created a democracy
of credit,”“a currency which comes into existence in response to the
call of every man who can show a going business and a concrete basis
for extending credit to him, however obscure or prominent he may
be, however big or little his business transactions.
299
Next he turned
to antitrust.
300
A. Wilsons Call to Arms
Wilson announced his antitrust initiative to Congress on January 20,
1914. Quoting multiple Democratic platforms, he declared: We are all
agreed that private monopoly is indefensible and intolerable.’”
301
But
as he sometimes had softened his 1912 rhetoric, Wilson now said [t]he
antagonism between business and government is over.
302
Wilson
repeated his calls for individual liability (his most popular line) and for
denitions to explicitly and item by item describe violations with such
clarity as to practically eliminate uncertainty, the law itself and the
penalty being made equally plain.
303
Tracking the 1912 platform, he
proposed to address holding companies, price discrimination and inter-
locking directorates (but dropped the demand to limit corporate size).
304
Further, he proposed an investigatory and advisory agency that would
aid courts (in formulating dissolution decrees), and he particularly high-
lighted aid that it would give to business.
297
Wilson to House Speaker Oscar W. Underwood, Oct. 17, 1914, 31 PWW, supra note
5, at 168, 169.
298
Link, New Freedom, supra note 284, at 212.
299
Wilson to Underwood, supra note 297, at 17172.
300
Signicant prior analyses of this legislative history include Lande, supra note 25, at
10626; Eugene R. Baker & Daniel J. Baum, Section 5 of the Federal Trade Commission Act:
A Continuing Process of Redenition,7Vill. L. Rev. 517 (1962); Sanders, supra note 172,
ch. 8; James, supra note 190, ch. 3; George Rublee, The Original Plan and Early History of
the Federal Trade Commission,11Proc. Acad. Pol. Sci. 114 (1926); Gilbert Montague,
Unfair Methods of Competition,25Yale L.J. 20 (1915); Neil W. Averitt, The Meaning of Unfair
Methods of Competition in Section 5 of the Federal Trade Commission Act,21B.C. L. Rev.
227 (1980).
301
H.R. Doc. No. 625, 63d Cong., 2d Sess. 5 (1914). See also supra note 247 and accompany-
ing text (platforms).
302
H.R. Doc. No. 625, supra note 301, at 4.
303
Id. at 67; Five Trust Bills in Wilson Plan, N.Y. Times, Jan. 21, 1914, at 1.
304
H.R. Doc. No. 625, supra note 301, at 68. See also supra note 248 (platforms).
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
2003] Origins of the FTC 53
And the business men of the country desire something more than
that the menace of legal process in these matters be made explicit and
intelligible. They desire the advice, the denite guidance and informa-
tion which can be supplied by an administrative body, an interstate
trade commission.
The opinion of the country would instantly approve of such a commis-
sion. It would not wish to see it empowered to make terms with monop-
oly or in any sort to assume control of business, as if the Government
made itself responsible. It demands such a commission only as an
indispensable instrument of information and publicity, as a clearing
house for the facts by which both the public mind and the managers
of great business undertakings should be guided, and as an instrumen-
tality for doing justice to business where the processes of the courts or
the natural forces of correction outside the courts are inadequate to
adjust the remedy to the wrong in a way that will meet all the equities
and circumstances of the case.
305
Indeed, Wilson so convincingly touted the proposed agencysroleasan
aid to business that he would later have to deny that the commission
could immunize conduct from Justice Department prosecution.
306
B. The Five Brothers and the Legislative Hearings
1. The Participants
Although Wilson asked Chairman Henry Clayton of the House Judi-
ciary Committee to draft a unied antitrust package, both chambers
bifurcated responsibility for the legislation. Each referred a commission
bill to its Commerce Committee and provisions of the future Clayton
Act to its Judiciary Committee. Each had separate debates and two sets
of managers. The Senate Judiciary Committee even met as the full Senate
debated the commission bill.
307
There were also cross-currents within the administration. Attorney
General McReynolds, presumably fearing interference with his Justice
305
Id. at 6.
306
Wilson would note surprise over suggestions that there was considerable confusion
as to just what the functions of the commission would be, and as to whether there would
be a conict between its duties and those of the other branches of the Government.
Trade Commission to Smell Around, Wilsons Homely Phrase for Pursuit of the Anti-trust Rat
by the Proposed Board, N.Y. Times, Jan. 27, 1914, at 7. The confusion extended to Senator
Newlands. Newlands to Wilson, Mar. 5, 1914, 29 PWW, supra note 5, at 317, 318 (seeking
clarication). Representative Harry Covington said on May 19, as the House debate began,
that certain big business men and their lawyers . . . began to hail the message as the
forerunner of a statute that would enable them to propose to a Government commission
their plans for exploitation . . . and obtain, perchance, that individual approval which
would mean individual immunity at a later date... 51 Cong. Rec. 8840 (1914).
307
See Allyn A. Young, The Sherman Act and the New Anti-Trust Legislation: II,23J. Pol.
Econ. 305, 30809 (1915), 51 Cong. Rec. 11,534 (1914).
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal54
Department, was among those who urged delay.
308
His hostility (which
would plague the Commission after Wilson placed him on the Supreme
Court
309
) was no secret. The press soon reported that he doubted the
agencys constitutionality.
310
Joseph E. Davies, Wilsons Commissioner of Corporations, advocated
a commission that he expected to head. Davies, who had undergraduate
training in economics, had been a district attorney and private prac-
titioner. He moved to the national stage when he helped Wilson win
the Wisconsin primary, and then managed his western campaign.
311
In
1913, Davies recommended a series of proposals, including various spe-
cic prohibitions.
312
He also proposed a commission to investigate Sher-
man Act violations, conduct hearings, prescribe such reformations as
are necessary, . . . serve notice on the offending corporation to comply
with such ndings within sixty days or more, and report non-compliance
to the Justice Department.
313
Louis Brandeis, whose sole government position at the time was as
special counsel to the ICC in a national railroad rate case, nonetheless
became an administration spokesman for antitrust legislation. In Decem-
ber 1913, he provided advice on antitrust legislation to Interior Secretary
Franklin Knight Lane (a former ICC Chairman) and Treasury Secretary
308
See Link, New Freedom, supra note 284, at 446. A potential for interference was in
language (which survived into the nal act and remains today) that authorized the commis-
sion to investigate and report on antitrust orders, perhaps second-guessing the Department.
H.R. 15613, 83d Cong., 2d Sess. (Apr. 13, 1914), § 13; 15 U.S.C. § 46(c). Representative
Covington even declared that the Commissions investigative power would prevent Justice
Department laxity. 51 Cong. Rec. 8845 (1914). Another likely concern was Wilsons
statement that the commission might propose orders in Department litigation by indepen-
dent suggestion. A far narrower provision survived in the nal bill, under which a court
could appoint the commission a special master to address antitrust remedies. 15 U.S.C.
§ 47. In practice, this narrow provision was used only once, by Judge Learned Hand. See
United States v. Corn Prods. Ref. Co, 234 F. 964, 1018 (S.D.N.Y. 1916).
309
McReynolds rejected the FTCs position in whole or large part during each of the
Commissions rst eight appearances before the Court, between 1920 and 1926. During
those years, he wrote four majority decisions in whole or large part adverse to the agency.
See, e.g., FTC v. Gratz, 253 U.S. 421 (1920); FTC v. Western Meat Co., 272 U.S. 554 (1926).
He also wrote two dissents from holdings favorable to the Commission. See, e.g., FTC v.
Beech-Nut Packing Co., 257 U.S. 441 (1922).
310
Flaw in Trade Board?, N.Y. Times, Feb. 20, 1914, at 1.
311
Elizabeth K. MacLean, Joseph E. Davies: Envoy to the Soviets 1013 (1992). See
also Elizabeth K. MacLean, Joseph E. Davies 5758 (1986) (unpublished Ph.D. dissertation,
University of Maryland) [hereinafter Davies].
312
For example, adopting a Brandeis proposal, he tentatively suggested that restraints
of trade be presumed illegal where a rm controlled 40% of a market. Joseph E. Davies
to Wilson, Dec. 27, 1913, 29 PWW, supra note 5, at 78, 82.
313
Id. at 84. Davies did not make explicit whether the commission order would affect
a subsequent case.
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
2003] Origins of the FTC 55
William McAdoo.
314
He later counseled McReynolds.
315
Brandeis was the
rst witness before the House Commerce Committee, and he spoke
for the administration before the Chamber of Commerce.
316
His ICC
commitment was time-consuming and much of his work on antitrust
was accomplished by proxy,
317
but Brandeis would provide pivotal input
in the spring, and would later became a strong Commission advocate
on the Court.
318
2. The Product
With the Administration having less than a unied vision, Clayton
developed four bills of a series dubbed the Five Brothers. (The fth
would be the commission bill). The bills included numerous procedural
provisions, as well as substantive provisions governing price discrimina-
tion, exclusive contracts and tying clauses, interlocking directorates and
holding companies. They provided for Justice Department civil enforce-
ment, but the focus was on their criminal sanctions. In keeping with
Wilsons philosophy of individual accountability, those sanctions could
be directed not only at rms but also at their individual directors, ofcers,
or agents.
319
The bills caused substantial consternation. One would have proscribed
agreements, arrangements, or understandings whose participants
directly or indirectly, undertake to prevent a free and unrestricted
competition among themselves or among any purchasers or consumers
in the sale, production, or transportation of any product, article, or
commodity.
320
This free and unrestricted competition provision did
not refer to effects on price and was, if anything, broader than its analog
in New Jerseys Seven Sisters. Like New Jerseys law and many other state
laws,
321
its terms seemed to frontally attack both the Standard Oil rule of
314
See Brandeis to Lane, Dec. 12, 1913, 3 LBL, supra note 4, at 218; Brandeis to Alice
Brandeis, Dec. 5, 1913, The Family Letters of Louis Brandeis 227 (Melvin I. Urofsky
& David W. Levy eds., 2002) [hereinafter FLB] (describing meeting with McAdoo and
noting that Senator Newlands had wanted to meet with Brandeis and Davies, but Brandeis
commuted this sentence to a luncheon with him & House members some time next
week.).
315
See Brandeis to Alice Brandeis, Mar. 2, 1914, id. at 242 (describing his future colleague
on the Supreme Court as a great time waster).
316
ITC Hearings, supra note 185, at 3; Brandeis, Democracy, supra note 197, at 31.
317
See infra text accompanying notes 382387.
318
See, e.g., FTC v. Gratz, 253 U.S. at 428 (Brandeis, J., dissenting).
319
See, e.g., No. 2Comm. Print. Tentative Bill § 4. (The tentative bills are reprinted in 2
Earl W. Kintner, The Legislative History of the Federal Antitrust Laws and
Related Statutes 107480 (1978).)
320
No. 2Comm. Print. Tentative Bill § 1.
321
See supra notes 287288 and accompanying text.
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal56
reason and the Courts earlier directness test. Though Wilson had
invited Clayton to use the Seven Sisters as a model,
322
the Administration
soon distanced itself from the text. Brandeis told the Chamber of Com-
merce that the Brothers were not Administration bills;reecting his
own views, he declared that Wilson sought regulated, not free and
unrestricted, competition.
323
Another source of concern was the price discrimination provision.
Local price cutting was among the unfair methods of competition
in Standard Oil; the Democrats had pledged to address the practice;
and many states already restricted in-state price differentials.
324
The new
provision would apply nationwide, though, and the devil was in its details.
What injury should be proscribed? The January bill reached differentials
intended to injure or destroy a competitor, either of the purchaser or
of the seller; a version reported by the House Judiciary Committee in
May backtracked to cover only those intended to cause wrongful injury,
but still focused on injury to a competitor and not competition.
325
Also, what exemptions should be allowed? Most state laws allowed price
differentials to reect differences in transportation costs, grade, or qual-
ity, and a few allowed quantity discounts or expressly allowed sellers to
lower prices to meet competition.
326
The Brothers bill allowed all of
these except a defense for meeting competition,
327
although Edwin Webb
(who became Judiciary Committee Chairman when Henry Clayton
became a judge on May 25) would say that no such provision was needed
because a price reduction to meet competition would not show wrongful
322
Wilson to Henry Clayton, Oct. 20, 1913, 28 PWW, supra note 5, at 420. Claytons
response to the invitation was not surprising; he was a follower of Bryan and something
of a deep-South liberal.Dewey W. Grunthal, Jr., Southern Congressional Leaders and the New
Freedom, 19131917,13J. S. Hist. 4 (1947) 439, 448 (Claytons politics).
323
Brandeis, Democracy, supra note 197, at 31.
324
Standard Oil, 221 U.S. at 43; Johnson, Platforms, supra note 105, at 169; H.R. Rep.
No. 627, Pt. 1, 63d Cong., 2d Sess. 9 (1914); Laws, supra note 16, at 54 (Arkansas), 64
(California), 87 (Idaho), 12728 (Kansas), 142 (Louisiana), 15455 (Massachusetts), 168
(Michigan), 19192 (Missouri), 20506 (Montana), 21112 (Nebraska), 232 (New Jersey),
256 (North Carolina) 26667 (North Dakota), 28889 (Oklahoma), 34243 (Utah), 355
56 (Wisconsin) and 35960 (Wyoming). Arkansas, Montana, New Jersey, North Carolina,
North Dakota, Oklahoma, and Utah all passed price discrimination laws during February
and March 1913. See id. But see John S. McGee, Predatory Price Cutting: The Standard Oil
(N.J.) Case,1J.L. Econ. 137 (1958) (arguing that the case record does not establish that
Standard Oil achieved its position through predatory price cutting).
325
No. 1Comm. Print. Tentative Bill ; H.R. 15657 as Reported by the House Committee on the
Judiciary (May 6, 1914) § 2.
326
Wyoming allowed a meeting competition defense, New Jersey allowed quantity dis-
counts, and California allowed both. See generally Laws, supra note 16.
327
See No. 1Comm. Print. Tentative Bill. These provisions survived into the nal House
bill. H.R. 15657 as Agreed upon in the Committee of the Whole House ( June 2, 1914).
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
2003] Origins of the FTC 57
intent.
328
The result was a potentially complex provision that threatened
to criminalize routine transactions.
In addition to problems of inclusion, there were questions of exclu-
sion. Wilsons comprehensive item by itemdenitions never emerged.
Perhaps most glaringly, Section 7 of the Clayton Act was (and would
remain until 1950) a holding company provision, limited to stock
and not asset acquisitions.
329
Though the House Report reserved special
opprobrium for holding companies,
330
it remains notable that Congress
made no attempt to set standards for asset acquisitions in an antitrust
package touted as comprehensive.
331
3. The Fading Momentum
Business quickly became skeptical that the Clayton bill would lead to
clarity.
332
Smaller business, supposedly beneciaries of the legislation,
came to fear that its criminal sanctions might be turned on them.
333
The
bills problems were further exacerbated because a recession began when
Wilson took ofce and was now worsening.
334
With the bills progress
328
51 Cong. Rec. 9389 (1914).
329
See FTC. v. Western Meat Co., 272 U.S. 554 (1927) (Commission could not reach
asset acquisitions under Clayton Act § 7, even if acquirer rst purchased the stock of the
acquired corporation); Arrow-Hart & Hegeman Elec. Co. v. FTC, 291 U.S. 587 (1934)
(Commission could not order divestiture if it challenged a stock acquisition and, during
litigation, the companies effected an asset acquisition); FTC v. Eastman Kodak Co., 274
U.S. 619 (1927) (Commission could not order divestiture in a § 5 challenge to an asset
acquisition). The Celler-Kefauver Act of 1950 nally amended § 7 to reach asset acquisi-
tions. Act of Dec. 29, 1950, ch. 1184, 64 Stat. 1125.
330
The report denounced them as an abomination. H.R. Rep. No. 627, supra note
324, Pt. 1, at 17. Senator Cummins noted that a pyramid of holding companies might
allow majority owners in the top rm to leverage control over rms at the bottom, and
he observed that a holding company could manage as a unit rms that the public mistakenly
took to be competitors. 1911 Hearings, supra note 21, at 1114; 51 Cong. Rec. 14,316 (1914).
331
Senators Reed and Cummins did attempt unsuccessfully to add provisions to the
Senate bill that would limit corporate size. (Reed proposed an absolute limit and Cummins
proposed to limit rms so large as to prevent substantially competitive conditions). These
amendments would have effectively limited corporate acquisitions, but Senator Reeds
amendment drew only 16 votes, and Senator Cumminss amendment was defeated without
a recorded vote. See infra notes 420, 502, 534, and accompanying text.
332
H.R. Rep. No. 627, supra note 324, Pt. 3, at 1 (views of Rep. John Nelson); Gaskill,
supra note 64, at 43.
333
Rublee, Original Plan, supra note 300, at 115; Link, New Freedom, supra note 284, at
434. A Chamber of Commerce referendum, reported on July 15, overwhelmingly opposed
(among other provisions) a price discrimination law. 51 Cong. Rec. 12,737 (1914). The
vote against the price discrimination provision, endorsing the recommendation by the
committee conducting the referendum, was 53122. (A tying clause provision was similarly
rejected, but the referendum overwhelmingly supported a relatively narrow prohibition
of interlocking directorates.)
334
Link, New Freedom, supra note 284, at 44546 (suggesting the recession might have
become a depression had war not intervened).
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal58
further confounded by the question of a labor exemption,
335
the New
York Times reported on March 1 that disclaimers from high quarters had
reduced what little momentum for passage the measures had . . . .
336
On
March 12, Wilson retreated from his commitment to precise denitions,
telling the press that some denitions might introduce uncertainty where
the law had become clear.
337
With elections approaching, the Chairman
of the Democratic National Committee asked Wilson to delay antitrust
legislation. Wilson declined. The matter was debatable as a question of
political expediency,he said, but beyond debate as a question of party
courage and energy.
338
C. The House Debates
1. The Clayton Bill
The House Judiciary Committees version of the Clayton bill included
prohibitions of price discrimination, exclusive and tying contracts, hold-
ing companies, and interlocking directorates. Violations were punishable
by criminal sanctions, which could reach corporate ofcers, directors,
and agents.
339
Consistent with Wilsons declaration that business and government
were no longer antagonists, the committee managed to derive satisfaction
from its observation that the atmosphere of antagonism which such
legislation might ordinarily be expected to encounter has not always
been present . . . .
340
The majority report denounced specic practices
for victimizing both competitors and consumers
341
but did not denounce
large-scale business per se. The bills stated intent was to help business
and the whole people of the country who are related to or affected by
it.
342
Three minority reports represented differing strands of opposition.
335
After Loewe v. Lawlor, 208 U.S. 274 (1908), applied the Sherman Act to labor activities,
see text accompanying notes 4950, the labor movement sought an antitrust exception.
That campaign became part of the Clayton Act debates, and Wilson resisted the broad
an exemption that labor sought. See generally Link, New Freedom, supra note 284, at 42733.
336
Trust Bills Fate Depends on Wilson, N.Y. Times, Mar. 1, 1914. at 12.
337
Press Conference, Mar. 12, 1914, 29 PWW, supra note 5, at 335. See also Press Confer-
ence, Mar. 5, 1912, id. at 313, 316 (denition is always a risky business, since inclusion
of some practices might imply that others were meant to be allowed under existing law).
338
Wilson to William Franklin McCoombs, Apr. 7, 1914, id. at 409.
339
H.R. 15657, 63d Cong., 2d Sess. (May 6, 1914), §§ 2, 4, 8, 9, 12.
340
H.R. Rep. No. 627, supra note 324, Pt. 1, at 7.
341
For example, price discrimination, as practiced by Standard Oil Co., the American
Tobacco Co., and others of less notoriety, was manifestly unfair and unjust, not only
to competitors who are directly injured thereby but to the general public. Id. at 89.
342
Id. at 7.
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
2003] Origins of the FTC 59
One sought a rest from further legislation,
343
another sought Roosevelt-
style regulation,
344
and a third attacked the so-called antitrust bill. . . .
Like a Don Quixote the committee sallied forth valiantly to overthrow
the giant monopoly, but under the pressure of political expediency it
turned aside to assail the windmills of little business.
345
The House began debate on May 25, and on June 5 it approved the
bill in substantially the form recommended by the Committee. The
margin of victory was 27754, with a near-unanimous Democratic vote.
346
2. A (Moderately) Expanded Bureau of Corporations
The House began debating the commission bill on May 22. That bill
was approved, by voice vote, on June 5.
347
Consistent with Wilsons January message (as subsequently claried),
the commission bill envisioned a slightly expanded Bureau of Corpora-
tions, an investigative and advisory body whose advice would afford
only limited protection to its recipient. The bills prime innovation was
to remove the Bureau entirely from the control of the President and
the Secretary of Commerce.
348
It would become an independent agency
headed by multiple commissioners (no more than a bare majority from
any party) with staggered terms and relatively high pay.
349
Writing to a
senator who opposed a commission, Wilson said that business wanted
one and his proposal would gratify them without launching out upon
a dangerous experiment.
350
In fact, the proposed commission would
have little real power. It could investigate, issue subpoenas, demand
343
Id., Pt. 2, at 1. The report by Rep. George Graham and two others argued that business
needed to adjust itself to existing laws, as construed by the Court.
344
Id., Pt. 4, at 14. The report by Rep. Dick T. Morgan argued that many businesses
have become of public consequence, . . . from a national viewpoint have become impressed
with a public use, and in the interests of the Nation should be placed under strict Federal
supervision and control. Id.at23.
345
Id., Pt. 3, at 12 (report by Rep. John M. Nelson).
346
51 Cong. Rec. 9911 (1914). The Democrats vote on the Clayton bill was 2181, 71
not voting. James, supra note 190, at 194.
347
Id. at 9910.
348
H.R. Rep. No. 533, Pt. 1 (Apr. 14, 1914), at 3. An investigation could be triggered,
though, at the direction of the President, the Attorney General, or either House of
Congress. H.R. 15613, 63d Cong., 2d Sess. § 10.
349
The House bill provided for 3 commissioners; the Senate for 5. Id. at § 1; H.R. 15613
as Reported by the Senate Committee on Interstate Commerce, 63d Cong., 2d Sess.
( June 13, 1914). Their pay would be $10,000, roughly $180,000 in current dollars. See
note 22, supra. That compared to salaries of $7500 for Senators, Byrd, supra note 275, at
675, and $5000 for the Commissioner of Corporations, Act of Feb. 11, 1903, ch. 544, § 6,
32 Stat. 823, but $10,000 for ICC Commissioners and $12,000 for Federal Reserve Board
members, S. Rep. 597, supra note 139, at 11 (advocating $12,000 gure for commissioners).
350
Wilson to John Sharp Williams, Jan. 27, 1914 29 PWW, supra note 5, at 184, 18485.
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal60
annual reports from business, provide information to the Executive, and
produce its own reports for the public or Congress.
351
It also could serve
as a master in equity to advise a court about remedies in a government
antitrust case, a potentially signicant but still advisory role.
352
Democratic spokesman Harry Covington deemed the commissions
prime weapon pitiless publicity, to make the man of devious ways an
object of reproach among his fellow men.
353
When that failed, it had
ample powers to promote benecent legislation.
354
Frederic Stevens,
the principal Republican spokesman for the commission bill in the
House, viewed the agency differently. For him, this bill was a stepping-
stone. In the short term, Wilsons commission would study pressing
questions, such as the proper treatment for antitrust purposes of trade
agreements, unions, and exporters, and the benets of national incorpo-
ration. Eventually, the Republican Stevens anticipated that it would
become a Roosevelt-style commission.
355
Unlike Frederic Stevens, though, two Representatives, both of whom
were then running unsuccessfully for the Senate and both of whom later
became FTC Commissioners, proposed a stronger commission during
the oor debates.
Victor Murdock of Kansas, a journalist who came to Congress as a
Republican in 1903, now led the small Progressive Party delegation;
he would later serve seven years as a Commissioner, including four as
Chairman.
356
Mocking Covingtons promise of pitiless publicity,
Murdock saw only an agency that could go hunting in the trust jungles
with a camera . . ..
357
He declared the evil of the pool, the trust, the
351
H.R. 15613, 63d Cong., 2d Sess., §§ 811, 13. The House bill mandated reports from
corporations capitalized at more than $5 million.
352
Id. at § 12. See also note 308, supra (noting that the provision has only been used once).
353
51 Cong. Reg. 8849 (1914).
354
Id.
355
If most of us thought that this measure would remain as it now stands, as a nality,
I have no doubt that none of us would approve it. Id. at 8850. The commission would
study what could be done to allow such cooperation as shall preserve the good without
encouraging the bad elements of society, . . . Negative prohibitory legislation has not
proved effective or satisfactory.Id. at 885152. After § 5 had been added to the FTC Act,
Stevens opposed the Clayton bill for attempting specically to dene any unlawful practices,
rather than relying on the Commission to sets such parameters. Id. at 16,32930
356
After his unsuccessful Senate bid, Murdock endorsed Wilson in 1916 and became a
Commissioner in 1917. He later returned to journalism. See Murdock of Kansas Comes Out
for Wilson, N.Y. Times, Oct. 23, 1916, at 8; V. Murdock Dead; Wichita Editor, 74, N.Y. Times,
July 9, 1945, at 11; Dictionary of American Biography 544 (Supp. 3) (noting that
Murdock introduced baseball slang to sports reporting).
357
51 Cong. Rec. 8973 (1914).
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
2003] Origins of the FTC 61
holding company, and the merger to be the same,
358
and denounced
money overlords who plundered the public estate, fed upon the sub-
stance of labor, taxed the people, polluted the public service, and
perverted the benefactions of the principle of cooperation [and] preyed
upon human life itself....
359
His answer, the Progressive Partys legisla-
tion, was drafted by a committee that included former Corporations
Commissioners Gareld and Smith.
360
It would be endorsed by Roosevelt,
and reected a version of Roosevelts regulatory program that empha-
sized a continuing role for antitrust.
361
Murdocks bill would empower
a commission to issue orders against certain specic practices and other
forms of unfair or oppressive competition.
362
As under the 1914 version
of Section 5, the agency could obtain injunctions for violations of these
orders.
363
Not merely anticipating Section 5, though, the Progressive
legislation would have required the commission to trace the source
whenever substantially monopolistic power existed to determine prices.
If that source was articial(a product of unfair or oppressive conduct),
the commission would use its power to prohibit unfair or oppressive
practices and thereby terminate the monopolistic power.
364
If the
source was natural,the bill provided that the commission should most
effectively and promptly terminate such monopolistic power, while at
the same time safeguarding property rights and business efciency.
365
This might require, Murdock explained, the separation of one factor
of the business, establishing either its independence or its subjection to
the obligation of public service (that is, obligations like those imposed
on railroads).
366
Murdock himself apparently doubted that such remedies
358
Id. at 8976.
359
Id. at 8973.
360
Donald Richberg, My Hero 5254, 56 (1954). The amendment was originally
introduced as a series of bills. H.R. 9299, 9300, 9301, 63d Cong., 1st Sess. (1913), reprinted
in 3 Bills and Debates, supra note 67, at 317278.
361
Colonel Assails Wilson Policies, N.Y. Times, July 1, 1914, at 2. See generally supra notes
139140 (Progressive Party disputes).
362
Murdock explained, The courts have dened, in great variation and elaboration,
numerous business dealings as unfair competition. There is that in the common sense
of fairness and right dealing which indicates plainly the distinction between close bargain-
ing and oppressionbetween pufng of goods and fraudulent misrepresentation. The
developing moral sense in the community adds constantly to the number of outlawed
business practices. 51 Cong. Rec. at 8979 (1914).
363
Violations of orders under the FTC Act were not made punishable by civil penalties
until the Wheeler-Lea Act. Act of Mar. 21, 1938, ch. 49, § 3, 52 Stat. 111.
364
51 Cong. Rec. 8979 (1914).
365
Id. at 9051.
366
Id. at 8980. (Murdock also said that the commission could divide a business into
two or more competing companies, although it is unclear how that could have been
accomplished for a natural monopoly). Id.
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal62
would often be needed,
367
but the bills expansive denition of natural
bases for monopolistic power left open the possibility of wider use.
368
In any event, fewer than one in six Representatives even voted on his
amendment, and it failed, 1449.
369
Democrat Raymond Stevens, who briey became a Commissioner in
1933,
370
then introduced his own amendment to authorize the commis-
sion to prohibit unfair or oppressive methods of competition. It was
ruled out of order.
371
By then, though, Murdock, Stevens, Brandeis, and
George Rublee had held a critical meeting with Wilsonand Murdock,
at least, was convinced that Wilson would support the Stevens proposal
when the bill reached the Senate.
372
D. George Rublee and Wilsons New Direction
The Senate version of the commission bill, introduced on June 13,
included a proscription of unfair competition and authority for the
commission to issue orders to stop unfair methods of competition.
Soon after, the Senate version of the Clayton bill would substitute admin-
istrative enforcement of that bills specic prohibitions for the criminal
enforcement in the House bill.
What prompted Wilsons change of heart? In part, perceived necessity.
His 1912 campaign had trumpeted regulated competition, and he
wanted an antitrust package before Novemberand preferably with time
367
Murdock was a rugged individualist, and therein he differed from many of his
Insurgent colleagues who welcomed the trend toward collectivism in government. Ken-
neth W. Heckler, Insurgency: Personalities and Politics of the Taft Era 37 (1940).
See also Government Control of Meat-Packing Industry, Hearings Before the Comm. on Interstate
and Foreign Commerce of the House of Representatives, 65th Cong., 3d Sess. 237879 (1919)
(Murdocks testimony as a Commissioner on behalf of a recommendation to license meat-
packers, in which he approved the remedy only because the conditions ....compelus
to take that step, because we are moving economically in some new, strange, rather
forbidding elds, and individually I am anxious that we proceed with caution.).
368
Natural bases included control of natural resources, control of terminal and trans-
portation facilities, control of nancial resources, and [a]ny other economic condition
inherent in the character of the industry, including, among other such conditions, patent
rights. 51 Cong. Rec. 9051 (1914).
369
Id. at 8980, 9055.
370
After his unsuccessful Senate bid, Stevens became special counsel to the FTC from
19151917. He later worked for the Government of Siam (Thailand), even serving on
that countrys Supreme Court. He was briey a Commissioner during a break in his service
to Siam. Stevens subsequently became a member of the Tariff Commission, resigned to
work for Franklin Roosevelts court-packing plan, and was soon reappointed to the Tariff
Commission as Chairman. 31 Cyclopedia of American Biography 365 (1944); Hum-
phreys Ousted from Trade Board, N.Y. Times, Oct. 8, 1933, at 24.
371
51 Cong. Rec. 905960 (1914).
372
Id. at 9061 (lively suspicion that Senate bill would include the amendment).
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
2003] Origins of the FTC 63
for Democrats to campaign.
373
The Clayton bill was proving unsatisfac-
tory. The economy was deteriorating. An augmented commission, den-
ing standards through orders that had, at most, indirect punitive
signicance, offered a palatable quick x.
This commission might appeal to Roosevelt supporters, both those who
preferred Roosevelts own regulatory approach and those who viewed
antitrust more favorably. Roosevelt himself was back from Brazil and
agitating for progressive reform. When Senator Henry Hollis asked Wil-
son to defer antitrust legislation, Wilson replied on June 2 that they
could afford not the least hesitation or lack of courage on this point
which is going to be the point of attack during the campaign, as Mr.
Roosevelt has kindly apprised us.
374
One way to draw progressive voters
was to adopt a part of the Progressive Party program reected in the
Murdock bill.
375
A commission also held appeal to the business constituency that Wilson
had courted in Januaryand was continuing to court, in June 1914,
when he selected controversial nominees to the new Federal Reserve
Board.
376
Many businessmen supported a commission, often hoping for
a business-friendly agency that might (despite Wilsons disclaimers)
approve contracts and agreements in advance.
377
While the business
community had many components,
378
Wilson might appeal broadly to
that community by strengthening the commission bill and weakening a
worrisome Clayton bill.
The immediate impetus for Section 5, though, came from Rublee.
Rublee had been a brilliant dilettante. He graduated from Harvard
College and Law School, taught at the Law School, and worked on
the creation of U.S. Steel. He then became independently wealthy and
periodically relocated to Europe for extended leisure or study.
379
Rublee
373
See, e.g., Pass Trust Bills by July 1, The Plan, N.Y. Times, May 5, 1914, at 12 (noting
Wilsons hope for adjournment by July 1, although others expected the session to run
through July).
374
Wilson to Henry French Hollis, June 2, 1914, 30 PWW, supra note 5, at 134.
375
Scott James argues that the principal appeal of what James called a Progressive Party
commissionwas its attraction to Roosevelt voters. James, supra note 190, at 17678, 183.
376
Wilsons nominees included businessman Thomas Jones and Wall Street banker Paul
R. Warburg. Democratic opposition from Senators like James Reed proved so strong that
Jones withdrew, apparently at Wilsons behest, and Wilson lashed out at members of his
own party on July 20. Wilson stood by Warburg and the Senate conrmed him on August
7, as it turned to the Clayton bill. Link, New Freedom, supra note 284, at 45057.
377
Link, New Freedom, supra note 284, at 435.
378
See Wiebe, supra note 150.
379
McClure, supra note 131, chs. 13. Rublee and his wife received $40,000 (approxi-
mately $750,000 in current dollars) from her father, and made fortuitous investments. Id.
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal64
was a knight errant who became energized when he was caught up
in the progressive movement in 1910.
380
After he assisted Brandeis in
progressive causes, Rublee was brought into Rooseveltscampasan
adviser by two college friends: Herbert Croly (who coined the phrase
New Nationalism and later founded the New Republic) and Learned
Hand.
381
Rublee contacted Brandeis seeking more unpaid public work in
September 1913.
382
Brandeis anticipated time-consuming ICC hearings,
which would lead him to begrudge the time which trusts & kindred
legislation are taking.
383
He did not seem troubled by Rublees ties to
Roosevelt. Roosevelt partisans did not necessarily share their candidates
hostility to the Sherman Act
384
; Rublee himself appears to have accepted
the statutes goals,
385
although his views are obscured by his tendency to
tailor his presentation to his audience.
386
In any event, Brandeis decided
at 6466. The Rublees social acquaintances included the Wilsons. See Ellen Axxon Wilson
to Wilson, Oct. 20, 1913, 28 PWW, supra note 5, at 391, 392 (Wilsons wife dined with
Rublees despite her “fierce indignation over Juliet Rublees bad behavior).
380
McClure, supra note 131, at 144 (quoting Dean Acheson).
381
Id. at chs. 45.
382
See Brandeis to Norman Hapgood, Sept. 30, 1913, 3 LBL, supra note 4, at 183.
383
Brandeis to Alfred Brandeis, Feb. 22, 1914, 3 LBL, supra note 4, at 246. See also ITC
Hearings, supra note 185, at 3 (apologizing for not scrutinizing the bill about which he
testied); note 314, supra.
384
See supra notes 138140. Brandeiss own 1912 campaign writings on Wilsons behalf
were published, as articles and unsigned editorials, by Colliers editor Norman Hapgood
who had supported Roosevelt during the primaries. Gunther, supra note 131, at 22829;
Strum, supra note 186, at 20102.
385
Rublee wrote Hand that he agreed with all the Supreme Courts decisions prohibiting
conduct under the Sherman Act. Rublee to Hand, May 8, 1914, Learned Hand Collection,
Harvard Law School, box 107, folder 2. (The letter was apparently misdated; it refers in
the past tense to a meeting with Wilson that took place on May 21). Although this appears
an overstatement in light of Rublees efforts to legalize resale price maintenance, see 51
Cong. Rec. 14,78689 (1914), it likely does suggest some afnity for antitrust. Further,
Rublee, Hand, and Herbert Croly earlier had worked on a proposed Progressive Party
platform. A typed text, perhaps prepared by Rublee, said that The Sherman Act was
passed to establish such control and to prevent the exploitation of the consumer by
monopolies and oppressive combinations. Its purpose is benecial and it should be pre-
served, . . . The typed text then objects to the way the act was implemented, but not to
its goal: but control cannot be successful which only operates after the event and by
means of litigation. Besides, it is a just complaint that capital cannot know in advance the
limits of lawful cooperation and combination. Progressive Party platform drafts, folder
6, Progressive Party Archives, Harvard University. (One of the authors crossed out the
latter text and substituted language more critical of the Sherman Act).
386
For example, to Wilson, Rublee described a commission as a way to regulate competi-
tion and not monopoly, fullling the Presidents campaign promises. George Rublee,
Memorandum Concerning Section 5 of the Bill to Create a Federal Trade Commission,
Wilson Papers, Lib. Cong., File 60, Reel 208. To Hand, he wrote that his goal was to put[]
over the [Progressive Party] idea of giving the Trade Commission power to prevent unfair
competition,and to kill the nonsense in the other bills.Rublee to Hand, May 31, 1914,
Hand Papers, supra note 385, box 107, folder 2, quoted in McLure, supra note 131, at 158.
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
2003] Origins of the FTC 65
to take advantage of his friends skills.
387
He asked Rublee to assist on
antitrust legislation.
Perhaps disingenuously, Rublee claimed to focus on a regulatory
agency only when he saw the Clayton billsdeciencies.
388
He drafted
the bill introduced by Raymond Stevens, a friend to both himself and
Brandeis,
389
and sought Section 5 as a substitute for, not a supplement
to, the substantive provisions of the Clayton Act.
390
He tried to interest
McReynolds in the bill, but the Attorney General discouraged him.
391
Commissioner of Corporations Davies was cool to the proposal despite
his past support for a prosecutorial commission (support likely unknown
to Rublee).
392
Having failed to win over subordinates, Rublee said that
he arranged through Stevens to meet with Wilson himself; that he rst
alerted Brandeis to his efforts on behalf of a prosecutorial commission
when he invited Brandeis to the meeting; and that Brandeis reserved
the right to object to the proposalbut was then so impressed by Rublee
that he joined Rublee in persuading Wilson to support Section 5.
393
Rublees recollections are imprecise in specics,
394
and he may have
overestimated Brandeiss initial resistance to a prosecutorial agency.
395
387
A biographer sums Rublee up thus: When aroused by the opportunity to affect a
meaningful change, Rublees unyielding determination led him to heroic efforts and
allowed him to hazard unconventional, even daring methods to win a contest. Combined
with his inuential relations on Wall Street, his association with leading journalists and
publishers and with progressive members of both the major political parties, Rublee was
a resourceful and resilient competitor who did not shrink from openly or surreptitiously
challenging industrial magnates, senators and even presidents for control of public policy.
His ability to survive such contests was often the result of thoughtful strategy and quiet
inuence. McClure, supra note 131, at 45. Hand wrote, I should not want to have to
cooperate with [Rublee] in matters about which he felt strongly. I should be submerged
by a stronger will, and a kind of concentration of purpose, which I have never experienced
in another. Hand to Felix Frankfurter, Jan. 10, 1916, Hand Papers, supra note 385, box
104, folder 5.
388
Original Plan, supra note 300, at 11516.
389
Rublee had persuaded the New Hampshire Progressives not to challenge Stevenss
Democratic candidacy in 1912. McClure, supra note 131, at 130. After the election, Brandeis
wrote the House Majority Leader to recommend Stevenss advancement. Brandeis to Oscar
Underwood, May 10, 1913, Brandeis Papers (Louisville collection), reel 32.
390
Original Plan, supra note 300, at 116.
391
George Rublee, The Reminiscences of George Rublee 109, Columbia University Oral
History Project (1972; transcribing interviews conducted in 19501951).
392
Id. at 110 (deeming Davies timid). See also supra note 313 and accompanying text
(Daviess earlier efforts).
393
Rublee, Reminiscences, supra note 391, at 11115.
394
Rublee was over 80 when he gave his Columbia reminiscences. For example, Rublees
account that he obtained the meeting through Stevens, a rst-term Congressman, is at
best an oversimplication; at a minimum, a letter from Norman Hapgood, by then editor
of Harpers, smoothed his path. Norman Hapgood to Wilson, Apr. 21, 1914, 29 PWW, supra
note 5, at 481.
395
See supra text accompanying notes 216218.
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal66
Still, Rublee was the driving force behind the Commissions prosecutor-
ial authority, and he clearly made an effective presentation when he rst
met with Wilson and Brandeis on May 21.
396
Brandeis was troubled by
the state of the antitrust legislation by the time of the meeting,
397
and
was apparently persuaded at the meeting that Section 5 held more prom-
ise than any other program for which he could hope.
398
Wilson himself
was soon offering specics to justify retreating from his earlier calls for
specically dened antitrust violations.
399
396
See supra note 372 and accompanying text (Murdocks remark that Wilson likely
would support a prosecutorial commission). Further, Senator Hollis wrote Wilson between
the rst meeting, which he did not attend, and the second, which he did attend. Wilson
answered that Brandeis, Rublee, and Stevens had shown him how to address the only
really debatable part of the Clayton bill. Wilson to Hollis, May 30, 1914, 30 PWW, supra
note 5, at 134.
397
Brandeis called the Clayton bill very bad legislation. Brandeis to Alice Brandeis,
June 10, 1914, FLB, supra note 314, at 252, 253. Likely specics include the following.
First, he openly criticized the bills interlocking directorate provision. Having recently
written a muckraking book about the so-called money trust, see supra note 24 and
accompanying text, Brandeis wanted to condemn interlocking directorships not only
among horizontal competitors (which the Clayton bill did), but also among rms in a
buyer-seller relation (which the bill addressed only when one of the rms was a bank or
common carrier). See Trust Legislation, Hearings Before the Committee on the Judiciary, House
of Representatives, 63d Cong., 2d Sess. 67982 (1914); Brandeis to James McReynolds, Feb.
22, 1914, 3 LBL, supra note 4, at 246. Second, the bills price discrimination provision
allowed quantity discounts. See supra note 327. Discounts for large buyers were anathema
to Brandeis. (Though he sought to legalize resale price maintenance, he would have
denied protection when manufacturers offered quantity discounts. Brandeis to Rublee,
Nov. 18, 1913, 3 LBL, supra note 4, at 216.) Third, Brandeis may have shared the growing
fears of small business that criminal sanctions for violating the Clayton Act could be turned
on them. See supra note 333. Brandeis might also have been frustrated that the bill failed
to legalize price maintenance.
398
Brandeis detected in Wilson an apparent lack of courage in some industrial lines,
although he deemed it a fault of the mind and not of the heart. Brandeis to Alice
Brandeis, May 21, 1914, FLB, supra note 314, at 248. Thomas McCraw calls Brandeiss
reliance on Rublee, leading to Brandeiss support of § 5, an abdication.McCraw, supra
note 198, at 122. But several factors vitiate McCraws criticism. First, Brandeiss inability
to secure modication of the interlocking directorship provision, see supra note 397,
undermines any assumption that he could have changed specic provisions of the Clayton
bill by more active efforts. Second, Brandeis had earlier recognized value in a trade
commission. See supra notes 215219 and accompanying text. Perhaps he hoped by 1912
that a strong commission might advance his campaigns for resale price maintenance and
limited trade agreements. Third, Rublee apparently did sympathize with antitrust, see supra
note 385, and also supported Brandeiss campaign for resale price maintenance. See 51
Cong. Rec. 14,789 (1914). Finally, general rate hearings were matters of national import,
see, e.g., Brandeis Files His Brief, N.Y. Times, Jan. 3, 1911, at 4, and Brandeis had committed
months before to serve the ICC as special counsel. Brandeis to James Harlan, Aug. 21,
1913, 3 LBL, supra note 4, at 163.
399
In March, Wilson had begun to retreat publicly from specically dening antitrust
violations. See supra note 337 and accompanying text. In July, he gave the example of
exclusive agency arrangements, arguing that such arrangements might have little impact
on competition in urban markets, but shut out competition in rural districts where there
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
2003] Origins of the FTC 67
Once he gained Wilsons sympathies, Rublee apparently worked to
line up congressional support, and then met with Wilson and Brandeis
again (with Senator Hollis but not Victor Murdock now in attendance)
on June 10.
400
He articulated a justication for Section 5 in a memo sent
to Wilson on July 10.
401
That memo became the basis for a oor speech
by Senator Hollis on July 15, and, through Hollis, a signicantpartof
the FTC Acts legislative history.
402
Rublee asserted that he wrote the
conference report, and he apparently wrote Covingtons remarks about
judicial review during the later debates.
403
The July 10 memo explained that the last election had settled that
the trust problem would be solved by regulating competition rather than
monopoly, and that Section 5 was directed to that end.
404
Rublee justied
use of an unfair competition standard to further that end by fusing
economics and morals in a passage that could have come from a 1912
Wilson speech.
[T]he only effective means of building up and maintaining monopoly,
where there is no control of a natural resource, or of transportation,
is the use of unfair competition.
Fair competition is competition which is successful through superior
efciency. Competition is unfair when it resorts to methods which shut
out competitors who, by reason of their efciency, might otherwise be
able to continue in business and prosper. Without the use of unfair
methods no corporation can grow beyond the limits imposed upon it
by the necessity of being as efcient as any competitor. The mere size
of a corporation which maintains its position solely through superior
efciency is ordinarily no menace to the public interest.
405
But, despite Wilsons prior assumptions, specicdenitions could not
encapsulate all wrongful practices. The list would be long and soon
incomplete. Unfairnesswould depend on industry-specic facts, which
would change over time. Denitions would necessarily use, as the Clayton
were a limited number of potential agents. Press Conference, July 9, 1914, 50 PWW, supra
note 5, at 508.
400
In a misdated letter that was written between the two meetings, see supra note 385,
Rublee wrote Hand that his approach was backed by Wilson, a majority of the Senate
Commerce Committee, and House Commerce Committee Chairman Covington (although,
consistent with observations by others, see infra note 473, Rublee said success was delayed
by Senator Newlandss incompetence.). See also Plan to Strengthen Trade Board, N.Y. Times,
June 12, 1914, at 7.
401
Rublee, Memorandum, supra note 386.
402
51 Cong. Rec. 12,14149 (1914) (Hollis speech).
403
Rublee to Brandeis, Oct. 6, 1914, quoted in Link, New Freedom, supra note 284, at
441; infra note 557. His efforts drew both praise and denunciations. 51 Cong. Rec. 11,299,
11,53738, 14,78689 (1914).
404
Rublee, Memorandum, supra note 386, at 6.
405
Id. at 3.
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal68
bill showed, language which would present very difcult problems of
construction to the Courts.
406
A general prohibition like the Sherman Acts was preferable, but the
Sherman Act itself might not reach the mere use of an unfair method,
without more, by a corporation of no conspicuous size. Even if it did, the
Justice Department focused on large cases, and [c]ountless competitors
succumb before relief is obtained.The Department deals with monop-
oly as an established fact; a commission could relieve it of a load of
burdensome work which it is not well tted to perform. Further, as
Rublee explained it, unfair competition was a meaningful standard.
He provided the theoretical underpinning that the term denoted compe-
tition succeeding for reasons other than efciency, and also pointed to
the terms use in Standard Oil, the Seven Sisters, other state laws, and
cases that construed those laws.
407
Perhaps most importantly, by emphasizing constraints on the agencys
authority, Rublee implicitly addressed Wilsons concerns about empower-
ing a smug lot of experts.
408
The commission would have only limited
authority to determine that conduct was unlawful; under the Stevens bill
(and the 1914 Act), its orders would lack force until enforced by a
court. Likewise, the commission would be restrained in nding that
conduct was lawful. A Sherman Act violation was independent of a
Section 5 violation, he argued, so the commission could not immunize
conduct from prosecution under the existing statute.
409
E. The Commission Bill in the Senate
Most House members were likely unmindful of Wilsons change of
heart when they approved an antitrust package on June 5. However,
Section 5 surfaced publicly when the Senate Commerce Committee
reported its commission bill on June 13.
410
In addition to powers provided
in the House bill, Section 5 now proscribed unfair competition, and
authorized the commission to issue orders prohibiting unfair methods
of competition.
Section 5 became the focus of the subsequent debate on the commis-
sion bill, submerging any concerns with such matters as interrm cooper-
406
Id. at 711.
407
Id. at 36, 1720. See also supra text accompanying note 63 (use of term in Standard Oil ).
408
See supra text accompanying note 265.
409
Rublee, Memorandum, supra note 386, at 12 (court would enforce FTC order only if
it was just), 22.
410
A letter from Hollis suggests that he was lining up Committee members until the last
minute. Henry French Hollis to Wilson, June 13, 1914, 30 PWW, supra note 5, at 181.
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
2003] Origins of the FTC 69
ation. The new section drew varying responses, even (perhaps especially)
among proponents of strong antitrust enforcement. Elizabeth Sanders
has analyzed patterns of support from different parts of the country,
with Senators from core manufacturing states tending to prefer no
new legislation (or, if legislation were inevitable, a commission that could
pre-approve business plans); those from periphery agricultural states
tending to prefer a strengthened Sherman Act; and those from diverse
states (including Nevada and Iowa, homes to Newlands and Cummins)
most likely to favor a trade commission that would conduct a more
calibrated analysis of competition problems.
411
The analysis below focuses
primarily on individual, sometimes idiosyncratic, Senators. The rst part
briey explores several opponents and reluctant supporters of the bill.
The parts that follow focus on Section 5s principal supporters, Senators
Newlands, Cummins, and Hollis, examining both their substantial com-
monalities and their divergences.
1. Surveying the Landscape: Six Senators
Most of Section 5s opponents criticized the broad discretion they
understood the statute to convey. However, following Henry Lippitt,
Republican of Rhode Island, some would concede at least limited utility
for the agency if it could shield business activities, providing protection
akin to that which the National Civic Federation had sought in 1908
and Roosevelt had embraced (to different degrees) in 1908 and 1912.
412
The idea had a substantial business constituency,
413
and Lippitt unsuccess-
fully proposed a limited shield, under which the commission could immu-
nize submitters from criminal prosecution.
414
Section 5 also drew opposition or half-hearted support from antitrust
proponents, primarily from agricultural states, who distrusted the pro-
posed agency. The Democrats among these, in particular, were associated
411
Sanders, supra note 172, at 1, 22, 25, 27883. Sanders deemed Nevada and Iowa
diverse because they were in economically interdependent trading areas for San Francisco
and Chicago.
412
See notes 105112, 137, and accompanying text.
413
A Chamber of Commerce Committee (on which Rublee served) had conducted a
referendum of member organizations to determine their views on a trade commission,
posing seven questions and making specic recommendations. Most of its recommenda-
tions (e.g., that there be a commission, and that it reach all rms except common carriers
that were engaged in interstate commerce) were approved by margins of 41 or higher.
The only recommendation that failed (303308) was one that opposed agency authority
to advise in advance whether conduct violated the law. Referendum on an Interstate Trade
Commission, Nations Business, June 18, 1914, at 5.
414
51 Cong. Rec. 13,21719 (1914). The amendment was defeated, 1847. Id. at 13,307.
Lippitt was the ideal Senator to promote what Sanders called a core constituency
approach. Rhode Island led the country in per capita value added. See Sanders, supra
note 172, at 22.
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal70
with the views of William Jennings Bryan, who was now Secretary of
State.
415
Bryanite interests were well-represented in the Senate, where
less populous states had a disproportionate voice. Their votes made
them, in Sanders term, the foot soldiers that saw reform through the
legislature, although, in the commission bill and elsewhere, Senators
from agrarian states often settled for less than they had hoped.
416
Consider James Reed, Democrat of Missouri, a maverick who infuriated
Wilson.
417
Reed denounced wealthy men scheming to rob entire commu-
nities, to crush great business concerns, to bankrupt States, to put out
the res in the furnaces of a hundred factories, and in the end to pilfer
and lch with monopolys cruel ngers from the pockets of the poor
and the needy.
418
His most lasting contribution to the 1914 debates was
an amendment that made it easier to challenge holding companies under
Section 7 of the Clayton Act, changing a prohibition on mergers whose
effect isto substantially lessen competition to one prohibiting mergers
whose effect may be to have such impact.
419
He also proposed to ban
corporations from interstate commerce if they were capitalized at more
than $100 million; to set minimum antitrust nes at 10 percent of defen-
dants assets (taken rst from interests of responsible ofcers, directors,
and agents); and to authorize states to bring Sherman Act cases in the
name of the United States when the Attorney General did not.
420
Reed
criticized Section 5 as vague and its procedures as weak, and he hesitated
to support the commission bill but ultimately did so.
421
However, he
415
See supra text accompanying notes 66, 245. Bryan would resign in 1915, protesting
Wilsons policies towards Germany.
416
Sanders, supra note 172, at 4.
417
Reed worked against Wilsons appointments to the Federal Reserve Board in the
midst of the antitrust debates. See supra note 376; Wilson to Cleveland Hoadley Dodge,
July 19, 1914, 30 PWW, supra note 5, at 288 (Reed and other Democratic Senators who
opposed the nominations acted with malevolent ardour). After Reed later broke with
Wilson in the battle for the League of Nations, Wilson would denounce him as a discredit
to the party to which he pretends to belong. Reed ran for President rather than seek
reelection in 1928. Dictionary of American Biography (Supp. 3) 621, 622.
418
51 Cong. Rec. 15,861 (1914) (Clayton Act debate). See also supra note 159 (Reed on
antitrust enforcement), 182 (Reed on Terminal Railroad Assn case).
419
51 Cong. Rec. 14,464 (1914).
420
Id. at 14,52628. These amendments failed 1636, 1336, and 2139.
421
When he decided to vote for the Senate bill at the end of the debate, Reed said he
did so in the hope that it would be improved by the House-Senate conference. Id. at
13,313. (He did not actually cast his intended vote, though, out of deference to a pair
with a Republican opponent of the bill who was absent. Id. at 13,318). He later expressed
disgust that the conference version did not fulll his expectations: Who ever heard of
creating a commission to determine, rst, whether a man has been guilty of committing
burglary, then to order him to stop, then to give him a right to appeal to a court, and in
the end if he be defeated to solemnly adjudge that he must now stop? Id. at 14,790,
14,802. See also infra note 454 (efforts to dene unfair competition).
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
2003] Origins of the FTC 71
voted against the conference version of the Clayton bill, after rst moving
to recommit it to a second conference that he hoped would produce
legislation more to his liking.
422
The direct substitution of administrative
enforcement for the bills criminal sanctions particularly offended Reed,
because it would take the sword from the hand of justice . . . and supinely
turn the monopolists over to a commission that can not even issue a
civil decree that it can itself enforce.
423
Harry Lane, Democrat of Oregon, attacked the [u]nmuzzled crimi-
nals who are engaged in robbing other and better people.
424
He was
outraged for the hundreds of thousands and millions of people who
were being robbed as they were compelled to accept arbitrarily xed
and unjustly low prices for products of their toil, while . . . compelled
to pay arbitrarily xed and unjustly high prices for what they consume.
425
He supported the three unsuccessful Reed efforts described above, and
himself proposed a ten percent informants fee in antitrust cases.
426
Lane thought a commission illogical and unworkable,
427
but nally
supported the commission (though not the Clayton) bill. He explained
that the commission bill would no doubt pass with all its indirection
and lack of virility, and I, among others, who hoped for better things
along these lines, will be compelled to vote for it. May God have mercy
on our souls.
428
John Sharp Williams, Democrat of Mississippi,
429
earlier had intro-
duced bills to make it unlawful to stie fair competition, to provide
up to ve years in jail for individuals who broke the law with intent to
defraud or to create a monopoly or unfairly to stie competition, and
(with a states rights twist) to require rms in interstate commerce to
422
51 Cong. Rec. 16,152 (1914) (bill should be returned to conference with instruction
to restore criminal sanctions); 16,170 (unsuccessful motion to recommit followed by Reeds
opposition to the nal bill).
423
Id. at 14,227.
424
Id. at 13,223.
425
Id.
426
See supra note 420 and accompanying text (Reed amendments); 51 Cong. Rec.
14,59197. Lanes amendment, which failed, 1438, would have provided a reward of
10% of the nes and penalties recovered in an antitrust case to the rst person who
furnished evidence of the violation.
427
51 Cong. Rec. 11,541 (1914).
428
Id. at 13,222 (1914). See also id. at 16,166 (Clayton Act offered no effective relief
against enormous combinations, who are literally rotting this country, rotting its govern-
ment, rotting its citizenship).
429
Williamss efforts are discussed in George Cullom Davis, Jr., The Federal Trade
Commission: Promise and Practice in Regulating Business, 19001927, at 11822 (1969)
(unpublished Ph.D. dissertation, University of Illinois), and Sanders, supra note 172, at
27879, 286.
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal72
incorporate in the state where they had their chief ofce.
430
Williams
supported Senator Reeds amendment to exclude rms capitalized at
more than $100 million from interstate commerce.
431
But he lobbied
Wilson against any commission in January 1914.
432
Privately, he wrote on
July 27 that the commission bill thoroughly disgusted him, but I believe
in team play . . . . I have quit as far as this bill is concerned and shall
stay quit for fear lest I do more harm if I open my mouth than by keeping
it shut.
433
Publicly, he defended the program vigorously but generically,
announcing that the Democrats would destroy what is plutocratic,
exploitative, and industrially tyrannical.
434
Williams voted for the com-
mission bill, as did most Southern Democratic Senators.
435
He also voted
for the Clayton bill, but rst showed his displeasure by supporting Reeds
motion to recommit it.
436
Moses Clapp, Republican of Minnesota and an insurgent like Cum-
mins, had headed the Commerce Committee before Newlands. He dis-
liked a commission for the Wilsonian (and agrarian) reason that he
feared the inuence business would exert over it.
437
However, he advo-
cated a prohibition on unfair competition to be enforced by the Justice
Department and private litigants in treble damage actions.
438
He later
430
See, e.g., S. 4747, 62d Cong., 2d Sess. (1912), reprinted in 3 Bills and Debates, supra
note 67, at 2423. See also 1911 Hearings, supra note 21, at 250334 (Williamss testimony).
The chartering state would have a sovereign rightto allow evil within its own borders,
but not beyond. Id. at 2507.
431
51 Cong. Rec. 14,527 (1914).
432
See Wilson to John Sharp Williams, Jan. 23, 1914, 29 PWW, supra note 5, at 184
(Wilsons response).
433
John Sharp Williams to Robert R. Reed, July 29, 1914, John Sharp Williams Papers,
Lib. Cong., Box 7.
434
51 Cong. Rec. 11,175 (1914) (characterizing program as constructively conser-
vative).
435
Most of the 22 Senators from the former confederate states, the Solid South, supported
the commission bill. (Fourteen voted for the Senate version; 7 cast no vote, but 6 of
those supported the conference bill; and one opposed the Senate bill but supported the
conference bill). While there was a Southern progressive tradition, see Dewey W. Grantham,
The Contours of Southern Progressivism,86Am. Hist. Rev. 1035 (1981), it is unclear how
many of these Senators were persuaded by the commissions merits and how many voted
out of party loyalty, caucus unity (see supra note 279), or to protect the national party so
they could keep the prerogatives of Senate control. (Southern Democrats chaired three-
fourths of the 28 Senate committees. Lewis L. Gould, Reform and Regulation: Ameri-
can Politics, 19001916, at 151 (1978)).
436
Of the 25 Senators who voted for the motion to recommit (including Williams, Reed,
Lane, Moses Clapp, and William Borah), only Williams then voted for the nal bill. See
51 Cong. Rec. 16,170 (1914).
437
See id. at 13,063.
438
Id. at 13,065. See also id. at 13,050 (complaining party should have a right of appeal
if commission did not issue an order).
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
2003] Origins of the FTC 73
proposed to create a private treble damage action for conduct declared
unfair by the commission,
439
and he voted for the commission bill because
a commission-enforced prohibition was better than none.
440
William Borah, Republican of Idaho, despised the unnatural, irregu-
lar and illegal combinations which are the result, not of legitimate and
natural growth and development, but monsters born of deceit, fraud,
overreaching, overcapitalization, and criminal combinations.
441
Borah
had been a Roosevelt partisan at the 1912 Republican convention and
had irted with Roosevelt-style regulation.
442
By 1914, though, he criti-
cized Section 5 because, whatever Congresss intent, the agency would
succumb to propaganda about the risk of disturbing business, and
then regulate monopoly and somewhat modify its extortions.
443
A
commission could only dull the edge of our activities and our desire
to destroy monopoly, and Borah opposed both the commission and
Clayton bills, in the latter case objecting to the lodging of enforcement
authority in the commission.
444
The commission bill attempted to kill
cancer with cologne water.
445
Unusually for a strong foe of monopoly,
Borah now followed Taft in defending the Supreme Court. Standard Oil
and American Tobacco had stopped the formation of new monopolies,
Borah declared.
446
Once public opinion stirred up by Standard Oil settled
down, it was now known that [the Court] had really condemned every
conceivable form of monopoly against which the people have ever
complained . . . .
447
James May has observed that legislators who embraced classical eco-
nomics, which saw no tensions between the multiple goals of antitrust,
439
Id. at 13,11314. The amendment failed, 1841. Id. at 13,150.
440
Id. at 13,301.
441
Id. at 11,233 (also decrying a property class, living in luxury and power, and another
class, . . . literally living upon the crumbs which fall from the rich mans table).
442
For Borahs support of Roosevelt, see Marian C. McKenna, Borah 11821 (1961).
(Borah declined to follow Roosevelt out of the party. Id. at 12526.) Borah had spoken
of Roosevelt-style regulation with approval in 1911. In the aftermath of Standard Oil and
American Tobacco, Borah had supported a resolution directing the government to institute
criminal prosecutions against the defendants for the stated reason that an effort should
be made fully to enforce the Sherman Act, even though he then expressed skepticism
about the Act, declaring that, we have indeed passed from the age of competition to the
age of regulation and control. 47 Cong. Rec. 3218 (1911).
443
51 Cong. Rec. 15,947 (1914). See also id. at 11,186 (bill would mark the beginning
of the time when the business of the country will be regulated and controlled through
bureaus and commissions, and . . . when the question of competition will be eliminated
entirely).
444
Id. at 11,233, 15,986.
445
Id. at 15,956.
446
Id.
447
Id. at 15,983.
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal74
might devote disproportionate attention to specic concerns, and stand
silent on possible tradeoffs, without necessarily indicat[ing] a desire to
protect only one part of the natural system while leaving aside or sharply
subordinating the rest.
448
Save for Lippitt, all the Senators discussed
above may well have been among those who implicitly or explicitly
accepted the substance of the classical vision, which saw monopolies
as abnormal constraints, and antitrust, in removing those constraints,
as simultaneously promoting opportunity, efciency, competition, fair
distribution, and political freedom.
2. The Commissions Advocates: Overview
Like some opponents of Section 5, its principal supporters criticized
twenty-four years of experience under the Sherman Act. Whether the
fault was intrinsic to the statute, or lay with courts or prosecutors, the
law had not stopped corporate abuse, and it had neither prevented nor
reversed the merger wave.
449
The bills advocates disclaimed an intent
to change the Sherman Act or undermine Justice Department enforce-
ment.
450
They saw merit in the laws approach of proscribing conduct
in general terms
451
(although they diverged as to whether specic prohibi-
tions were appropriate as well). But they wanted a new agency that would
prosecute if the Department faltered, enforcing a exible new standard
that could reach where the Sherman Act might not. Newlands said
Section 5 would check monopoly in the embryo, Cummins that it
would seize the offender before his ravages have gone to the length
necessary in order to bring him within the law that we already have,
and Hollis that it would reach the mere use of an unfair method, without
more, by a corporation of no conspicuous size.
452
The bills spokesmen also shared a common legislative imperative.
Unfair competition and related terms had some common currency,
453
but opponents charged that Section 5 was so vague it unconstitutionally
delegated legislative authority. Even many supporters backed an effort
448
May, Theory, supra note 25, at 299. May particularly associated such views with refer-
ences to supracompetitive pricing as theft,”“robbery, and extortion, id. at 291, as
appeared in numerous statements quoted above. See also supra text accompanying notes
183184.
449
See, e.g., 51 Cong. Rec. 12,03031 (1914) (Newlands).
450
Id. at 11,529 (Cummins), 12,623 (Newlands).
451
See, e.g., id. at 12,024 (Newlands); 12,14647 (Hollis); 11,45556 (Cumminss refer-
ence to unfair competitions myriad forms).
452
Id. at 12,030 (Newlands); 12,146 (Hollis) (using language of the Rublee memo);
11,455 (Cummins).
453
See supra text accompanying notes 63, 95, 102, 231, 324.
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
2003] Origins of the FTC 75
by Senator Reed to dene the term.
454
Although advocates did not argue
that every application of the term was clear (if it were, why have an
expert commission?), and although part of their justication was that
laws already included terms like reasonable rates or unreasonable
time,
455
they endeavored to show that Section 5s standard itself was
clear, with meaningful guides to its application.
Thus, they pointed to economic bases for the term. Hollis, using
Rublees language, said unfair competition was competition by which
rms grew for reasons other than efciency.
456
Reference was made to
a recent article by future FTC economist William Stevens, which declared,
fair competition in an economic sense signies a competition of eco-
nomic or productive efciency.
457
Section 5 advocates also pointed to two elds of law. The rst was
antitrust. Standard Oil had used unfair competition to describe some
abuses with which the trust was charged; courts had issued injunctions
that prohibited specic practices and other forms of unfair competi-
tion; and the term appeared in state laws, albeit generally price discrimi-
nation laws.
458
Even when courts gave no specic content to the term,
its use in court orders was evidence that the term had content.
459
The
454
Reed repeatedly criticized § 5 and repeatedly was challenged to improve it. See, e.g.,
51 Cong. Rec. 12,938 (1914). He eventually proposed to dene unfair competition as
those acts, devices, concealments, threats, coercions, deceits, frauds, dishonest practices,
false representations, slanders of business, and all other acts or devices, whether of like
nature to those herein enumerated or not, done or used with the intent or calculated to
destroy or unreasonably hinder the business of another or prevent another from engaging
in business, or to restrain trade or to create a monopoly; the effort failed, 3032. Id. at
13,234, 13,235. He then proposed a second amendment changing the nal clause to read
done or used with the intent, or the effect of which is to destroy or unreasonably hinder
the business of another or prevent another from engaging in business.That effort failed,
2933, with afrmative votes coming from 12 Democrats and 5 Republicans who eventually
voted for the Senate bill. See id. at 13,312, 13,314.
455
See, e.g., id. at 11,38889 (Cummins).
456
Id. at 12,146.
457
William S. Stevens, Unfair Competition,29Pol. Sci. Q. 282 ( June 1914). See also
William S. Stevens, Unfair Competition,29Pol. Sci. Q. 460 (Sept. 1914); 51 Cong. Rec.
11,23031, 12,145, 16,329 (1914) (quoted by Sen. Joseph Robinson, Sen. Hollis, and Rep.
Frederic Stevens). The article lent a professional imprimatur to a list of eleven species of
unfair competition, including local price cutting (which Stevens thought too dangerous to
allow), bogus independentconcerns, “fighting brands(e.g., low-priced brands, secretly
made by manufacturers of high-priced brands, brought into a market to repel new entry),
and tying arrangements. Stevens was blunt: If there be a sound basis for competition, it
lies in the preservation of the economically efcient and the destruction of the inefcient.
See also id. at 11,300 (critique by Sen. Borah).
458
See supra text accompanying note 63 (Standard Oil ); 51 Cong. Rec. 11,22831; 12,142
45; 12,21920; 12,99799 (1914) (discussions of antitrust decrees and state laws).
459
See, e.g., id. at 11,452 (1914) (Cumminss remark).
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal76
second eld was business torts. There, unfair competition once had
been limited to a practice whereby a seller, perhaps by naming a product
similarly to that of a better-known competitor, sought to palm off
goods. Section 5 advocates declared that the Act was not so narrow.
460
Some courts had broadened the offense to reach other business torts,
and the bills advocates cited Harry Nimss treatise on unfair competi-
tion, whose premise was that the term now reached more broadly.
461
The bills spokesmen shared these substantial points of agreement.
Further, in their very reliance on an expert agency, they tended to break
from the faith of those, like Taft and Borah, who trusted the courts to
construe a exible antitrust standard. At the same time, there were
signicant differences in emphasis, at the least, among the bills spokes-
men, as acknowledged by Cummins and criticized by Senator (later
Justice) George Sutherland.
462
It is to the concerns of Newlands, Hollis,
and Cummins that the discussion now turns.
3. Francis Newlands
a. A Senator and His Commission
Francis Newlands of Nevada, the Democratic Chairman of the Com-
merce Committee, had arrived in the House in 1893, moved to the
Senate in 1903, and served there until he died in 1917.
463
Anticipating
Roosevelts call for a Bureau of Corporations, he had advocated adminis-
trative scrutiny of business in 1899.
464
He had worked with George Perkins
and others in 1911, contemplating a commission with broad licensing
authority. While he had then settled on a more modest proposal under
which a commission would award a seal of approval to rms not guilty
of unfair methods of competition, he had declared himself agnostic
about whether the future lay in preserving competition or in Roosevelts
460
Id. at 12,14245, 12,211 (Hollis and Newlands).
461
See, e.g., Harry D. Nims, Law of Unfair Business competition (1st ed. 1909)
(citing abuse of trade secrets, condential business relations, unfair interference with
contracts, libel and slander of merchandise, trade names, business credit, and reputation);
51 Cong. Rec. 11,228 (1914) (quoting Nims). See also Bureau of Corporations, Trust
Laws and Unfair Competition (1915). Cf. Restatement (Third) of Unfair Competi-
tion xi (1995); International News Serv. v. Associated Press, 248 U.S. 215 (1918) (unfair
competition in transmitting reports taken from Associated Press).
462
51 Cong. Rec. 11,103, 12,98084 (1914). Sutherland, who argued in 1914 that the
proposed Commission was unconstitutional, later wrote the seminal decision rejecting a
challenge to that very constitutionality. Humphreys Executor v. United States, 295 U.S.
602 (1935).
463
See Albert W. Atwood, Francis G. Newlands, A Builder of the Nation (1969).
464
1 Public Papers of Francis Newlands 395 (1932) (Sept. 20, 1899 speech).
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
2003] Origins of the FTC 77
program to regulate monopoly.
465
Indeed, while Newlands spoke out
squarely for Wilsons approach in 1914, the Senator might then have
felt bound to Wilson by party unity (and by his dependence on the
President to secure the commission that he had long sought). Thus,
Newlands might still have harbored doubts about whether Wilson or
Roosevelt was on the right track.
Newlandss exemplar was the ICC, an agency under the oversight of
his Commerce Committee. He deemed the ICC a tribunal second in
importance only to the Supreme Court, and credited it with making
transportation a science.
466
He also justied his condence in agency
decision making by pointing to administrative procedures, specically
the guarantees of a hearing and of judicial review.
467
Newlandss personal
preference would have been to transfer all antitrust enforcement to a
commission from a changing, politicized Justice Department,
468
but he
was a pragmatist. His immediate goal was to establish some sort of com-
mission and start a regulatory process that could later expand.
b. Substantive Goals and Unfair Competition
Whatever personal doubts he may have harbored, Newlands promised
in 1914 that the proposed commission would destroy monopoly, check
monopoly in the embryo, and secure pygmies against giants.
469
His
committee report declared monopoly to be intolerable, unscientic,
and abnormal,
470
and he said the commission would halt abuses that
had sufcient import between the parties and with reference to the
public interest.
471
Newlands sometimes seemed reconciled to growth
that resulted from past abuse,
472
but he anticipated that the commission
would prevent similar abuse in the future.
465
Davis, supra note 429, at 72 (Perkins input); 51 Cong. Rec. 11,094 (1914) (quoting
Newlandss 1911 opposition at present to agency authority to set prices, and declaring
it too early to say whether Roosevelts approach would or should prevail). See generally
Davis, supra note 429, ch. 4 (documenting Newlandss efforts from 1911 to 1914). See also
supra note 139 (Herbert Knox Smiths role in turning Newlands away from positive
regulation).
466
Cummins Report, supra note 69, at 20.
467
51 Cong. Rec. 11,108 (1914).
468
See, e.g., id. at 11,23435; see also id. at 14,274 (applauding Senate action, later reversed
in conference, to delete price discrimination and tying clause provisions from the Clayton
bill and leave enforcement to the commission under § 5).
469
Id. at 12,030, 12,867, 12,939.
470
S. Rep. No. 597, supra note 139, at 10.
471
51 Cong. Rec. 11,109 (1914).
472
Newlands said in 1913 that the results of prior abuse were so interwoven with the
general business of the country as to make men tremble at their disruption. Cummins
Report, supra note 69, at 19 (quoting his own remark on Jan. 11, 1911). He may have
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal78
The agency would proceed under its unfair competition authority.
Newlands did not seem to ponder deeply on the term,
473
and explained
that he initially spoke little on the matter because he did not think it
required much discussion.
474
His intuitive understanding was grounded
in morality. Unfair competition encompassed practices against good
morals in trade and that tend to give competitors unfair advantage and
dishonest advantage.
475
Certain practices shock the universal con-
science of mankind.
476
The moral element appeared in his expectation
that the commission would challenge deceptive advertising claims.
477
While Newlandss benchmark was morality, though, he equated morality
to legal and economic authority, particularly as the debate advanced
and others cited specic authorities (largely supplied by Rublee) in
defending Section 5.
478
Before the debate ended, Newlands found the
very meaning of stiing competition by unfair methods’” in economics
and the law, and he declared that unfair competition in its legal
signicance is the same as the economic signicance.
479
trembled himself. Compare 51 Cong. Rec. 11,109 (1914) (Either you have to break up
these great combinations of capital, . . . or you must adopt some social machinery which
will protect the individual from oppression and wrong) with id. at 12,866 (bill tended to
destroy and not maintain monopoly).
473
Several commentators disparaged Newlands. Brandeis called him the despair of
mankind and attributed his shortcomings to senility. Brandeis to Alice Brandeis, June 6,
1914, FLB, supra note 314, at 250, 251. Rublees views were harsh. See supra note 400. John
Sharp Williams, a political foe within his own party, compared Newlandss thought to a
hummingbirds movements, never alighting in one place for long. Williams letter, supra
note 433. These comments seem generally consistent with Newlandss comments during
the debate. He spent little time discussing specic cases, appending a written analysis of
the cases but declining to discuss it so that he need not weary the Senate. 51 Cong.
Rec. at 11,084 (1914). On the other hand, when a member of the Commerce Committee
repeated Cumminss argument that equated Whites Trans-Missouri dissent to the Standard
Oil decision, see supra text accompanying note 70, Newlands did perceptively argue that
Standard Oil in fact reected the common law that Cummins criticized the Court for
rejecting. 50 Cong. Rec. 48283 (1913).
474
51 Cong. Rec. 11,107 (1914).
475
Id. at 11,084. See also id. at 11,109 (societys interest in the maintenance of good
morals).
476
Id. at 12,980. See also id. at 11,108 (You can not take a body of ve men, intelligent
men, composed as this body will be of lawyers, economists, publicists, and men experienced
in industry, who will not be able to determine justly whether the practice is contrary to
good morals or not.).
477
Id. at 11,109. Newlands predicted that future growth would be fueled not by amalgam-
ation but by the devices of deceit and of cunning and of fraud. Id. at 12,939.
478
Newlands showed hesitation at rst, when he said that the words have a legal signi-
cance, and . . . if they have not Congress can give them a legal signicance, and I imagine
that possibly there would be remedies for all those things either at law or in equity. Id.
at 11,084, 11,113.
479
Id. at 12,211, 12,220 (1914). See also id. at 12,024.
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
2003] Origins of the FTC 79
Newlands also defended Section 5s clarity, perhaps tempted to over-
state that clarity because it faced constitutional attack. I think almost
every well-regulated mind can determine it, particularly where you get
together ve men of capacity and learning and experience .... I see
no difculty about such an organization determining what is fair and
what is unfair . . . in such a way as to satisfy the universal judgment of
mankind . . . .
480
If the standard was so clear, though, why have a commission at all?
First, though an unfair competitionstandard was clear, Newlands con-
ceded that its application to specic practices was not always clear. Some
practices were on the borderland between fair and unfair.
481
Second,
the commission would bring cases and vindicate rights that the individ-
ual, because of his poverty or of his insignicance, is often unable
to assert against these great organized powers.
482
Finally, Newlandss
committee report brought out a point that tended to get submerged as
the Senate focused on Section 5: the commission would combine non-
adjudicative with adjudicative functions, and in its judicial role could
draw on expertise acquired elsewhere.
483
Newlandsscondence reposed in the agency itself, its ability to inter-
pret a standard that Newlands himself had trouble articulating. Although
there is reason to question the depth of his commitment to the regula-
tion of competition as opposed to the regulation of monopoly, his
stated position in 1914 was similar to that of Brandeis. He wanted to
stop abnormalgrowth but, unlike such Senators as Reed or Borah, he
trusted a commission to further that goal.
4. Henry Hollis
Henry Hollis, the rst Democratic Senator from New Hampshire since
1852,
484
served a single term. Hollis apparently interjected himself into
the process of developing antitrust legislation after Rublees and Bran-
deiss rst meeting with the President, became part of the subsequent
efforts to win over the Commerce Committee (of which he was not even
a member), and attended the second meeting that Rublee and Brandeis
480
Id. at 12,980.
481
Id. at 13,149.
482
Id. at 12,030.
483
S. Rep. No. 597, supra note 139, at 9.
484
Congressional Digest, 63d Cong., 2d Sess. 63 (May 1914).
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal80
held with Wilson.
485
He then became a spokesman for the commission
bill.
Much of what Hollis said came, often verbatim, from Rublee. He
adopted Rublees argument that a general unfairness standard was pref-
erable to the specicdenitions attempted in the Clayton bill. He
repeated as well Rublees view that fair competition was competition
which is successful through superior efciency, and adopted Rublees
and Wilsons dichotomy that business success was either the product of
a rmsefciency (and good) or its misbehavior (and bad).
486
Hollis
also observed, in his own words, that unfair competition would not be
discerned exclusively from economic sources; rather, the commission
would look to court decisions and to dictionaries or other authorities,
and the law of unfair competition would develop through precedents
as did other areas of law.
487
Hollis appeared to share Newlandss essential
faith in the workings of a commission. He seemed indifferent to the
standard for court review of commission determinations, presumably
because he expected those determinations to be supported so convinc-
ingly that the standard of review would matter little.
488
Adopting the Rublee memos most evocative phrase, Hollis con-
demned those who competed unfairly as pirates of business, the sort
of language, frequently used by Senators like Reed, Lane and Borah,
that suggested an opprobrium and moral content extending beyond the
mere absence of efciency.
489
Further, Hollis took one more step, which
Rublee had not. He declared, when you have all the monopoly out of
the way the little fellows are there to do business.
490
His terminology
suggests that Hollis (like Brandeis and like Wilson in 1912) assumed
that unfairness underlay much corporate growth, and that once unfair-
ness was eliminated, those left to compete would be little fellows.
Perhaps Hollis followed Brandeis in discounting the efciency of massive
rms, and assuming that markets constrained to operate fairly would be
markets of relatively small competitors. As with Newlands, though, Hollis
broke with Senators like Reed and Borah in trusting a commission to
further his goal.
485
See supra notes 374, 400, 410, and accompanying text; Congressional Digest, supra
note 484, at 174 (not a member of Commerce Committee).
486
51 Cong. Rec. 12,14647 (1914). See also supra text accompanying notes 404409.
487
51 Cong. Rec. at 11,17879 (1914).
488
Id. at 11,179 (describing as extremist the position that commission orders be made
absolutely binding unless the court should think there is bad faith or that the commission
had not used its honest judgment).
489
Id. at 12,147.
490
Id. at 12,146.
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
2003] Origins of the FTC 81
5. Albert Baird Cummins
Albert Cummins, Republican of Iowa, gained local fame in litigation
against a barbed wire trust. He became governor in 1901, reached the
Senate in 1908, and sought the Republican Presidential nomination
(along with Roosevelt and Taft) in 1912.
491
He remained a progressive
through most of Wilsons rst term.
492
However, like most of the insur-
gents, he voted more closely with his fellow Republicans after Wilson
became President.
493
As reected in part by his opposition to Brandeiss
nomination to the Supreme Court, he had drifted to the right (as he
made another Presidential bid) by 1916.
494
As Commerce Committee
Chairman in 1920, Cummins pressed for railroad legislation that dif-
fered sharply from Progressive-era regulatory practices.
495
He served six
years as President Pro Tem of the Senate and became a staunch ally of
Calvin Coolidge. Cummins died in 1926, shortly after he was defeated
by a progressive in a primary challenge.
496
In 1914, Cummins served on both the Judiciary Committee that pre-
pared the Clayton bill and the Commerce Committee that prepared the
commission bill. The Democrats tightly controlled the former bill, as
they had other Wilson initiatives, but things proved different on the
491
Elbert W. Harrington, A Survey of the Political Ideas of Alfred Baird Cummins,39Iowa
J. Hist. Pol. 339 (1941).
492
Howard Allen examined Senate votes from 1911 through 1916. Howard W. Allen,
Geography and Politics: Voting on Reform Issues in the United States Senate, 19111916,27J.S.
Hist. 216 (1961). He rst analyzed nal votes on 12 issues. However, the results were
distorted by the small number of votes and by Democratic caucus unity; half the Democrats
scored over 90% reformvoting records. Allen then examined every roll-call vote for the
covered years and identied 135 as reform votes that were not decided on essentially
party-line votes. (These included 53 votes that concerned trusts). When applied to Republi-
cans, who were not bound by caucus unity, the second scale has a close correlation to
nal votes on the antitrust bills. See infra notes 541, 549. Cummins rated 60% on Allens
rst (nal vote) scale and 80% on the second scale. (Newlands ranked 93% and 58%;
Hollis 100% and 65%.)
493
Jerome M. Clubb & Howard W. Allen, Party Loyalty in the Progressive Years: The Senate,
19091915 (1967), 29 J. Pol. 567, 578 n.13, 580 n.15 (in the Congress that sat from 1909
to 1911, Cummins voted with the Republican majority only 34% of the time; in the
Congress that sat from 1913 to 1915and passed the FTC Acthe voted with the Republi-
can majority 80% of the time).
494
See Holt, supra note 67, at 15558, 166 (discussing Cummins in 1916 and after).
Cummins was joined in his opposition to the nomination by 21 Republicans and one
DemocratFrancis Newlands. Alpheus Thomas Mason, Brandeis: A Free Mans Life
501, 504 (1946).
495
Harrington, supra note 491, at 37075; Hoogenboom & Hoogenboom, supra note
101, at 9294. The bill dealt with the industry after it operated under federal control
during World War I. Cummins proposed, among other things, compulsory mergers of
weak railroads with strong.
496
Cummins Life One of Battle, N.Y. Times, July 31, 1926, at 8.
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal82
Commerce Committee.
497
Although Democrats initially rebuffed Cum-
mins, by March 7 The New York Times reported his role as a curious
instance of the dominant Republican member of a committee bending
his efforts to induce the Democrats to go further than they wish in the
direction of trust control.
498
On July 6, Newlands described Cummins
to Wilson as clear, just and temperate in his presentationalthough
Cummins had just published an article (The PresidentsInuence a
Menace) denouncing Wilsons legislative efforts.
499
Cummins also may
have spoken for many of the eleven other Republicans, mostly insurgents
and mostly Midwestern, who supported the bill.
500
a. Cumminss Pre-1914 Program
If Newlandss earlier pronouncements suggested that he was open to
a Roosevelt-style commission, Cumminss views were more in line with
a typical agrarians. In 1913, Cummins supported a special tax rate for
corporations that controlled more than one-fourth of a national market,
explaining it would target the accumulation of so much dishonest
wealth.
501
Cummins offered several proposals to address the trust problem. He
would establish a commission, give its determinations the same effect in
a subsequent proceeding as though made by Congress, and authorize
it to enforce a ban to exclude from interstate commerce a rm that was
so large that its capital destroys or prevents substantially competitive
conditions.
502
His commission would also enforce prohibitions of below-
497
See Holt, supra note 67, at 112 (commission bill was the only New Freedom initiative
that Republican insurgents helped frameand the only one that a majority of them sup-
ported).
498
Wants Trade Board Stronger, N.Y. Times, Mar. 17, 1914, at 2; Francis Newlands to
Wilson, Feb. 16, 1914, 29 PWW, supra note 5, at 227 (Cummins and Clapp withdrew from
the committee).
499
78 The Independent 350 ( June 1, 1914); Newlands to Wilson, 30 PWW, supra note
5, at 266.
500
Although the insurgents hardly held uniform views, see, e.g., supra notes 437447 and
accompanying text, they tended to vote together during the debates on the FTC Act. On
Cumminss amendment to narrow judicial review of commission orders, see infra notes
510517 and accompanying text, 10 of the 33 afrmative votes came from the 12 Republi-
cans who supported the Senate version of the commission bill. (The other two did not
vote). See 51 Fed. Reg. 13,109 (1914) (vote on narrow review). When Cummins sought a
strong prohibition in the FTC bill against holding companies, 8 of his 16 votes came
from those Republicans, with 4 not voting (although one subsequently opposed a similar
amendment to the Clayton Act). See id. at 12,993, 14,476. See also id. at 13,319 (nal vote
on the Senate version of the Commission bill, against which the votes on amendments
were compared); supra note 67 (denition of insurgents).
501
50 Cong. Rec. 4283 (1913).
502
S. 1730, 63d Cong., 1st Sess. (1913), 3 Bills and Debates, supra note 67, at 311214.
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
2003] Origins of the FTC 83
cost pricing and excess capitalization.
503
Still other prohibitions would
be enforced by courts. Where businesses were competitive or of the
same general character, he would forbid both interlocking directorships
and ownership by a single person or corporation (unless voting rights
were not exercised) of more than 10 percent of the stock in each.
504
He
would ban all shareholding by corporations.
505
However, Cummins drew
the line at Roosevelt-style regulation, opposing government approval of
prices and, by extension, approval of trade agreements that (he assumed)
would entail review of prices they set.
506
b. Cummins and a Commission
Unlike Newlands, Cummins did not suggest that the Commission
should be the sole antitrust enforcer.
507
Further, unlike Newlands, he
had no objection to supplementing the Sherman Act and Section 5 with
more specic statutory prohibitions (although Cummins objected to the
actual denitions in the Clayton bill).
508
For Cummins, Commission
enforcement of Section 5 was simply one way to effectuate antitrust
policy under the power of Congress and the eye of the people.
509
On one Section 5 matter, moreover, Cummins was far more aggressive
than Newlands or Hollis. The question was judicial review, and the
struggle extended through the Senate debates and into the conference.
The nal version of the 1914 Act would require courts to treat commis-
sion factual ndings as conclusive if supported by evidence
510
; it would
be silent on the degree of deference to be accorded to ndings of
law (including ndings that a given practice was an unfair method
of competition). The latter ndings would receive, as Representative
Covington observed, the respect due to those of an expert body.
511
503
Id.
504
S. 1617, 63d Cong., 1st Sess. (1913), 3 Bills and Debates, supra note 67, at 311012.
505
Id.
506
See, e.g., 1911 Hearings, supra note 21, at 187, 195.
507
See, e.g., 51 Cong. Rec. 14,228, 14,253 (1914) (role for criminal law when violation
sufciently clear).
508
Id. at 14,228 (Clayton bills price discrimination, holding company and interlocking
directorate provisions would create a refuge for lawbreakers and monopolists); 14,253
(bills tying clause provision might reach conduct that should be lawful); 14,263 (would
not object to criminal enforcement of a price discrimination provision, along with Commis-
sion enforcement).
509
Id. at 11,236, 13,047 (1914).
510
The standard of review established in 1914 remains in force today. 15 U.S.C. § 45.
511
51 Cong. Rec. 14,932 (1914) (quoting Charles Prouty, formerly a member of the
ICC). See also, e.g., id. at 12,147 (Hollis); FTC v. R.F. Keppel Bros., Inc., 291 U.S. 304, 314
(1934). Cummins was prescient in his concern that courts would soon rein in the agency,
although it is unclear if the agency would have fared much better, at least initially, under
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal84
Cummins had sought more. [W]hen we enlist in a mans war we ought
to carry a mans weapons. . . , and an FTC order should thus have all
the effect . . . that we can constitutionally give it.
512
The Supreme Court
was starting to accord increased deference to the ICC,
513
and Cummins
proposed that the law require that courts extend the same level of
deference to the FTC. The Commerce Committee, with Newlands acqui-
escing for pragmatic reasons, disagreed. It supported a proposal by
Senator Atlee Pomerene that addressed only the agencys factual nd-
ings, making them prima facie evidence of the fact stated therein.
514
The precise meaning of this standard was not entirely clear,
515
but Pomer-
enes intent was different from Cumminss.
516
When the Senate had to
choose between them, apparently acting without clear guidance from
Wilson, Cummins prevailed with bipartisan support.
517
c. Unfair competition and the substance of antitrust
As discussed previously, Cummins wrote in 1913 that the Sherman Act
was intended to reach restraints that failed to leave the competitive
force as an adequate protection to the people, but a Standard Oil anal-
ysis would instead test each restraint by the economic standard which
narrow review. (In FTC v. Gratz, 253 U.S. 421 (1920), for example, the Court held that
the challenged practices fell squarely outside § 5; no amount of deference would have
saved the agency.)
512
51 Cong. Rec. 13,004, 13,045 (1914). Under questioning by Newlands, Cummins
agreed that narrow review would allow a court to reverse the commission if the facts
were such as not, in the judgment of the court, to constitute unfair competition, but he
likely meant, as he said elsewhere, that a court could reverse the commission if the
facts established . . . clearly, unmistakably show that these facts do not constitute unfair
competition. Id. at 13,007, 13,046.
513
The ICC was then 27 years old, its organic statute had been strengthened three times
in 11 years, and the Court was coming to terms with its regulatory power. See supra note 172.
514
51 Cong. Rec. 11,108, 13,066, 13,316 (1914) (Newlandss initial preference for narrow
review, his later acquiescence in broader review to parallel the review he understood the
Clayton Act would provide, and his assertion that he was reverting to narrow review
albeit one where that in his view would leave the court to determine whether the facts
stated in the order constituted the offense of unfair competition”—when he learned that
his information about the Clayton bill was wrong).
515
Cummins said it would reduce the commission to an open door for reaching the
court.Id. at 13,004. Newlands argued that the Pomerene and Cummins proposals might
differ little in practice. Id. at 13,066.
516
Pomerene said, I object to getting ve men together, calling them a commission,
accepting in good faith the fact that they are thereby clothed with omniscience, and
allowing them to create all of this new growth of the common law or to extend it into
new elds which heretofore have not been covered. Id. at 12,874.
517
The vote was 3325. Democrats supported Cummins 2016, Republicans 139. The
uncertainty about Wilsons position is shown by the fact that Wilsons Corporations Commis-
sioner, Joseph E. Davies, later wrote a brief supporting Cummins. See infra note 552.
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
2003] Origins of the FTC 85
the individual members of the court may happen to approve, by each
Justices opinion as an economist or sociologist.
518
The prohibition on unfair competition, which for Cummins was a
somewhat narrow term that did not reach (for example) merger activ-
ity,
519
was similarly intended to preserve the competitive force. Section
5 would stop the kind of competition which has for its object the
destruction of competition. There is no unfair competition that is consis-
tent with the endurance of any competition.
520
Competing unfairly was
like using brass knuckles in a ght.
521
Like Newlands, Cummins some-
times emphasized the clarity of both the standard and its application,
522
but elsewhere emphasized the need for a rule of reason: [e]verything
must be determined by the rule of reason.
523
His organizing principle
was that prices shall be determined by honest competition among those
who are engaged in commerce.
524
For Cummins, a Section 5 analysis would require consultation of a
wide range of converging sources, both legal and non-legal.
525
Cummins
waslesscondent than Newlands in the reliability of morality as a guide.
On the one hand, to Cumminss way of thinking, the United States was
(then) virtually alone in adopting a policy of competition. Antitrust laws
518
See supra text accompanying notes 6970.
519
In Cumminss view, holding companies destroy competition entirelyand interlock-
ing directorates suppress competition, but neither was unfair competition. 51 Cong.
Rec. at 11,103 (1914). (Newlands disagreed. Id. at 11,106). Cummins wanted a commission
to address these threats to competition, but thought that the commission would require
authority (which he sought to provide) beyond § 5. See id. at 12,987, 12,993, 13,11213.
520
Id. at 11,385.
521
Id. at 11,448.
522
Id. at 12,917 (any businessman could identify a particular act as fair or unfair
competition), 12,913 (denying that a court or commission in a § 5 case would be at
liberty . . . to use its own peculiar economic or social opinions with regard to the character
of the conduct under examination).
523
Id. at 12,914.
524
Id. at 12,920.
525
See id. at 12,873 (1914) (no difference between the technical meaning of unfair
competition, as that meaning may be derived from the decisions of the courts, and the
so-called popular meaning), 13,048 (board would consult the decisions of the courts,
the learning of the time, the custom of merchants, the habits of trade, the writings of
studious and thoughtful men, all of which go to make up our understanding of the words
unfair competition.’”), 12,653 (Our language is not made up by the courts ....Unfair
competition means what the people who use the English language commonly believe
that those words mean. . . . Business men are just as potent in determining what unfair
competition means as are the courts; the writers who make our literature, after observing
the affairs of men, are just as inuential in determining the meaning of unfair competition
as are the courts.).
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal86
might thus be violated by practices that other countries might tolerate
or even encourage, and that might be undertaken without any sense
of moral wrong, without any consciousness of moral turpitude.
526
On
the other hand, a moral concept, the civilized sense of mankind,
was a benchmark to identify unfair competition.
527
A seemingly moral
concept also appeared reected in his explanation of why Section 5
reached a palming off offense. Although Cummins did not think that
Section 5 would apply if a railroad terminal diverted business by misrepre-
senting its competitors facilities, he asserted that, If one goes into a
store and desires a thing and through a misrepresentation . . . he takes
another thing he is injured, and the people generally are injured if the
same thing is practiced on them, without regard to the price, without
regard to the quality, of the goods involved.
528
Cummins also saw sheer size as a competitive problem. He acknowl-
edged that some kinds of business must be carried on in large units,
and seemed reconciled by 1914 to markets with only two competitors.
529
But when U.S. Steel controlled over half a market and its competitors
were all smaller producers, those competitors existed at its sufferance.
Size means power; and whenever you reach the power that the United
States Steel Corporation has, you have already touched monopolistic
power; you have touched the power to suppress real, substantial
competition. . . . The company does it merely because it is so big.
530
The proper rule should be fair, reasonable competition, independence
to the individual, and dissociation among the corporations.
531
Though
business should benet from economies and efciencies, [w]hatever
those economies and efciencies may be, they must, however, stop short
of one thing, that is, the power to rule that eld of commerce which
they attempt to occupy.
532
Cummins had said in 1911 that what needed
to be promoted was [f]air competition among business institutions of
526
Id. at 11,37980. Although mergers were not within Cumminssdenition of unfair
competition, for example, Cummins highlighted the difculties of determining when
businesses are competitive for purposes of a merger analysis. He also asked how a court
would decide if a merger of 6 rms in a eld of 12 violated the Sherman Act. Id. at 11,380.
527
Id. at 11,104.
528
Id. at 11,106. Cumminss explanation for why the railroads misrepresentation differed
from the soap manufacturers was less than satisfactory. The latter, but not the former,
was tinctured with unfairness to the public. Id. at 11,105.
529
Id. at 11,45556. The previous year, he had declared that no rm should have more
than 25% of a national market. 50 Cong. Rec. 4283 (1913).
530
51 Cong. Rec. 11,457 (1914).
531
Id. at 11,455.
532
Id. at 11,456.
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
2003] Origins of the FTC 87
substantially equal advantages.
533
In 1914, he again proposed to ban
rms so large as to prevent substantially competitive conditions.
534
Even an economic analysis, then, had to balance the benets of ef-
ciencies against the harms attendant to size. Although Section 5s unfair-
ness must be tinctured with unfairness to the public; not merely
unfairness to the rival or competitor,
535
the preservation of smaller
enterprises was integral to protecting the competitive force. Further,
despite his critique of Standard Oil for incorporating sociological views,
Cummins had explained in 1911 that antitrust would not only prevent
unduly high consumer prices (and thus secure that distribution of
wealth which arises or comes about from fair and decent rivalry). It
would also address another object of danger:thesociological one
the desirability of having as many men as possible who are their own
masters, rather than having a few masters and a good many employees
. . . . building up and maintaining the manhood and character necessary
to sustain a nation like ours.
536
Cummins thus echoed Justice Peckhams
concern about small dealers and worthy men and Brandeis views of
the goals of antitrust.
537
Indeed, he declared:
[T]he people . . . have long ago reached a conclusionand I think it
is practically a unanimous opinionthat we must do something to
preserve free, fair competition in the business life of the United States;
that we must do something to preserve the independence of the man
as distinguished from the power of the corporation; that we must do
something to perpetuate the individual initiative.
We often go wrong, I believe, in assuming that because a great corpo-
ration, a vast aggregation of wealth, can produce a given commodity
more cheaply than can a smaller concern, therefore it is for the welfare
and the interest of the people of the country that the commodity should
be produced at the lower cost. I do not accept that article of economic
faith. I think we can pursue cheapness at altogether too high a price,
if it involves the surrender of the individual, the subjugation of a great
mass of people to a single master mind.
538
533
1911 Hearings, supra note 21, at 524. Cf. 51 Cong. Rec. 11,456 (1914) (need for
competent and efcient competitors).
534
51 Cong. Rec. 14,543 (1914). The amendment was defeated without a recorded
vote. Id.
535
Id. at 11,105.
536
1911 Hearings, supra note 21, at 1584. See also id. at 1110 (while consumers were
chiey interested in getting a good article at a fair price, they were also interested in
another indirect way, namely, the trying to have the business of this country carried on
so that independent men shall be in business whose characters will be developed by the
responsibility which they must bear).
537
See supra text accompanying notes 31, 185214.
538
51 Cong. Rec. 12,742 (1914). See also id. at 11,379 (need to protect individualism
in business, individualism in society, individualism in every eld in which energy and
initiative are required).
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal88
Despite Cumminss emphasis on competition as a regulator of prices,
then, even cheapnessmight be suspectand not merely because large
rms might manipulate the market and ultimately deny consumers the
benets of efciencies, but also due to social harms attendant to indus-
trial concentration.
539
6. The Commissions Advocates: Summary
Just as Roosevelt and his opponents could converge in support of
specic programs, the Commissions principal advocates converged in
their support of Section 5. Newlands had at least irted with Roosevelt-
style regulation and the attendant embrace of large-scale business in
1911, and the sincerity of his later rejection of such regulation is subject
to question. Cummins, in contrast, shared the distrust of concentrated
wealth reected by other agrarian Senators, as well as by Louis Brandeis.
Yet they converged, along with Hollis, in supporting a prosecutorial
commission that would enforce a prohibition on unfair competition.
Further, although Newlands emphasized a moral dimension to unfair-
ness, Hollis an economic dimension, and Cummins an economic vision
with a social component, they also converged in seeing Section 5 as a
way to stop incipient Sherman Act violations or, more broadly, unde-
served growth.
7. Senate Passage of the Commission Bill
On August 5, the Senate passed the commission bill, 5316, and sent it
to conference. Voting under a caucus resolution,
540
forty-one Democrats
supported the bill, two opposed it, and ten cast no vote. Twelve of the
more progressive Republicans supported the bill, fourteen Republicans
opposed it, and sixteen cast no vote.
541
F. The Clayton Bill in the Senate
The Senate them turned to the Clayton bill. Since Congress now
contemplated that the commission would be an enforcement agency,
539
Cummins did assert that an unfair competition analysis would not depend on such
broad sociological and industrial conditions and consequences as would a restraint of
trade analysis. Id. at 12,915. However, he did not thereby preclude more limited consider-
ation of those conditions in analyzing unfair competition, and his understanding of unfair
competition, as noted above, did not include merger activity. See supra note 519.
540
See supra note 279.
541
Under Howard Allens second scale for measuring reformvotes, see supra note 492,
the Republicans who voted for the Senate commission bill scored 58% or above; the 13
who were rated and voted no scored 51% or less.
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
2003] Origins of the FTC 89
the central questions became what substantive provisions, if any, to retain
in the Clayton bill, and how any retained provisions should be enforced.
542
The Judiciary Committee rst removed all the substantive provisions
from the Clayton bill,
543
as Wilson had perhaps intended. Had that action
stood, price discrimination, the creation of holding companies, and
other affected conduct might still have been challenged under the Sher-
man Act to the extent they violated that law; otherwise a federal challenge
could have rested only on the FTC Act. But the Committee reversed
course before it reported the bill to the full Senate. It restored all the
substantive provisions of the Clayton Act, but substituted administrative
enforcement of Clayton Act provisions by the FTC (or the ICC in the
case of common carriers
544
) for criminal enforcement. The bill did create
new criminal liability for corporate ofcers, defendants, and agents, who
could be sanctioned for their rms violations of the Sherman Act.
However, the substantive provisions of the Clayton Act itself could only
be enforced by Justice Department civil proceedings (a possibility often
ignored during the debate) or by administrative proceedings. This was
the change that most aroused the ire of Senators Reed and Borah.
545
Then, when the bill reached the Senate oor, the Committee recom-
mended an intermediate approach. At its behest, the Senate voted to
retain, with provisions for civil and administrative enforcement, prohibi-
tions on holding companies and interlocking directorates. The other
substantive provisions were deleted.
546
Thus the matter stood early in
the Senate debate, although a limited tying clause provision would be
restored in the Senate and most of the deleted provisions would be
restored, in some form, in conference.
542
Much of the debate also turned on the labor exemption. As noted before, that
exemption is beyond the scope of this study.
543
See 51 Cong. Rec. 14,089 (1914).
544
Before the bill became law, the Conference Committee also made the Federal Reserve
Board the enforcement authority against banks. Act of Oct. 15, 1914, ch. 323, § 11, 38
Stat. 730 (codied as amended at 15 U.S.C. § 21). For purposes of this discussion, reference
to enforcement by the commission should be understood to include enforcement by
any of these agencies.
545
See supra text accompanying notes 417423, 441447; S. Rep. No. 698, 63d Cong., 2d
Sess. 4344, 4749 ( July 22, 1914) (explaining that experimental stage of this legislation
warranted substitution of administrative for criminal enforcement). While FTC Act viola-
tions became subject to civil penalties in 1938, see supra note 363, the Clayton Act made
no such provision until 1959. Act of July 23, 1959, Pub. L. 86-107, § 1, 73 Stat. 243 (codied
as amended at 15 U.S.C. § 21(l)).
546
51 Cong. Rec. 13,84849 (1914). The Senate also deleted a provision forbidding
mine owners from arbitrarily refusing to sell to a responsible buyer; that provision was
never restored.
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal90
Other changes were made as well, some narrowing a prohibition and
some broadening one. For example, the Houses price discrimination
language had express exemptions for price differentials that reected
different transportation costs, quality, grade, and quantity. The provision
recommended by the Senate Committee (before it was deleted entirely)
added a meeting competition defense, as well as provision for differences
in selling costs.
547
While this language arguably weakened the bill, the
holding company provision came to the Senate with a prohibition on
acquisitions whose effect is to eliminate or substantially lessen competi-
tion; after multiple changes on the Senate oor, it reached more widely,
prohibiting acquisitions whose effect may be to lessen competition.
548
The bill passed on September 2 by a vote of 4616. The thirty-eight
Democrats who voted all supported the bill. Only seven Republicans and
the Senates lone Progressive joined them in that support.
549
G. The Conference Bills
1. The Federal Trade Commission Act
But for Section 5, the House and Senate versions of the commission
bill differed little. The House, with some encouragement from Wilson,
550
acquiesced in the critical addition of Section 5, subject to two changes.
The rst change, largely cosmetic, was to use unfair methods of competi-
tionto describe both the conduct that violated the law and the conduct
the Commission could prohibit; thus, it was made clear that Section 5
was not limited to palming off offenses.
551
The second revisited the standard for judicial review. The issue split
the conferees and, on August 20, Corporations Commissioner Davies
led a brief supporting a narrow standard of review.
552
Perhaps because
547
H.R. 15657 as Reported by the Senate Committee on the Judiciary, 63d Cong., 2d Sess. § 2
( July 22, 1914).
548
See 51 Cong. Rec. 14,46364 (1914).
549
Id. at 14,610. On Howard Allens second scale, see supra note 492, the rated Republicans
who voted for the Senate bill scored 60% or higher. With one exceptionSenator Borah
the 15 rated Republicans who voted against the bill scored 58% or less.
550
For example, Wilson discouraged Charles Culberson, Chairman of the Senate Judi-
ciary Committee, from seeking to dene unfair competition; according to Wilson, the
term maintained elasticity without real indeniteness. Wilson to Culberson, July 30,
1914, 30 PWW, supra note 5, at 320.
551
Senator Hollis had proposed this change earlier. 51 Cong. Rec. 12,145 (1914). The
Senate version of the commission bill had proscribed unfair competition, although it
had authorized the Commission to issue orders to stop unfair methods of competition.
552
Brief by the Bureau of Corporations Relative to Section 5 of the Bill (H.R. 15613) to Create
a Federal Trade Commission, 63d Cong., 2d Sess. (Aug. 20, 1914). When power to determine
whether a law has been complied with is delegated to an administrative ofcer, the brief
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
2003] Origins of the FTC 91
of personal and international crises then absorbing Wilson,
553
Davies did
not solicit the Presidents advance input; he did, however, send Wilson
a memo urging his position the next day.
554
Anticipating later Rublee-
Davies disputes on the Commission, though, Rublee submitted his own
brief on August 25, arguing that Cumminss amendment neither could
nor did accomplish what Cummins sought.
555
Rublee argued for broad
review, or, at least, broad review of agency determinations that a practice
was unfair.
556
Wilson sided with Rublee, and intervened to convert
Newlands.
557
Since Rublees view was in tune with Wilsons distrust of
experts, Wilsons alignment with Rublee was hardly surprising. The nal
bill, as noted above, required deference to Commission ndings of fact
but was silent on deference to ndings of law, and those ndings received,
as Representative Covington observed, the respect due to those of an
expert body.
558
Thus, Wilsons last intervention in the legislative process
was to broaden judicial oversight of the Commission, and to limit the
potential impact of the smug experts he had earlier denounced.
After brief debate, the conference bill passed the Senate 435. The
Democrats were united, 340. Eight Democrats who had not voted on
the Senate bill supported the nal bill (as did one of the two Democratic
Senators who had opposed the Senate bill).
559
The House passed the
said, the courts have declared (a) that the ndings of fact by such ofcer or body are
nal, (b) that the decision of a mixed question of law and fact is nal unless the question
of law may readily be separated from the question of fact, and (c) that a decision of a
question of law, unless clearly wrong, will not be set aside. Id. at 17.
553
Wilsons wife died on August 6, and European governments began to declare war
on each other on July 28. Link, New Freedom, supra note 284, at 46162; Arthur S.
Link, Wilson: The Struggle for Neutrality 34 (1960). Wilson had virtually no staff
working on legislation, see Marshall E. Dimock, Woodrow Wilson as Legislative Leader, 19
J. Pol. 3, 13 (1957), so his personal withdrawal from the legislative process was tantamount
to withdrawal by the White House. Perhaps Davies decided to approach Wilson on August
21 because the press reported that Wilson had met with Covington, and was thus again
addressing the antitrust package. Press Conference, 30 PWW, supra note 5, Aug. 20, 1914,
at 404.
554
Davies to Wilson, Aug. 21, 1914, 30 PWW, supra note 5, at 427.
555
Brief by George Rublee Relative to the Court Review in the Bill (H.R. 15613) to Create a Federal
Trade Commission, 63d Cong., 2d Sess. (Aug. 25, 1914). Rublee argued Congress could not
constitutionally limit court review of commission ndings within the narrow connes that
Cummins sought, and that, properly applied to commission proceedings, the ICC standard
that Cummins proposed to incorporate would itself lead to broad review.
556
Id. at 5.
557
See Wilson to Harry Covington, Aug. 27, 1914, 30 PWW, supra note 5, at 454, 455.
Rublees brief was the basis for Covingtons remarks on judicial review during the nal
debate. 51 Cong. Rec. 14,93133 (1914).
558
See infra note 511.
559
See 51 Cong. Rec. 14,803 (1914). Eight Republicans voted for the nal bill, including
seven of the twelve who had supported the Senate bill (the other ve failed to vote), and
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal92
act without a recorded vote,
560
and the bill became law on Septem-
ber 26.
2. The Clayton Act
The Senate and House versions of the Clayton bill differed in many
respects, and the conference bill emerged with multiple compromises
and changes. Thus, the conference restored a price discrimination provi-
sion, retaining most of the exemptions in the bill reported to the Senate
but replacing the test of intent to wrongfully injure a competitor with
a test of whether a differentials effect . . . may be to substantially lessen
competition or tend to create a monopoly in any line of commerce.
561
The holding company provision reected a compromise between the
stronger Senate provision and the weaker House provision.
562
Still, the
Senate change that was perceived to be most important survived. The
conference accepted the Senates replacement of criminal with adminis-
trative enforcement, leaving intact the Justice Departments civil enforce-
ment authority (and allowing the Department to challenge the same
practice under both the Sherman and Clayton Acts). The result, almost
inadvertently, was dual jurisdiction under the Clayton Act.
The conference version proved controversial in the Senate. The debate
extended over seven days before the bill passed, 3524, on October 5.
The margin was far narrower than the 4616 vote that sent the bill
to conference. Three Democrats (including Lane and Reed) and four
Republicans (including Clapp) reversed prior support, registering their
disappointment that the bill was not further strengthened in confer-
ence.
563
Three days later, the House approved the conference version
of the Clayton bill, 24552.
564
The bill became law on October 17.
one who had previously opposed it. Progressive Senator Miles Poindexter, who failed to
vote on the Senate bill, voted for the conference bill.
560
Id. at 14,943.
561
Act of Oct. 15, 1914, supra note 544, § 2. See also supra text accompanying notes
324328, 547. One exemption in the reported bill, allowing price differences for different
selling costs, was not in the nal bill.
562
The House version forbade acquisitions whose effect is to eliminate or substantially
lessen competition in a relevant market. The Senate version applied when that effect
may be to lessen competition. The conference bill used the Senate language, but with
the word substantially reinserted. Further, the House and Senate bill also had another
clause, forbidding holding companies that create a monopoly in any line of [trade or
commerce]. The Conference Committee instead applied where the transactions effect
was to restrain . . . commerce in any section or community, or tend to create a monopoly
of any line of commerce. See H.R. 15657 with Senate Amendments Numbered, 63d Cong., 2d
Sess. at 9 (Sept. 3, 1914); Act of Oct. 15, 1914, supra note 544, § 7.
563
See 51 Cong. Rec. 16,170 (1914).
564
Id. at 16,344.
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
2003] Origins of the FTC 93
VII. A ROCKY START
A. Wilsons Plans for the Commission
While Section 5 enforcement authority was the most debated part of
the FTC Act, the agencys mandate extended well beyond litigation. The
Commissions information-gathering and reporting functions survived
from the House bill. Wilson, for his part, highlighted assistance to busi-
ness, a function not even mentioned in the Act, as he had highlighted
such assistance in his January 1914 speech.
565
In 1916, Wilson would
make grandiose, if expressly ambiguous, claims for the Commission. Its
[p]owers of guidance and accommodation . . . have relieved business-
men of unfounded fears and set them on the road of hopeful and
condent enterprise.
566
It is hard to describe the functions of [the]
Commission. All I can say is that it has transformed the Government of
the United States from being an antagonist of business into being a
friend of business.
567
He compared, as well, the Commissions helpful
men to the Justice Departments litigious attorneys.
568
B. The First Wilson Commission
Wilsons most immediate impact would come from his selection of
Commissioners. The Commissions broad but mixed mandate would
have challenged the best complement of Commissioners in the best of
times. The Commission would not, however, start in the best of times.
World War I would temporarily result in virtual abandonment of anti-
trust. The exigencies of wartime mobilization drove the country to
embrace broad economic regulation under the lead of Bernard Baruchs
War Industries Board and Herbert Hoovers Food Administration.
569
The
Commission itself would struggle to nd a role, and would largely serve
as a cost-nding agency for the government.
570
565
See supra text accompanying note 306.
566
Speech accepting the Democratic Nomination, Sept. 2, 1916, 38 PWW, supra note 5,
at 126.
567
Address, Sept. 25, 1916, 38 PWW, supra note 5, at 261, 265.
568
See supra text accompanying note 6. At the same time, Commissioners were quoting
from Wilsons January 1914 speech about the Commissions role in offering guidance to
industry. See Edward Hurley, Some Business Problems of Today, Dec. 1, 1915, and William
Harris, The Work of the Federal Trade Commission, Apr. 4, 1916, FTC General Records, Box
146, National Archives.
569
See, e.g., Robert D. Cuff, The War Industries Board: Business-Government
Relations During World War I (1973); Robert A. Himmelberg, The War Industries Board
and the Antitrust Question in November 1918,52J. Am. Hist. 59, 60 (1965).
570
W.H.S. Stevens, What Has the Federal Trade Commission Accomplished,15Am. Econ. Rev.
625, 63637 (1925).
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal94
Nor were Wilsons initial selections the best complement of Commis-
sioners. When Brandeis declined an appointment,
571
the Commission
lost the chance to gain the instant stature that the ICC had obtained in
1887 when its initial Commissioners included Thomas M. Cooley, a
distinguished law professor, former Chief Justice of the Michigan
Supreme Court, and author of some of the most signicant treatises
of the nineteenth century. Most signicantly, as the contrast between
Commission men and Justice Department lawyers shows, the President
had not shaken his distrust of attorneys.
572
Nor did economists fare better.
Wilson dismissed those tedious persons,
573
and, though he appointed
some to other agencies, he named none to the Commission.
574
Wilsons
selections were driven in part by geographic diversity,
575
and at least one
primarily by patronage.
Wilsons favored selection (as shown by his receipt of the longest term)
was Corporations Commissioner Joseph E. Davies. Although Daviess
appointment was widely expected,
576
his credentials were hardly those
of a Cooley or Brandeis; he had been a district attorney and built a
private practice before joining Wilsons campaign. The other lawyer was
Rublee. Rublee was nominated to the short three-year seat and, although
his efforts to secure Section 5 showed him legally and politically astute,
he, too, lacked a national reputation.
Among the non-lawyers, Edward N. Hurley received a six-year term.
Hurley was a self-made man, an elementary school drop-out who built
successful businesses.
577
He had played an intermediary role in recruiting
571
1929 Interview, supra note 194.
572
When Huston Thompson, whom Wilson had invited to identify a government position
that interested him, approached Wilson about a Commission seat in 1917, Thompson felt
compelled to ease Wilsons fear at placing lawyers on the several Commissions because
they as a rule immediately tie their hands or powers up in technical legal limitations.
Thompson explained that he was not that sort of lawyerbut Wilson conrmed that he
in fact would not put a third lawyer on the commission. Thompson to Wilson, Jan. 15,
1917, 40 PWW, supra note 5, at 490; Wilson to Thompson, Jan. 16, 1917, id. at 493.
573
Speech, Sept. 27, 1912, Davidson, supra note 258, at 284, 291.
574
Wilson placed Frank W. Taussig of Harvard on the Tariff Commission and Winthrop
Daniels of Princeton on the ICC. For the Commerce Board, N.Y. Times, Jan. 31, 1914, at 10;
Professor Taussig Accepts, N.Y. Times, Jan. 7, 1917, at 3.
575
As late as the 1950s, geographic diversity factored signicantly even in Supreme Court
appointments. Thomas R. Marshall, Symbolic Versus Policy Representation on the U.S. Supreme
Court,55J. Pol. 140, 141 (1993).
576
See, e.g., President Holds Up Trade Commission, N.Y. Times, Dec. 29, 1914, at 4.
577
Hurley organized the pneumatic tool industry in America in 1896, retired to raise
livestock in 1902, and became president of a bank and re-entered business in 1906,
manufacturing (and, according to the National Cyclopaedia of American Biography, helping
to invent) the electric washing machine. 40 National Cyclopaedia of American Biogra-
phy 89 (1955).
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
2003] Origins of the FTC 95
Wilson for the 1910 gubernatorial race, and had studied South American
banking and credit on Wilsons behalf.
578
Will Parry had held a succession
of signicant local posts in northwestern politics, business and journal-
ism.
579
Davies located Parry because Wilson wanted a Progressive West
Coast businessman for the agency.
580
Finally, William J. Harris had been
in the insurance business and president of a bank. After he ran Wilsons
Georgia campaign, Wilson had named him Director of the Census in
1913.
581
After a tumultuous period in which personal animosities led to a coup
detat against Chairman Davies, all ve Commissioners were soon gone.
582
Because of his efforts in Raymond Stevenss 1914 Senate campaign,
Rublee was never conrmed; he served as a recess appointee and left in
sixteen months.
583
Hurley returned to the private sector in 1917, although
he later become Chairman of the United States Shipping Board and
President of the Emergency Fleet Corporation.
584
Parrys health deterio-
rated, apparently from overwork, and he died on April 21, 1917.
585
Harris
resigned to run for the Senate in 1918, won, and served there until he
578
Wilson to John Maynard Harlan, June 11, 1910, 20 PWW, supra note 5, at 519; Edward
Nash Hurley, The Bridge to France (1927).
579
Parry had been president of the Seattle City Council, the Seattle and Lake Washington
Water Company, and the Seattle Chamber of Commerce. He had managed a rm that
built a battleship and (fullling Senator Newlandss vision that the Commission include
publicists) had been a journalist and editor. 18 National Cyclopaedia of American
Biography 11617 (1922).
580
MacLean, Davies, supra note 311, at 5758.
581
Trade Commission Named by President, N.Y. Times, Feb. 23, 1915. at 1, 3. In 1929,
Brandeis dismissed Harris as small caliber, with no grasp of the real problems. 1929
Interview, supra note 194.
582
From 1914 until 1950, the Commissioners chose a Chairman from among the agencys
members. At the rst meeting, Davies secured a vote naming him Chairman so long as
he was a member of the Commission. Commission Minute, Mar. 16, 1915. By 1916,
Rublee, Hurley, and Harris joined to remove Davies from the Chairmanship, and passed
it to Hurley. See Commission Minute, May 31, 1916.
583
Rublee tried unsuccessfully to persuade the New Hampshire Progressive Party not to
run a Senate candidate in the race. When Rublee failed, he focused his energies on
attacking the Republican incumbent, Jacob Gallinger. Gallinger won, though, and invoked
the doctrine of Senatorial courtesy to block Rublees conrmation. McClure, Earnest
Endeavors, supra note 131, at 17185. Rublees career after he left the Commission
included appointments under Presidents Wilson, Calvin Coolidge, Herbert Hoover, and
Franklin Roosevelt, one of which led to a highly regarded 1938 effort to assist German
Jews, and private practice with Covington, Burling, Rublee, Acheson, and Shorb.
584
Hurley, supra note 578.
585
When he returned to Seattle for a vacation, Parry was betrayed by a friend to the
newspapers. Once word got out that the West Coast Commissioner was available in
Seattle, he was so beset by petitioners there that he fell back into a rut of ten-hour
workdays. Parry Letter to Commissioners, FTC General Records, Box 38, File 8117-1,
National Archives.
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal96
died in 1932.
586
Davies also resigned to run for the Senate in 1918, but
he lost.
587
VI. CONCLUSION
The candidates, advisers, and legislators who debated competition
policy in the wake of Standard Oil confronted the reality of unprece-
dented business growth. That growth challenged classical assumptions
that business efciency was compatible with opportunity, competition,
fair distribution, and political freedom, and that all could be secured
by non-discretionary antitrust adjudication. Participants in the debate,
lacking any roadmap from countries that had previously responded to
such growth with competition-based policies, debated how much of the
traditional model could and should be retained. They also considered
alternatives that were largely untested in the United States (although
some would soon be tested under the spur of war), including govern-
ment-business cooperation, government encouragement of interrm
cooperation, and direct government regulation.
The legislative resolution of 1914 was a milestone in competition policy
and the startbut only the startof the Commissions story. In 1938,
the Wheeler-Lea Act would expand the Commissions Section 5 authority
to encompass unfair or deceptive acts or practices as well as unfair
methods of competition; additionally, it would subject violations of
Commission orders to civil penalties.
588
Later legislation would modify
the specic prohibitions of the Clayton Act, as when the Celler-Kefauver
Act of 1950 expanded Section 7 to reach asset acquisitions, and the
Hart-Scott-Rodino Act of 1975 added Section 7A to require premerger
lings.
589
Numerous special statutes would expand the Commissions
powers, beginning with the 1918 Webb-Pomerene Act.
590
Even the Com-
missions internal organization would be changed, as Reorganization
Plan No. 8 of 1950
591
would authorize the President to select the Chair-
man from among the Commissioners and would make that Chairman
the executive and administrative head of the agency.
586
24 National Cyclopedia of American Biography 266.
587
Davies returned to private practice, and later became Ambassador to Russia under
Franklin Roosevelt.
588
Act of Mar. 21, 1938, ch. 49, § 3, 52 Stat. 111.
589
Act of Dec. 29, 1950, ch. 1184, 64 Stat. 1125 (codied as amended at 15 U.S.C. § 18).
590
That law authorized the Commission to receive certain lings from export trade
associations organized under the Act, investigate association activities that might adversely
affect domestic competition, advise businesses of adjustments the agency deemed necessary
to comply with the law; and recommend law enforcement to the Attorney General in
appropriate cases.
591
15 Fed. Reg. 3175 (1950).
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE
2003] Origins of the FTC 97
Still, much of the 1914 framework has remained intact. Then, as
now, the Commission could issue orders to prohibit unfair methods of
competition. Then, as now, its general statutory mandate was supple-
mented by enforcement authority over specically dened law violations,
initially those under the Clayton Act. Most importantly, then, as now,
the agency combined formal powers to investigate (those emphasized
in the House debate), formal powers to prosecute (those emphasized
in the Senate debate), and informal authority to educate and work with
business to facilitate compliance with the law (those emphasized by
Wilson). These authorities would provide fertile ground for the agency
to grow and adapt as it addressed changing times and, at its best, to
shape its broad mandate to the needs of those times.
World Composition Services Sterling, VA (571) 434-2510
ABA: Antitrust LJ Vol. 71, No. 1, 2003 ab4268uwin 08-22-03 10:17:50
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
CUT HERE